View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOUSING

AND THE

NATIONAL

ECONOMY

Remarks of
John J. Balles, President
Federal

Mortgage




Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Bankers Association of Northern California
San Francisco, California

December 10, 1975

Housing and the National Economy
I !m delighted to have the chance to discuss business and financial
trends with a group which plays such an important role in the state's
economy.

In glancing over your association's brochure, I was impressed

with the description of the role of mortgage bankers, "as catalysts
between the sources of funds and the developers wh o translate drawings
into b u i l d i n g s / 1

I was even more impressed with the figures which show

how well the industry has prospered in the difficult years of the past
decade, with servicing volume in the state rising from $14 billion to
$27 billion b e t ween 1967 and 1974 alone.

Wit h the housing market now

improving, I would expect this strong uptrend to continue.
My assignment today is to analyze the factors that will affect the
national economy--especially housing--during 1976.

Right at the outset,

let m e say that the recovery from the "worst postwar recession" is p r o ­
ceeding on schedule.

Yet, as always seems inevitable in such situations,

we will be faced for some time to come with the wreckage created by the
recession and the preceding inflationary excesses.
for financial-page headline writers.

It's been a field day

Y o u know the list:

W. T. Grant

down to its last five-and-dime; the airlines fast losing altitude; the
tanker industry on the rocks; the jerry-built REIT's being foreclosed;
and N e w Y o r k City desperately trying to sell Brooklyn Bridge.
But the dominant fact, to repeat, is that the recovery is in place,
with production, profits and employment rising substantially in recent
months.

As we move into 1976, consumer spending, inventory stockpiling

and foreign purchases should help support the recovery, providing the




2

basis for a relatively strong increase of

percent in real GNP.

But

what of the other sectors of the economy--especially the long-depressed
housing industry?

Consider first where the industry stands today.

During

the third quarter, residential construction outlays posted a healthy a d ­
vance in real terms, following a modest turnaround in the previous quarter
and the precipitous two-year slide before that.

This increase in outlays

reflected a significant improvement in housing starts, w h ich averaged
1.25 m i l l i o n units (annual rate) in the third quarter--and even higher
in October--in contrast to the average of 1 million units or less in the
first half of the year.

According to m y s t a f f 1s economic forecast, the

average level of starts next year might be one-third higher than the 1975
average--about 1.57 m i l l i o n starts, as compared to this y e a r fs estimated
1.18 m i l l i o n units.

But these figures indicate that further increases

may be rather mode s t after the recent rise.

This is understandable, in

vi e w of the rather mixed nature of the statistics indicating the health
of the industry.
The Housing Outlook
To begin with, the inventory of unsold and uncompleted units remains
rather high.

Despite the obvious improvement in home sales since last

spring, the inventory of unsold single-family housing has declined only
moderately to about 375,000 units, which represents an 8%-month supply
at recent sales rates.

As for multiples, we lack precise information on

the unsold inventory--but we do know that starts of m u lti-family housing,
despite the recent upturn, are still only about one-third of the level
reached during the 1970-73 boom.




And there are signs that the recovery

3

in this sector ma y be rather slow, considering the reluctance of lenders
to finance the construction of condos, a s well as the continued high level
of vacancies in the rental market.
Another important housing factor, the cost factor, has been improving
recently.

Average construction prices stabilized during the third quarter,

reflecting some improvement in materials costs and (apparently) some r e d u c ­
tion in the size and furnishings of n e w units.

Sales prices of n e w homes

also have levelled off, at about a $38,900 median, although the 9-percent
rise over the past year has outpaced the rise in household income.

The

market in 1976 of course would benefit from a stabilization of home prices
and a continued rise in incomes, but some of this impact could be offset
by a continued rise in the overall costs of home ownership.
A more important question concerns the cost and availability of
credit--the lifeblood of housing.

As you know, money has generally been

available this year, but at very high costs by historical standards.
same may well be true in 1976.

The

Although rates on F N M A commitments fell

by about 20 basis points in October, that decline offset only a part of
the 80-basis point increase that occurred during the third quarter,
leaving yields in this market at 9.32 percent in early November.

And

no matter h o w attractive such high rates may be to investors, they cut
severely into the potential market for housing.

For example, with the

last decade*s increase in mortgage rates from roughly 5% percent to 9%
percent, the monthly payment on a typical 3 0 -year, $30,000 m o rtgage has
jumped by half, because of that factor alone.

The continuation of very high mortgage rates reflects the heavy
competition for funds in long-term markets and, above all, the lender’
s




4

demand for a substantial premium to offset the effects of inflation.
say more about that subject in a minute.

I'll

Nov, i t fs true that the m o r t g a g e

industry has been veil able to compete for funds in the present env i r o n ­
ment.

Thrift institutions will probably garner a record inflow of savings

in 1975--probably more than $40 billion--and they could approach that
figure again in 1976.

Even so, the competition for funds will probably

become stiffer over time, with corporations, state and local governments
and (above all) the Federal government all entering the mar k e t w i t h very
heavy borrowing demands.

Government and Housing
Of course, support to the market will be available from various
Federal programs.

Should the housing market falter during 1976, strong

pressures would arise in Congress to beef up such programs, adding to
the already m a s sive Federal presence in the market.
defeating element in this approach.

But there's a self-

Federal programs can help housing

in the short-run, but in the long run they only exacerbate the industry's
basic problems.

Housing activity always falters in periods of high and

rising interest rates, but rates are pushed up by the need to finance
soaring Federal deficits--which in turn are caused by increased g o v e r n ­
ment spending for housing and other purposes.
Federal government support has been a mainstay of the mark e t for
over a generation; for instance, with FHA-insured and VA-guaranteed m o r t ­
gages accounting last year for 28 percent of total mortgage debt on oneto-four family properties.

But government support has burgeoned during

the past decade--a period which included the credit crunches of 1966,
1969 and 1 9 7 3-74— with mortgag e - l o a n holdings supported by various govern-




5

ment agencies and programs increasing about 25 percent annually over this
period.

Government and related agencies held 13 percent of the nation*s

outstanding residential-mortgage debt at the end of 1974, but in that one
year alone, they supported 54 percent of the entire loan increase.
The pressure for an increased government role is evident in the House
Banking Committee1s recent report on Financial Institutions and the Nation*s
Economy--the FINE study.

Like the Hunt Commission of several years ago,

this study group is in favor of giving thrift institutions broader lending
powers and removing ceilings from their deposit rates, provided that the
assumption of such new powers is accompanied by acceptance of a common
set of rules and restrictions.

For example, all Federally-insured de­

positary institutions would have to meet reserve requirements on their
deposit liabilities, with all such reserves being held at the Federal
Reserve.

As for housing, the FINE study*s authors go beyond the Hunt

Commission and argue that broadened powers would not be sufficient to
produce more money for the housing market--especially low-cost housing-and that further incentives are needed.
One such incentive would be a mortgage-interest tax credit, availa­
ble to any financial institution, but restricted to mortgages on prop­
erties designed for low- and moderate-income owners and renters.

A

second incentive would be the broadening of Home Loan Bank lending at
subsidized rates for low-cost housing, again available to any financial
institution.

Furthermore, the Federal Reserve would be authorized to

provide reserve credits to all depository institutions involved in finan­
cing low- and moderate-income housing.

For each dollar of reserves held

at the Fed, each institution would receive a reserve credit equal to a




6

fixed percentage of its dollar volume of mortgage and residential-construction loans.

Under this credit-allocation scheme, low-cost housing would

have a preferred status over all other seekers of bank credit.
All of these Federal programs--present and proposed--only tend to
get the Federal government more deeply enmeshed in the operations of the
housing market.

I would prefer to see a more direct attack on the basic

cause of housing's woes--the prolonged inflation of the past decade,
which has pushed market interest rates to unprecedented highs.

Housing

is always the most sensitive sector in the economy to tight money and
high interest rates, since the level of the mortgage rate is much more
critical in limiting the ability of the home buyer to carry such debt
than is the interest rate on any other type of borrowing.

The problem is

compounded by the fact that mortgage funds become not only expensive but
practically nonexistent during credit crunches, since the principal sources
of mortgage money find their own money flows drying up or turning nega­
tive whenever short-term money rates rise above the ceiling rates that
they can pay investors.

Part of the problem thus is the long-run inef­

fectiveness of Reg Q ceilings, but the basic problem of course is inflation.
Government and Inflation
Our severe inflation problem has been attributed to many factors,
such as oil embargoes, food shortages, dollar devaluation, and price and
wage rigidities in concentrated industries.

But the basic cause is the

long series of soaring Federal deficits and its impact on financial m a r ­
kets.

It's no accident that housing's problems, and the intensified

Federal efforts to support housing, have gone hand in hand with the in­
tensified deficit spending of the past decade.




The basic difficulty has

7

been the failure of Federal budget-makers to find the funds to pay for
the growing responsibilities they have taken on, and it has been a g g r a ­
vated by the impact of inflation on man y spending programs.

The problem

threatens to swamp the ne w Congressional budget committees at the very
inception of their activities, but it is one which they must grasp and
bring under control.
Mor e Federal spending would aggravate the pressures already evident
in financial markets, wit h unparalleled Federal demands piled on top of
gradually reviving private credit demands.

This is the well-publicized

and all-too-real problem of "crowding out."

It's true that financial

conditions n o r mally ease substantially during a recession and remain
easy even in the initial recovery period.

But with the Federal deficit

reaching $75 billion or more, total credit demands could outrun the
available supply of funds, forcing interest rates higher and crowding
man y non-Federal borrowers out of the market.

W e 've already had a sam­

ple of what could happen with the third-quarter bulge in rates.

Even with

the recent easing, Treasury bill rates still hover near 5% percent-unusually hig h levels for this stage of the business cycle, and a portent
of disintermediation if credit demands quicken.
One way that mo u n t i n g credit demands can be satisfied without an
increase in interest rates is for the Federal Reserve to accelerate the
growth of mon e y and credit.

But if done for too long, or to an ex c e s ­

sive degree, such an action could generate inflationary pressures which
would soon become imbedded in the nation's price structure.

Still, many

people reply, with so man y idle resources in the economy, h o w could in­
flationary pressures arise from easy money at this stage?




8

The answer, at least in part, involves the lags in the effects of
monetary policy.

Generally speaking, whenever an excessively easy-money

policy is adopted, the "good news" appears first, with production, em­
ployment and profits expanding within six to twelve months or so--but
then the "bad news" arrives, in the form of increased inflation with a
lag of one to three years.

Conversely, if a tight-money policy is

adopted, the bad news of a dampening of economic activity comes first,
whereas the good news of a diminished rate of inflation is delayed.
For this reason, the Federal Reserve at this stage of the business
cycle is strongly alert to price considerations.

At the same time, it

is also strongly alert to the need to provide the financial basis for
continued recovery.

In a word, we are determined to m a i n t a i n a prudent

but not parsimonious mo n e t a r y policy.

This stance is seen in the m o n e ­

tary growth path that the Fed is attempting to follow between the third
quarter of 1975 and the third quarter of 1976--that is, a 5-to-7% percent
growth rate for the

m e a s u r e of the m o n e y supply (currency plus demand

deposits).
This range is quite appropriate in the present environment of high
unemployment and unused industrial capacity.

On the other hand, it is

on the generous side by long-term historical standards.

Thus, w e could

endanger the fight against inflation if we continued expanding the money
supply indefinitely at today's specified pace.

I mig h t add that the

directors of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco are fully alert
to this situation, since they v i e w inflation as the nation's No. 1
problem.

As the economy returns to higher rates of resource utilization,

we'll have to reduce the rate of m o netary and credit expansion, in order
to lay the foundation for a prolonged e r a of prosperity w i t h o u t inflation.




Concluding Remarks
To sum up, it appears likely that the economy will strengthen further

in 1976, on the basis of the improvement already evident in the consumer
and inventory sectors--and in residential construction as well.

But as

I 1vc indicated, housing may not be as strong a support as it has been in
earlier recovery period?-,*

The housing boom of the early 1970/s has left,

as its legacy, both an overly high level of costs and an overly large
inventory of unsold u n i t s .

The severe inflation of the past decade

meanwhile has left, as its legacy, a m o r t g a g e -finaneing m e c h a n i s m that
is both overly subject to disintermediation and overly dependent on go v e r n ­
ment support.
In 1976, w e 1re likely to see a gradual increase in the credit demands
of mortgage borrowers and other private borrowers.

H o w the market handles

these demands depends critically on the size of the Federal deficit.

Even

with the deficit held under Congressional target levels, there could be
periods of market congestion as the year goes on.

The first task of p o l ­

icymakers thus is to bring Federal credit demands under control.

Other-

e, "crowding out" could become a painful reality--and we all know
-h industry would be the first casualty in that situation.




# # # #