View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks bv
John P. LaWare
Member. Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System
at a
Conference on Critical Issues and Trends in Banking
Sponsored bv the University of Tennessee
Financial Institutions Center
Knoxville. Tennessee
June 8. 1990

Good afternoon.

It is a privilege to be with you today for

this important conference.

The topic could not be more timely.

It is essential that there be wide debate in both the public and
private sector about the future of banking.

The Congress will

deal with these issues in earnest early in its next Session.

The

issues are complex, not generally well understood, and in some
cases will be considered by legislators emotionally committed to
now discredited historic conclusions.

American banking today is embattled both at home and abroad.
At home, traditional customer relationships have eroded as
foreign banks and the money markets have offered cheaper access
to working capital for U.S. firms, and U.S. firms faced with
narrower margins and greater financing needs have made decisions
according to price rather than historic relationships.

2

United States banks today find themselves faced with higher
capital costs and higher funding costs than many of their
competitors.

And, domestically, the spectrum of services banks

may offer is so narrow as to preclude the "one stop banking"
approach that many banks advertised to consumers only a few years
ago.

I am not going to recite all the numbers you have heard so
many times about how U.S. banks have slipped in terms of their
world position measured by the size of the balance sheet.
Frankly, I d o n ’
t think that's a very good index.

The Japanese

banks, for example, which have had such dramatic growth in the
last few years, are very poor performers when measured in terms
of return on assets.

They struggle to get to 30 basis points.

That kind of return would get them little favorable attention
from the investment community in this country.

And yet!

And

yet! How do we account for the disproportionate growth of
Japanese and European banks in the past 10-12 years?

Are they smarter?
innovative?

I hope not and think not.

Are they more

Well, I think the record would support an argument

that U.S. banks have been very innovative in lending, investment,
and cash management techniques.

Perhaps, in fact, they have been

world leaders in innovation, but with a rather narrower spectrum
in which to apply it.

3

There is also a case to be made that foreign competitors
operate under a lighter and more easily understood burden of
regulation and compliance.

I can only tell you that we at the

Fed wince when to comply with legislation we must impose an
additional burden on banks.

These burdens are the result of

well-intended legislation drafted without a full appreciation of
the cost to banks of additional reporting and compliance.

It is also fairly obvious to me that the American ethic of
short-term profits and matching short-term strategies puts
American banks and financial institutions at a great
disadvantage.

Foreign competitors at least take a longer view

which is condoned and rewarded by their capital markets.
Forgoing short-term profits to gain market share by bidding deals
at skinny profit margins is considered smart in many countries.
In the United States such behavior is punished with lower stock
prices and higher interest costs for borrowed capital.

Well, I won't bore you with further description of a
situation of which you are all too well aware.

My purpose today

is to share with you my belief that the opportunity to eliminate
some of these competitive disadvantages is at hand.

The

willingness of most Members in Congress to deal with GlassSteagall reform was clearly demonstrated by the overwhelming
Senate vote for Senator Proxmire's bill in 1988.

In my opinion,

that legislation would have passed the House in similar fashion

4

if it had reached the floor.

Although I was disappointed at the

time that such a significant attempt at reform failed, I now will
argue that failure to act then may have been a blessing in
disguise.

Since then the Congress has become increasingly

concerned about the competitive position of our banking system.
I believe that concern has survived the shock and dismay
surrounding the S&L mess and when Congress revisits banking
legislation, it will be on a much broader front than just
securities powers.

By the end of this year Treasury will be putting the
finishing touches on its FIRREA-mandated study of deposit
insurance.

That study will undoubtedly contain recommendations

for revisions to the system designed to inject more market
discipline into the depositor-bank relationship.

The thought is

that deposit insurance, originally designed to avoid financial
panics and runs on solvent banks, has worked too w e l l .

In the

past the threat of a run motivated most bankers to stick to safe
and sound practices.

Experience has shown that deposit insurance

has almost totally eliminated consumer runs.

Encouraged by the

security from runs, some bankers moved into riskier assets,
attracted by higher returns.

Certainly that pattern emerged time

and again in failed S&Ls and in many failed commercial banks as
well.

5

The difficult part of deposit insurance reform will be to
strike the right balance.

Any re-introduction of market

discipline by exposing depositors to more risk will have an
offsetting effect of somewhat less stability for the system.

And

perhaps most difficult of all will be any effort to make
significant changes in a system which, after 55 years, is deeply
imbedded in our commercial culture.

Deposit insurance is the centerpiece of the so-called
federal safety net mechanism.

The pivotal issue in consideration

of new powers and the future structure of the banking system will
be whether to extend the protection of the safety net to new
financial activities of banks.

Depending on how that issue is

resolved, the future structure of the banking system will be
determined.

The safety net is essentially of three parts.
deposit insurance.

The first is

The second is emergency liquidity assistance

provided through the discount window at Federal Reserve Banks.
Liquidity assistance was, as you know, an important reason for
creating the Federal Reserve in the first place.

The third

element of the safety net is access to the payments system
through clearing and settlement services of the Fed.

An argument frequently used against spreading the net any
wider, that is to say granting additional powers to federally

6

insured banks, is that the safety net provides a subsidy to
banks.

The assumption is that banks can fund themselves at lower

cost than other financial institutions because the insurance of
deposits and access to emergency liquidity insulate them from
failure.

But whatever advantage is gained in funding cost is at

least partially offset by the opportunity cost of the sterilized
noninterest-bearing reserves member banks must keep at the Fed
and the cost of services provided Icq depositors by banks acting
as paying and collecting agents.

Unfortunately, we do not have a definitive quantitative
analysis of this much discussed subsidy, and the numbers would
vary widely from bank to bank depending on the deposit mix and
the purchased funds markets which a particular institution might
use.

In any case, access to the window may be the most important

element of the safety net, particularly in this era of widely
fluctuating markets and volatile interest rates.

If after dealing with deposit insurance reform there is
still an overriding desire to prevent further extension of the
safety net, Congress is likely to turn to the financial services
holding company as a structural solution.

The holding company

concept is seductive in that it permits the isolation of the
insured deposit-taking bank from the risks inherent in any new
powers and facilitates functional regulation of new businesses.

7

One urgent question is:

Can U.S. financial institutions

forced into a holding company structure, with all of the
attendant inefficiencies of funding and management, compete
effectively with European and Japanese banks which will probably
develop as so-called universal banks.

As yet, no one has

successfully quantified what the trade-offs are, but I suspect
that Congress will be reluctant to spread the federal safety net
under an unlimited number of new services given the disastrous
outcome in the thrift industry.

Competitiveness arguments will favor the universal bank, but
defense of our unique federal safety net will clearly favor the
financial services holding company.

One compromise might be to

permit the formation of un-insured bank subsidiaries of holding
companies.

These un-insured banks could operate as universal

banks either domestically or internationally with independent
funding or funding from the parent, and regulation could be
minimal.

Capital in sufficient quantity to be competitive might

be a problem, but the opportunity available to such an entity
might attract the necessary capital.

Another compromise which might be considered would allow new
powers — securities, for example — to be carried on in a
subsidiary of the bank but with the stipulation that the sub be
capitalized as though it were free-standing and its capital not
be counted with the parent bank's capital in calculating capital

8

adequacy of the bank for requlatory purposes.

This approach

would address some of the competitive weaknesses of the holdinq
company alternative and at the same time partially insulate the
insured institution from any additional risks involved in the
subsidiary's operation.

An issue closely related to structure is the issue of
commerce and banking.

Whether Congress adopts the holding

company structure or the universal bank alternative or some other
structure, the question of ownership will arise.

The United

States has long held that commerce and banking should be
separate; that commercial enterprises should not own and operate
banks and banks should not substantially own or manage commercial
entities.

But should an insurance company or an automobile

manufacturer be allowed to own a bank or financial services
holding company?

Well, Ford and G.M. and Chrysler are operators

of huge finance companies and G.M. has a large insurance
operation as well.

Is there an inherent threat to the country if

one of them or all of them were to own a bank?

By the same

token, would it be wrong in some moral or economic sense for a
large bank or bank holding company to also own a life insurance
company, an investment banking company, a computer company and a
real estate development company as long as the insured deposittaking company was insulated from whatever additional risks might
exist in those other businesses?

9

This issue of commerce and banking will also arise because
of the recent history of the thrift industry where the ownership
of thrift institutions by insurance companies and industrial and
commercial enterprises is well established.
owns the nation's third largest thrift.

For example, Ford

Thrifts and banks are

operationally more like each other every day, although the
capital sections of their balance sheets may be somewhat
different.

Why then do we accept the relationship in one case

and not in the other?

It is high time we re-examined this

ancient issue; and all of us, whichever side we are on, should be
vocal participants in the debate.
It may well be that pragmatic considerations will override
philosophy in the resolution of this issue, if we find that
ownership by a commercial enterprise would significantly improve
access of banks to capital.

But, we should not rush this one.

We need to be sure we understand all of the implications before
we act.

Turning to another issue, interstate banking on a nationwide
basis is rushing at us like a fast freight train, and whatever
our individual feelings are about that development, the trend is
not going to be reversed.

By the mid-1990s we will have de facto

nationwide interstate banking without the de jure blessing of
Congress or repeal of the McFadden Act.

But, absent clarifying

federal legislation, we may be creating a whole army of severely

10

handicapped institutions in the form of multi-state bank holding
companies.

Consider for a moment some of the nightmare problems the
manager of a bank holding company faces with banks in ten
different states.

First, he is forced into a holding company or multi-holding
company organizational structure because the McFadden Act
effectively precludes branching across state lines.

— That means ten different management teams; at least ten
boards of directors; and compliance with applicable state banking
regulations which may dictate ten different ways to handle the
same transaction.

— To the extent that there are state-chartered banks in
each state, there will be ten different examination standards to
be managed to, and ten different examinations to be endured.

— Advertising, marketing, pricing, etc. may be subject to
ten different standards or sets of regulations and limitations.

— And, if you are in more than one Federal Reserve
District, where is your friendly, helpful, fatherly central

11

banker?

Is he in Boston, New York, Atlanta, Dallas, or San

Francisco?

And

—

Given those constraints, can the multi-state hoJding

company really achieve the operating efficiencies that were
promised to analysts and investors as justification for the high
price paid to put the company together in the first place.

I predict that whether they are federalists or statesrighters bankers will all be calling for reform to accommodate
more efficient interstate operations by the mid-1990s.

One

approach which will probably be proposed will be legislation to
create a whole new class of federally chartered financial
institutions — multi-state banks or holding companies which
would be federally regulated, overriding state authority
entirely.
In order to deal with redundancy, repeal of McFadden will be
considered to permit nationwide branching in order to make
operations more efficient.

That debate will be a hot one.

Finally, an issue which has not had enough serious attention
is the structure of federal regulation.

We have the OTS, the

FDIC, the OCC, the NCUA, and the Federal Reserve — all operating
in addition to regulations imposed by the individual states.

No

12

matter h ow diligently the agencies strive through

mechanisms

like the Exam Council to coordinate policies and procedures,
there are inevitable differences and inconsistencies which create
confusion and error on the part of regulated companies.

It is

particularly troublesome in multi-bank holding companies with a
mixture of national, state member, and state nonmember banks.

The Fed regulates bank holding companies and state-chartered
member banks.

The OCC, national banks? the FDIC, state-chartered

nonmember banks; the OTS, federally chartered thrift
institutions; and the NCUA, credit unions.

Simple logic tells you that there must be a better way, but
I would hesitate to speculate in this area.

There may be too

many turf considerations ever to reach a sensible solution.

But

a system where there was one insurer for all deposit takers, one
regulator for federally chartered institutions, and one for
state-chartered federally insured institutions sounds simpler and
more logical to me.

I think all of these issues will be visited by the Congress
in the next 12 to 18 months.

The debate and ensuing legislation

may be as important to the future of banking and of the country
as the National Banking Act of 1863, the Federal Reserve Act of
1913, and the several pieces of banking legislation in the mid1930s.

It will be a big debate.

Let us not hesitate to

13

participate, keeping in mind that what is right for the United
States overrides any parochial interests which any of us might
have.

Thank you for inviting me to be with you.