View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THINGS TO COME:

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION

Remarks bv John P. LaWare
to the
National Economists Club
Washington. D.C.
October 31. 1989

Good afternoon.

I am delighted to be here — in the

midst of bands of professional economists — and not have to
discuss the economy or monetary policy.

That crystal ball

is one into which I am still learning to look intelligently.

What I want to do is gaze with yoxi into another crystal
ball, the one that looks into the future of the banking
system in the United States.

Let's look together at the

long-term issues with which bankers will be dealing and the
implications of those issues for the future of the industry.

I would argue that this Federal Reserve Board is not at
all constrained by historical policies and inhibitions, but
rather it is committed to the proposition that U.S. banks
should be fully competitive, both domestically and
internationally.

Strong support for interstate banking; for

the legislative initiative of Senator Proxmire in 1988 on
Glass-Steagall reform; and the watershed so-called Section
20 decisions which allowed bank holding companies to set up
affiliates to underwrite and deal in certain classes of

2

securities, are all clear evidence of this constructive
stance.

Indeed, we may seem too timid vet to bankers, but I
would remind you that by statute we are simultaneously
compelled to make safety and soundness a high priority.
That priority dictates a measured pace of reform, with time
to learn from experience, rather than a headlong rush,
fraught with all of the inherent dangers of excessive speed.
I assure you that our long-term goal, subject to the will of
Congress, is to move to broader powers to assure the
competitive position of United States banks both
domestically and internationally.

Now let's look at some of the issues we face:

Capital will be a central issue for the foreseeable
future.

The thrift mess, the Texas snafu, and the LDC debt

debacle all teach the same lesson.

More capital!

More

capital would not have prevented any of those tragedies, but
more capital would have made each one more manageable and
would have significantly reduced the casualty lists and
ultimately the cost to the taxpayer.

As we move to reconstitute or assimilate the troubled
institutions in the thrift industry, and rehabilitate the
great Texas banking companies, and as banks absorb

3

additional provisions to bring third world debt reserves to
mor* realistic levels, the demands of banking on the capital
markets will be huge.

At the same time we are moving toward

risk-based capital standards and some banks will need more
than just retained earnings to get them there.

Will the markets be able to respond to that demand?
Well, there is no question the capacity exists, but is there
a will to do so.

Securities markets tend to measure their

appetites in terms of rates of return on investment.

Will

banks or holding companies having only .80 returns on assets
and 12 percent returns on equity be able to compete for
capital at an acceptable cost?

Perhaps.

But I suspect the

prize will go to the swift and lean, those with a better
than one percent return on assets and 15 percent or more on
equity.

On paper the differences between .8 and 1.0 and 12

and 15 percent look small, but when you are a manager trying
to close that gap it looks as wide as the Chesapeake Bay.
foresee a scramble for capital in the next few years which
will force banks to rethink their strategies; to see if
those strategies fit the changed world in which they will
find themselves.

New strategies to improve earning power

and improve risk management will be searched for.
Restructuring, downsizing, market targeting, narrower
specialization and stringent cost controls will be common
themes — all in the name of capital.

And as bank powers

are expanded, new elements of risk will be encountered —

I

4

risk which must be matched against adequate levels of
capital.

All Winston Churchill could promise Britain in 1940 was
blood, sweat, and tears.

All I can promise bankers in 1989

is the need for more capital.

Another issue, much in the news these days, is LBO and
takeover financing accomplished with heavy ratios of debt.
One emerging philosophy seems to be that investors using
their own money are welcome to the junk bond market, and if
they call it wrong they are simply wasting their own assets.
But, there is growing concern whether it is appropriate for
banks, using insurance-protected depositors' funds, to
participate in these highly leveraged financings.

In

Congress the usual reaction to a perceived problem of this
sort would be to regulate it or outlaw it.

In my opinion,

either course in this case would be a mistake since the real
outcome would be to allocate credit, and credit allocation
flies in the face of all that is holy in a free market
economy.

But, I do think there is a distinct element of risk in
this kind of lending.

The risk is in failing to make a

proper appraisal of whether the cash flow coverage of debt
service requirements is sufficient to absorb changes in
interest rates, revenue flows or asset values which are part

5

of the forecast on which the loan is based,

a stunning

example is Campeau, where cash flows apparently failed to
materialize as projected and a seemingly perfect deal
quavered on the brink of disaster with very unsettling
effects on financial markets.

For banks the seductive

elements in these highly leveraged situations are large
fees, new lending opportunities and just the sheer
excitement of being part of big deals.

I have urged bankers to be more skeptical and to impose
higher credit standards in these transactions lest Congress
be goaded into action the bankers will regret.

Bankers must

make sure credit policies and procedures are sound; they
must determine a prudent level of exposure to highly
leveraged financing in their overall portfolios and stick to
it.

And they must make sure their directors know what

policies they are following and what exposure limits have
been established.

In short, if highly leveraged financings

are administered prudently, they are not likely to encounter
objection or interference from Congress.

But perceived

imprudence will likely result in restrictive legislation
which no-one wants.

All of this apparently defensive commentary is intended
to help preserve the creative initiative to produce new
services and new ways to lend.

Creativity is an important

6

part of competitiveness and competitiveness is the key to
future banking success.

While the other issues I want to touch on today are
structural, the basic question remains;

Are American banks

competitive domestically and internationally with other
financial institutions offering similar services?

If not,

are there changes in the structure of banking institutions
which would contribute to greater competitiveness without
compromising safety and soundness?

Those are not puny issues which should be abandoned to
casual solutions.

When you stop to think about it, many of

them threaten long-held principles and sacred practice.

All

of the answers are not clear, but here are some of the
issues which those who operate banks, we who regulate and
supervise banks, and Congress itself will be wrestling with
in the immediate future.

The United States has long held that commerce and
banking should be separate; that commercial enterprises
should not own and operate banks and banks should not
substantially own or manage commercial entities.

This issue will inevitably emerge as part of the debate
over further expansion of bank powers.

The recent

experience with the thrifts and sensitivity to the exposure

7

of taxpayers may dictate that, to the extent additional
powers mean additional risk, the exercise of those powers
must be outside of the comfort of the federal safety net.
In that case Congress is likely to turn to the financial
services holding company structural concept.

In such a

holding company, additional powers would be granted to
separate subsidiaries and the insured deposit-taking
subsidiary would be insulated from the risks of its
affiliates by appropriate prohibitions or limitations on
inter-company financing or transfers of capital.
to use the vernacular.

Firewalls

Functional regulation of nonbanking

activities would assure expert oversight for each activity
and integrated marketing of related financial services would
significantly enhance competitiveness.

An inevitable question arising from consideration of
such a structure is the ownership of the holding company
itself.

Could an insurance company own such a holding

company?

Actually, for many insurance companies the only

item missing today from their subsidiary lists is a
commercial bank.
a company?

Could an automobile manufacturer own such

Well, Ford and G.M. and Chrysler are operators

of huge finance companies and G.M. has a large insurance
operation as well.

Is there an inherent threat to the

country if one of them or all of them were to own a bank?
And what about G.E. or Sears or Gulf & Western and so on?
By the same token, would it be wrong in some moral or

8

economic sense for Citicorp's shareholders to also own a
life insurance company, an investment banking company, a
computer company and a real estate development company as
long as Citibank itself was insulated from whatever
additional risks might exist in those other businesses?

This issue of commerce and banking will also arise
because of the recent history of the thrift industry where
the ownership of thrift institutions by insurance companies
and industrial and commercial enterprises is well
established.
nation.

Ford owns the second largest thrift in the

Thrifts and banks are operationally more like each

other every day, although the capital sections of their
balance sheets may be somewhat different.

Why then do we

accept the relationship in one case and not in the other?
It is high time we re-examined this ancient issue, and all
of us, whichever side we are on, should be vocal
participants in the debate.

It may well be that pragmatic

considerations will override philosophy in the resolution of
this issue, particularly if we find that ownership by a
commercial enterprise would significantly improve access of
banks to capital markets.

But, we should not rush this one.

We need to be sure we understand all of the implications
before we act.

9

Uncharacteristically, I am not sure where I am
personally on that issue.

My tilt at the moment is toward

change, but it is too early on for final judgments.

Interstate banking on a nationwide basis is rushing at
us like a fast freight train, and whatever your individual
feelings are about that development, the trend is not going
to be reversed.

By the mid-1990s we will have

facto

nationwide interstate banking without the de jure blessing
of Congress or repeal of the McFadden Act.

But, absent

clarifying federal legislation, we may be creating a whole
army of Frankenstein monsters in the form of multi-state
bank holding companies.

Consider for a moment some of the nightmare problems
the manager of a bank holding company faces with banks in
ten different states.

— First, he is forced into a holding company or
multi-holding company organizational structure because the
McFadden Act effectively precludes branching across state
lines.

— That means ten different management teams; at least
ten boards of directors; and compliance with applicable
state banking regulations which may dictate ten different
ways to approach the same transaction.

10

— To the extent that there are state-chartered banks
in each state, there will be ten different examination
standards to be managed to and ten different examinations to
be endured.

— Advertising, marketing, pricing, etc. may be subject
to ten different standards or sets of regulations and
limitations.

— And, if the company is in more than one Federal
Reserve District, where is its friendly, helpful, fatherly
central banker?

Is he in Richmond, Philadelphia, New York,

or Cleveland?

— Given those operating constraints, can bankers
really achieve the operating efficiencies they bragged about
to the security analysts when they were trying to explain
how they were going to eliminate the dilution they saddled
themselves with to make the acquisition?

Efficiency is

forced to take a backseat to jurisdiction.

I predict that both federalists and states-righters
will be calling for reform to accommodate these changes by
the mid-1990s.

And one approach will be legislation to

create a whole new class of federally chartered financial
institutions — multi-state banks or holding companies which
would be federally regulated, overriding state authority

11

entirely.

In order to deal with redundancy, repeal of

McFadden would be proposed and nationwide branching
permitted making much more efficient operation possible.

Obviously many assumed values would change if all that
came to pass.

Treasured axioms such as:

beautiful, big is bad."
at all costs."

"small is

"States rights must be preserved

"Local banks with local management and local

directors are the only way to assure proper attention to the
needs of the community."

Or, "the bigger the bank, the more

unmanageable it becomes."

Some of those axioms are established elements of our
economic culture, but in the interest of adapting to the
changing needs of the economy and the requirements of
competitiveness we may have to discard them as we have done
others in the past.

For example:

It took us 125 years and two aborted prior attempts in
order to establish a central bank — the Federal Reserve.
By doing so we rejected the once popular argument that a
central bank gave bankers too much power over the economy.

12

We chartered national banks and created a national
currency system to provide a sounder base for financing the
Civil War and to help stabilize the banking system.

To meet the financial exigencies of the depression we
stopped redeeming paper currency with gold and ceased gold
coinage.

We accepted control over securities markets and banks
by the federal government in the 1930s in order to restore
confidence in financial institutions in return for federal
insurance of deposits.

All of those were painful, even heart-rending, changes.
But today we accept those changes and generally agree either
that they were an improvement or at least that they were
necessary given the call of the times.

Change is always threatening and almost always
uncomfortable, but like death and taxes it is also
inevitable.

The issues I have presented for your

consideration today are only a few of the more obvious ones
we will be dealing with in the near future.

I hope we can

approach the development of these issues with our focus on
what is good for the United States.

Too often in the past

there has been division on great issues along parochial
proprietary lines and Congress has thrown up its hands and

13

gone its own way.

That is always a risky outcome.

might have said, "Let's come reason together."

As LBJ

If we do, I

am confident we can achieve results good for the country and
good for banking.