View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

BOBROWHIG FBQM THE FEDERAL RESERVE BAHK
SOME BASIC PBIWCTPLBS

Before the Annual Convention of the Pennsylvania Bankers Association
Wednesday, May 28, 1958
Atlantic City, H. J.




borrow ing from the federal reserve hank
—some hasic principles
MgT-£3.|L. iflSS___
64-th Annual Convention of the Pennsylvania Bankers Association.

small business in an age of big business

business review



Additional copies of this issue are available
upon request to the Department of Research,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Philadelphia 1, Pa.




BORROWING FROM
THE FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K -

SOME BASIC PRINCIPLES
By Karl R. Bopp, President*

I propose to discuss borrowing from the Federal

Before I discuss borrowing as such I would

Reserve Bank. I have selected this topic for d is­

like to describe briefly some of the economic

cussion today precisely because few member

developments and bank lending and investing

banks have occasion to borrow at this time. The

policies that may lead to it.

amount of borrow ing is low in part because the
Federal Reserve System has provided reserves

W hy some banks borrow

liberally and cheaply in other ways as an im por­

The ebb and flow in the demand for loans at

tant contribution to economic recovery.

com mercial banks is a reflection of the ebb and

Why, then, talk about such borrow ing now?
There are several reaso n s:
1. If experience is any guide, this will not be
a permanent state of affairs.
2. We all wish to know the basic principles

flow in economic activity itself. In periods of
rising business and inflation, the demand for
loans increases and the com m ercial banker won­
ders where to get the funds to lend, how to keep
custom ers content with less money than they wish,

on which we operate.
3. We are m ore apt to establish valid prin­
ciples when our immediate profit position
is not affected by the decisions we reach.




* A n address before the 64th Annual Convention
o f the Pennsylvania Bankers A sso ciatio n in A tlan tic
C ity, New Jersey, M a y 28, 1958.

and how to maintain good will while denying
some applicants altogether. In periods of declin­
ing business, on the other hand, the banker seeks
customers who will borrow as well as other ways
to employ idle funds.
These alterations in demand and supply would,
of themselves, produce corresponding alterations
in interest rates. Action of the monetary authori­
ties who are pursuing a flexible policy adjusted
to current conditions reinforces such changes in
interest rates.
When demand for loans is slack a banker pre­
fers to invest his excess funds in short-term
securities so that the early maturities will provide
the funds to meet his needs when loan demand
again picks up. The same is true of bankers gen­
erally and of other lenders. As a consequence,
short-term rates usually move down much more
than long-term rates, and the structure of interest
rates takes on an upward slope. This slope is con­
firmed when the market anticipates that rates will
rise. The reason is that anyone who wishes to
borrow or lend for a long period can do so either
by means of a single contract for the entire term
or by means of a series of short-term contracts.
If the market anticipates a rise in rates, borrowers
will prefer the long contract to beat the rise and
lenders will prefer the short contracts so as to
secure funds from maturities for reinvestment
when the rise occurs. In other words, the supply
of funds will concentrate in the short market and
the demand for funds in the long market, thus
confirming the upward slope in rates.
That is not the whole story, however. Slack loan
demand and low rates of interest put pressure on
bank earnings. There is, therefore, a strong temp­
tation to meet the immediate problem of earnings
by reaching out for longer maturities because of
the relatively higher yields, even though prices
are high. At such times it is not always recognized




adequately that any investor assumes a risk when
he buys the longer bond. It is the possibility that
yields may go higher with a consequent loss of
capital value. Even a relatively small change in
yield will mean a relatively large change in the
market value of a long-term bond. Although an
investor is more likely to remember this when
the time for liquidation comes, it is more profit­
able to remember it when the initial investment
decision is made. Some short-term investors delib­
erately buy long-term bonds with the expectation
of liquidating just in time to secure a maximum
return. This approach has possibilities, but it has
hazards as well. Sometimes these individuals
develop a dual standard. They take credit when
developments follow their expectations, but they
blame others when subsequent developments are
adverse.
The prices of long-term bonds, bought to se­
cure income in a period of weak loan demand and
easy money conditions, decline as money tightens.
And, just when money tightens in response to
economic expansion, the problem of the banker
shifts from trying to find profitable outlets for
excess funds to finding funds with which to meet
expanding demands. The risk that was assumed
when the long bonds were bought becomes a
loss on the books. In seeking funds to meet
expanding demands it is understandable that the
banker might prefer not to sell the bonds because
this would convert the book loss into an actual
loss.
At this point hope often enters the picture—
hope that the tightness will be only temporary.
And, of course, experience shows that although
the decline in prices continues as money tightens,
eventually a peak in yields or a trough in bond
prices is reached from which both move in the
opposite directions.
Why not, therefore, tide over this period by

borrowing? If the cost of borrowing is not too
great, this might appear to be a method of eating
one’s cake, the higher yield, and having it too,
not incurring a capital loss.
The discount window is not an automatic
escape route
I want to indicate why member banks should not
seek funds for this purpose from the Federal
Reserve Bank. Suppose we look at the responsi­
bilities of the Federal Reserve System under the
conditions that have been described. It is the
central bank which must adjust its monetary
policy to economic developments. It tightens
credit to restrain inflationary expansion. One evi­
dence of tighter money is the higher interest rates
that have been mentioned and the higher discount
rates that the Reserve Banks themselves would
charge under the circumstances. Another is a
reduced availability of reserves.
The effectiveness of the System’s efforts to
restrain would be blunted if reserves were made
available freely, if member banks had no hesi­
tancy in borrowing, and the Reserve Banks never
asked any questions about continuous borrowing.
As an economist, I appreciate that the Reserve
Banks probably could discourage, even to the
point of preventing, such borrowing by charging
a high enough rate. But that is not the kind of
rate policy on which the Federal Reserve Act is
based. The Act requires each Federal Reserve
Bank to refuse credit accommodations for any
purpose inconsistent with the maintenance of
sound credit conditions. It provides specifically:
“ Each Federal Reserve Bank shall keep itself
informed of the general character and
amount of the loans and investments of its
member banks with a view to ascertaining
whether undue use is being made of bank
credit. . .o r for any . . . purpose inconsistent




with the maintenance of sound credit condi­
tions; and, in determining whether to grant
or refuse advances, rediscounts or other
credit accommodations, the Federal Reserve
Bank shall give consideration to such infor­
mation.”

One reason for not relying on the rate exclu­
sively is that the appropriate rate would have to
be comparatively high. The same rate would have
to be charged to all members; yet the primary
purpose would be to discourage the relatively
small number of banks that tend to borrow exces­
sively. This is not to say that the discount rate is
unimportant. On the contrary, it is an indispens­
able tool of monetary policy. Its level and changes
in it influence the tone of the market, including
market rates. I do not, however, have time to dis­
cuss it adequately today.
The discount window of the Federal Reserve
Bank is like a safety valve that enables a member
to secure funds temporarily to meet needs that
could not reasonably be anticipated. It should not
be necessary to charge a member that finds itself
in such a condition the high rates that would be
necessary to discourage the complacent borrower.
The principles and rules that govern loans to
member banks are published as Regulation A of
the Board of Governors. I would like to read from
the foreword to that Regulation:
“ Federal Reserve credit is generally
extended on a short-term basis to a member
bank in order to enable it to adjust its asset
position when necessary because of develop­
ments such as a sudden withdrawal of
deposits or seasonal requirements for credit
beyond those which can reasonably be met
by use of the bank’s own resources. Federal
Reserve credit is also available for longer
periods when necessary in order to assist

member banks in meeting unusual situations,
such as may result from national, regional
or local difficulties or from exceptional cir­
cumstances involving only particular mem­
ber banks. Under ordinary conditions, the
continuous use of Federal Reserve credit by
a member bank over a considerable period
of time is not regarded as appropriate.
“ In considering a request for credit
accommodation, each Federal Reserve Bank
gives due regard to the purpose of the credit
and to its probable effects upon the mainte­
nance of sound credit conditions, both as to
the individual institution and the economy
generally. It keeps informed of and takes
into account the general character and
amount of the loans and investments of the
member bank. It considers whether the bank
is borrowing principally for the purpose of
obtaining a tax advantage or profiting from
rate differentials and whether the bank is
extending an undue amount of credit for the
speculative carrying of or trading in securi­
ties, real estate, or commodities, or otherwise

I would like to call to your attention the signifi­
cant analysis of the functioning of the discount
mechanism that appears in the latest Annual Re­
port of the Board of Governors (pp. 7-18).
Borrowing at the Reserve Bank is significant
to the member bank and to the Reserve Bank. To
the member it is a privilege of obtaining addition­
al reserves to meet unexpected needs. Ordinarily
such needs would be for short periods though in
exceptional cases they may be more extended. In
any event, borrowing gives the bank time to make
orderly adjustments in its assets should that
become necessary. To the Reserve Bank appro­
priate borrowing has the advantages of supplying
additional reserves directly to the banks that have
legitimate need for them and of attaching a string




to withdraw the reserves when the loan is repaid.
I should stress that the System always views the
net result of total borrowing, when deciding
whether to add more to, or subtract from, bank
reserves through open market operations. So the
discount window is not an automatic escape route
that nullifies the effects of open market opera­
tions. On the contrary, these tools function to­
gether, to achieve the degree and the distribution
of pressure throughout the banking system that
fulfills at any particular time the objectives of
monetary policy.
Misconceptions clarified
I would like now to try to clear up a few misun­
derstandings that I have heard about the admin­
istration of our discount policy. One of these is
belief and repetition of an occasional rumor that
I have heard phrased in these words: “ Boy, the
Fed sure is tough.” It is difficult to trace such
rumors to their source. On occasion we have
found that they begin with a banker whose bor­
rowing record in terms of frequency, amount, and
duration concerned us sufficiently to warrant a
discussion. We do not, in these discussions, tell
the banker how he should manage his own insti­
tution. We do point out that we have a responsi­
bility to manage the Federal Reserve Bank in
accordance with the law and that he should take
into account that frequent or continuous borrow­
ing is not appropriate except in unusual circum­
stances. I mention this because unfounded rumors
may have kept some members from applying for
advances for legitimate purposes. My suggestion
is that when you hear such a rumor either ignore
it altogether or investigate it until you have ascer­
tained all relevant facts in the case. When the rele­
vant facts are known, I would leave to your judg­
ment whether we acted tough and capriciously
or responsibly.

There has been some misunderstanding concern­
ing the distinction I have drawn between manag­
ing our own Reserve Bank and managing the
member bank. As a result, we have at times
received unmerited praise and blame. Usually the
praise is some variant of the following observa­
tion: “ Thanks a lot for forcing me to sell those
bonds to repay our debt to you. The bonds have
since gone down several more points.” The blame
is some variant of these statements: “ Your atti­
tude cost my bank plenty. Those bonds you made
me sell have since recovered several points.”
Actually, we do not tell a banker how to adjust
his position so that he can repay. That is his prob­
lem. The nature of that problem will vary among
banks, depending in part on earlier investment
decisions. The results of action taken will also
vary, depending on subsequent developments that
cannot be foreseen.
Another misunderstanding is that the adminis­
tration of discounting varies over time. I can
appreciate how this misunderstanding arises. In
a period of easy money most banks will be seeking
ways to employ idle funds, relatively few will be
borrowing at all, and very few, if any, may be
borrowing inappropriately. In a period of tight
money, on the other hand, few banks will have
idle funds, relatively more will be borrowing, and
some may be complacent about their borrowing.
In other words the discount department of the
Reserve Bank will usually be busier in a period
of tight money than in a period of easy money.
More banks may approach the continuous bor­
rower category as sanguine expectations do not
materialize. And so we have to make more tele­
phone calls. This results, however, from mainte­
nance of standards by the Reserve Bank and not
from a change in standards or administration. An
indication of uniformity of standards is the fact
that occasionally we do find inappropriate bor­




rowing that calls for correction even in recessions.
Now, every real craftsman in the field knows
that credit cannot be administered according to
mechanical rules. Among the important factors
that are considered in evaluating the position of
a particular bank are the following:
What is the nature and extent of its loan
expansion ?
Is it confronted with seasonal requirements
for credit beyond those which could reason­
ably be anticipated?
To what extent has it liquidated other assets
to meet the loan expansion?
Has it been subjected to unusual withdrawals
of deposits?
Has the community in which the bank is
located experienced economic adversity or
other unusual developments that require time
for solution or adjustment?
Officers of the Federal Reserve Bank are gener­
ally familiar with the managements and policies
of most of the member banks in the District.
Nevertheless, our discount officers find it desir­
able from time to time to supplement our knowl­
edge by means of direct inquiry. Raising questions
is at times a necessary part of proper administra­
tion of discounting. It is not the questions but the
answers that influence our judgment. You appre­
ciate that I cannot cite specific cases because these
relationships are confidential, but I know of
instances in which the facts demonstrated that
even extended borrowing was appropriate.
Commercial banks are different
I move now to the reasoning that leads some
observers to very different conclusions with
respect to the investment policies of commercial
banks, especially in recessions. Since many of

the ingredients are the same as those I have men­
tioned, I can be brief.
Most analysts of business fluctuations would
agree that lower long-term interest rates contrib­
ute to economic recovery from recession by stimu­
lating construction of public works, of houses,
and of plant and equipment. Since a rising
demand for long-term bonds would tend to pull
down long-term rates, some analysts would
encourage all investors, including commercial
banks, to purchase such bonds. A few observers,
if I understand their reasoning, would even single
out commercial banks particularly for such
encouragement. They reason that such action by
the commercial banks would contribute not only
to the recovery but also to restraining later pos­
sible inflationary developments. It would help
restrain inflation because the losses in capital
values that accompany inflation would tend to
freeze the bonds into the banks.
The logic behind this view has cogency. Never­
theless, I am not convinced that commercial banks
should be encouraged to ignore their internal
liquidity positions even in recessions. Their essen­
tial role differs from the role of those whose essen­
tial function is long-term investment. The genuine
long-term investor can ride out a temporary loss
in capital values. The commercial banker, on the
other hand, is always faced with the possible
demand for deposit withdrawal and with pros­
pective demands from his borrowing customers.
Particularly these latter demands—and for indi­
vidual banks the former as well, as we have
learned in the Third Federal Reserve District—
are apt to come precisely when long-term bond
prices are depressed.
This does not disturb the analysts I have men­
tioned. On the contrary, they see it as a great
advantage; because it would make a restrictive
monetary policy more effective by putting greater




pressure on banks. I have a hunch, however, that
they are more expert at constructing economic
models than at managing either commercial or
central banks.
I do not mean to suggest that commercial banks
should confine their investments exclusively to
securities of very short maturity. I am well aware
of the fact that many commercial banks hold
substantial amounts of savings deposits and, to
pay reasonably competitive rates on such deposits,
they must invest in longer-term obligations, espe­
cially when short-term rates are low. I also recog­
nize the problem of maintaining earnings in
periods of slack loan demand and low rates. What
I do suggest is that, in expanding its investment
portfolio at such times, a bank should aim for
such a maturity distribution as will meet its fore­
seeable needs, and not sacrifice adequate liquid­
ity for immediate earnings, nor look to the Fed
to rescue it from its errors.
Such a policy, generally followed by commer­
cial banks, would not mean that the banks were
not doing their share to promote recovery. By
investing their available funds in whatever matur­
ities were most appropriate for them, they would
be helping to finance Government expenditures
and providing funds for investment by others.
Concluding remarks
I have no desire to tell you how to run your insti­
tutions. That is your responsibility. On the other
hand, I do have a responsibility with respect to
the Federal Reserve Bank. In the nature of the
case there is a reciprocal relationship between
our operations. When you borrow from the
Federal Reserve, the Federal Reserve lends to
you. That is why it seemed appropriate to discuss
Federal Reserve Bank lending policy at a time
when loans are few and we can be most objective.
I cannot close without expressing what we all

know and feel. We share a common goal of
reasonably full use of our resources and a reason­
ably stable level of prices. The banking system
alone cannot achieve this goal. Much else is




needed in many areas. Nevertheless, appropriate
monetary policy by the Federal Reserve System
and appropriate policies of the commercial banks
are indispensable parts of the common effort.