View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

i

THE
ENVIRONMENT
FOR
MUNICIPAL
___FINANCING







ten
hftz.

John J. Balles

I am delighted to join you here today
for a discussion of the econom ic and
financial factors that will affect your
activities in the year ahead. I would add,
however, that a better location for this
particular session might be Pali Pass. For
those who are unfamiliar with Hawaii­
an history, that's the spot where a hardpressed defending army once found itself
with King Kamehameha’s advancing
army in the front and a steep precipice at
its back. Every municipal treasurer would
feel right at home there.
The analogy is not too far-fetched, since
all governmental units have been
caught these past two years between the
grinding attack of inflation and the steep
decline of recession. In my remarks, I
would like to discuss how those two
forces helped create the fiscal problems
of state-and-local governments, as well as
the near-crisis situation in the municipal


bond market. Certainly the problems of
the state-local sector are crucial to the
national economy, because of both its
rapid growth and present size; this sector
has grown twice as fast as the rest of the
economy in the past decade and a half,
and now employs 16 percent of the
nonfarm workforce.
Surprisingly, hardly anyone foresaw the
oncom ing crisis several years ago. Just
as the Vietnam peace dividend was
supposed to ease the Federal government’s
financing problems, so the revenuesharing dividend was supposed to solve
the problems of state-local government
finance during the 1970’s. Budget surpluses
were projected—and for a brief time
actually realized— partly because of
increased aid from Washington, and
also because of such factors as a wide­
spread increase in tax rates and a falling
real demand for costly educational
services.
Effects of Inflation and Recession
The financial situation has now changed
considerably, with expenditures rising
sharply and revenues lagging substan­
tially. Consider first the expenditure
side. Inflation has boosted the cost of
governmental goods and services, and has
helped account for the strong drive by
public-em ployee unions for large wage
increases. At the same time, recession has
increased the demand for welfare and
other services.
Now look at the revenue side. Inflation
has reduced the real impact of the $30billion revenue-sharing program, which
incorporated an inflation factor far
smaller than the actual rate of price
increase. Inflation also has meant a loss in
revenues, in real terms, from that half of the



state-local tax structure which normally
responds slowly or not at all to rising
prices— meaning gasoline, liquor and
property taxes. The recession slow-down
in business activity meanwhile has meant a
slower flow of revenues from income
and sales taxes, in contrast to their usual
tendency to expand at least proportion­
ately with rising activity.
The result has been a rising tide of red
ink across the land. State-and-local
governments in the aggregate have
moved into deficit, despite legal or tradi­
tional rules against deficit financing.
Indeed, if we ignore the surpluses run
up by their pension funds and consider
operating budgets alone, we see that stateand-local governments as a group have
been running deficits for the last several
decades, except for the initial revenuesharing period of several years ago. In the
aggregate, state-local operating budgets
shifted from a $10-billion surplus to an
$11-billion annual deficit between late
1972 and early 1975.
Short-term Solutions
This situation, as you know, has forced
governmental units everywhere to
adopt hard-nosed cost-reduction pro­
grams during the past year or so. In earlier
business downturns, most jurisdic­
tions wereabie to cope by making minor
adjustments; for example, by spending
previously accumulated surpluses or mani­
pulating budgets through shifts in timing
of receipts and expenditures. Today,
however, there are no more surpluses
to spend, and no more room for fiscal
sleight-of-hand. Rigid economy is the
order of the day, as can be seen from
the $8 billion worth of tax increases,
service cutbacks, and capital-construction reductions scheduled for this year.



According to a recent survey by the
Congressional Joint Economic C om ­
mittee, state governments plan to make $4
billion in adjustments, either by raising
taxes or reducing services, while local
governments plan to make $3 billion in
similar adjustments and together, they
will delay or cancel roughly $1 billion in
capital-construction projects. The C o n ­
gressional survey suggested that the
problem centered in the larger metro­
politan areas, but a follow-up survey by
the National League of Cities found that the
same problem existed among small and
medium-sized cities. The League report­
ed that one-third of the cities surveyed
had cut payrolls already through layoffs or
other means, almost one-half had sched­
uled tax increases, and over one-half
had postponed essential capital
expenditures.
A number of solutions have been
proposed for state-local fiscal problems,
most of them involving injections of
Federal money. Some of the alternatives
include an expanded public-service em­
ployment program, an accelerated
public-works program, or expanded
revenue-sharing or other grants pro­
grams. Some of these programs have merit,
but the general approach tends to
evade the issue by shifting the problem
back to the general taxpayer. It's been
suggested also, in New York City's case,
that the Federal Reserve should come to
the aid of beleaguered communities.
But this proposal, aside from ignoring
the fact that the System's special lending
powers are narrowly circumscribed by law,
could undermine the nation's financial
strength by setting a precedent for the
Fed to support all types of public and
private credit demands, at the cost of future
inflation. The only useful solution in the



long run is t o cure the underlying evils of
inflation and recession— the evils
which created the governmental financ­
ing problem in the first place.
Problems of Recession
This leads to the basic question— can we
achieve a strong econom ic recovery with­
out inflation? I can't say yes unequivocal­
ly, but the prospects are much brighter
now than they were a few short months
ago. First of all, the upturn definitely
seems to be underway. The leading indica­
tors of business activity have been
giving off favorable signals for the past
four months, and the indexes of current
activity have now reinforced those earlier
signals. Industrial production turned up
in June, and an even broader m e a su re real GNP— practically stabilized in the
second quarter after the most prolonged
and most severe decline of the past 40
years. Some significant problems re­
main, of course. Although the number
of jobs has increased in recent months,
almost 81/2 percent of the labor force is
unemployed, and more than one million
of the 8 million jobless have been
looking unsuccessfully for work since
the beginning of the year. Roughly onethird of the theoretical capacity of the
nation's industrial plant remains unuti­
lized, and this has caused corporate
planners to reverse gears and slash away at
their budgets for new plant and
equipment.
Nonetheless, the script for recovery has
already been written, especially in the
form of the spring upturn in consumer
expenditures. In real terms, consumer
spending rose at more than a 6 -percent
annual rate during that period, reflect­
ing an unparalleled 25-percent rate of
gain in real disposable income, which



offset practically all of the prolonged
income decline since late 1973.
Take-home pay was boosted about $48
billion this spring by the provisions of the
Tax Reduction Act, including actual tax
cuts as well as increases in social-security
and other transfer payments. That stimu­
lus was reinforced by a slowing of the
inflation rate, which also helped boost
real income. Admittedly, little of this
strength has shown up in the crucial
auto and housing industries, but the
upsurge in buying power creates the
groundwork now for a strong rise in
other household-budget categories,
and later on for an upturn in those two
depressed sectors as well.
A second major element in the recovery
script is the prospective turnaround in
business spending for inventories. This
sector was the weakest link in the severe
slump of last winter and spring, but
because of its self-correcting nature, it
should be one of the stronger elements of
the outlook for the next year or so. Business
inventories declined at more than a $26billion rate in the first half of this year, so
that stock-room shelves have now
been cleared of most of their excess
supplies. With final demand now rising,
businessmen should begin ordering
more inventory, cautiously at first and
then more confidently. Also, as consumer
buying continues to rise and as inventory
restocking begins, businessmen will be
forced to restart some of their idled
production lines. Rising demands on
capacity, plus the increased investment
tax credit, should then lead businessmen to
resuscitate some of their now-dormant capitalspending plans. O n the basis of this un­
folding scenario, real GNP could increase as
much as 8 percent by a year from now.



Problems of Inflation
From all that I've said, it would seem that
the recession danger to state-andmunicipal finances will gradually be
overcome during the nextyear. But what
of the inflation danger? First the good
news. The annual rate of inflation declined
during the second quarter almost to the 5percent level, far below the 14V2-percent
peak rate of late 1974. But the bad news
is just as important. There’s no guarantee
that we can push the inflation rate below 5
percent, and judging from some earlysummer developments, we may be
hard-pressed to keep the rate from rising
again, at least temporarily. Food prices
recently have risen sharply, and they
could continue to do so in the wake of
heavy export sales to the Russians and
other overseas buyers. Fuel prices could
jump again in the event of another price
increase by the O PEC oil cartel, or even
in the event of sudden decontrol of the
domestic market, necessary as that move
would be for the sake of a rational energy
policy. Industrial prices also are stirring
again—witness the aluminum industry,
the rubber industry, and the hints from
Detroit of boosts in 1976 auto model
prices.
However, it’s not the increases in
individual sectors of the economy that
we have to worry about; these happen
every day in response to specific market
forces. The danger is an upsurge generat­
ed by the same basic forces that have
been behind the powerful groundswell of prices throughout the past
decade; that is, unparalleled Federal
budget deficits and a necessarily ac­
commodative monetary policy. The
portents are not entirely favorable. The
largest deficit in history ($59 billion) is in
prospect for fiscal 1976 because of the tax



cut, the recession-caused decline in
revenues, and the substantial rise in
new expenditures. Moreover, the A dm in­
istration calculates that the deficit could
actually go as high as $88 billion if
Congress extends recent tax cuts, ig­
nores Administration spending-cut re­
quests?, and passes new spending bills now
pending in Congress.
Such a development would aggravate
the pressures already evident in financial
markets, with unparalleled Federal de­
mands piled on top of gradually reviving
private credit demands. Some observers
argue that the Federal Reserve should
try to ensure that all borrowing de­
mands (both Federal and private) are
accommodated at stable or declining
interest rates. Such an approach, by
flooding the markets with liquidity,
could prevent current credit-market
strains but at the expense of fueling
inflation anew as the recovery builds up
steam. The end result of this renewed
inflation would be a continued fiscal
crisis for every governmental unit in
the land.
A related and even more immediate
problem is the danger of Federal “ crowd­
ing out” of other borrowers in the nation’s
credit markets. It's true that financial
conditions normally ease substantially
during a recession and remain easy
even in the initial recovery period. But if
the Federal deficit substantially exceeds the
Administration’s proposed figure, total
credit dem andscould rapidly outrun the
available supply of funds, forcing interest
rates higher and crowding many nonFederal borrowers out of the market. I
don’t need to remind you that the most
likely losers in this game of musical
chairs would be state-and-and local



governments, along with mortgage
borrowers.
We've received a hint recently of what
could happen along this line. The anti­
recession program, with its outpouring of
Treasury funds into private deposits,
helped bring about a 141/2-percent
annual rate of growth in the money
supply during May and June. Since this
rate of expansion was far outside of the
Federal Reserve's 5-to- 7V2 percent
target range, the Fed moved to offset the
m oney-supply bulge in the course of its
regular open-market activities. But in the
wake of this action to avert future
inflationary pressures, short-term inter­
est rates suddenly rose by a full
percentage point, and fears of renewed
credit stringency (however unwarranted)
began to surface again.
Problems of Municipal Financing
All these intense fiscal pressures and
renewed inflation fears have surfaced
recently in the muni-bond market.
Faced with massive operating deficits
and forced to allocate more and more of
their revenue-sharing funds simply to
cover current expenses, state-andlocal governments have had to raise
record amounts of funds in the capital
market at record interest rates. But their
marketing task has been complicated by
the disappearance of many traditional
purchasers, either because of more
attractive investing opportunities else­
where or because of fears regarding the
safety of investments in certain m unici­
pal issues.
New tax-exempt issues this year could
easily exceed the 1971 peak of $25 billion.
How much could be marketed today at
lower interest costs is anybody's guess,



since state-and-local governments—
unlike the Federal government— are quite
sensitive to the yields they must pay on
their debts. Although interest-ceiling
laws have been liberalized, other consid­
erations (such as voter referenda) make
many governmental units reluctant to
issue debt at very high interest costs.
Yields generally have remained quite high
in the capital market this year. This reflects
in part the investment community's
demand for a significant inflation premi­
um, and in part the heavy borrowing
requirements of corporations and (espe­
cially) the Federal government. Still, the
pressures undoubtedly are greater in the
tax-exempt sector of the market than
elsewhere. O ne symptom of course is
today's extremely high level of tax-exempt
yields. Another symptom is the devel­
opment of a definite two-tier market,
with investors turning their backs on
lower-quality issues. Thus, while the spread
between Aaa and Baa tax-exempt yields
averaged about 60 basis points in the
earlier years of this decade, the spread
this spring was more than 100 basis points.
The most obvious example of course is
New York City, which is playing the same
destabilizing role in the tax-exempt
market that Con Ed played in the corporate
market last year. This spring, New York
had to pay 8.69 percent on an issue of
bond-anticipation notes, or about 200
basis points more than the average taxexempt yield at that time, and soon
thereafter the city found it all but
impossible to get money at any price.
When the city approached the brink of
bankruptcy, the state legislature created
the M unicipal Assistance Corporation,
and authorized Big M acto issue as much
as $3 billion in long-term debt in order



to repay a like amount of the city’s short­
term debt. The idea was to give the city
enough breathing space so that it could
balance its books, regain the confidence
of investors, and resume borrowing on its
own next fall. But as you've noticed, the
new agency has had considerable trouble
marketing its own issues, even though
the city's sales-tax and stock-transfer
tax revenues are earmarked for its debtservice payments. It used to be that Big Mac
brought to mind the image of a deluxe
hamburger with all the trimmings; today
all the trimmings are gone.
With problems such as these, investors are
not exactly rushing forward to buy taxexempt issues, except at very high
yields. Besides, the usual participants in
this market have other reasons for staying
on the sidelines this year. Fire-andcasualty insurance firms have been
limiting their commitments because of
recent unprofitable operations. Com m er­
cial banks, who had taken down more
than two-thirds of all new issues at the
beginning of the decade, reduced their
share to only one-fourth of the total last
year—and more recently they have be­
come net liquidators of municipals.
Apparently this is more than the usual
cyclical phenomenon; although they are
traditionally the dominant factor in the taxexempt market, commercial banks may
become much smaller purchasers as
time goes on.
Banks now have greater offsets to taxable
income than in earlier periods, and
hence they don’t need as much taxexempt income from municipals. These
offsets include some of the increase in
loan-loss reserves which many banks have
arranged as a result of the recession.
Also, bank holding companies en­



gaged in leasing activities are able to
generate large depreciation expenses,
while those banks with established
foreign branches are able to generate
foreign tax credits, in both cases further
limiting their need for tax-exempt income.
Besides, in this period of uncertainty
where default becomes an ever-present
threat in the municipal market, banks
logically prefer to rebuild their portfolios
mainly with the safest possible investment,
U.S. Treasuries. And with the Federal
deficit at its present size, they obviously
have no difficulty in finding enough
Treasuries to buy.
Consequently, the municipal market has
been forced to rely heavily on the
relatively small number of wealthy indi­
vidual investors for whom the taxexemption feature is an advantage.
These individuals act only at unusually
attractive yields, as in 1969 or 1974-75.
With such a narrow base, the market
apparently needs restructuring to attract a
broader group of investors. The market
in its infinite wisdom has already come
up with one possible solution— taxexempt bond funds. These funds have
been tailored for the large number of
individuals with relatively high incomes
but not much wealth, permitting them to
avoid the usual drawbacks to muni-bond
purchases, such as high minimumpurchase requirements and lack of
portfolio diversity. Rates of return on
muni-bond funds have now reached a
level that is attractive to middle-incom e
families, with income around $18,000 a
year. As a result, sales of these funds
were almost as great in the first half of this
year as they were in all of 1974.
A more basic means of widening the
market would be to grant state-and-




local governments the option of issuing
taxable bonds, with a direct Treasury
subsidy making up for the higher
interest cost of such securities. (This
option of course would not replace their
present right to issue tax-exempt bonds.)
Pension funds, life-insurance companies
and other investors who are uninterest­
ed in the tax-exemption feature would
probably enter the market once this step
was taken. But the argument for reform has
broader aspects. Critics of the present
system claim that if Federal assistance for
state-and-local governments is a legiti­
mate goal— as seems likely in view of the
$54 billion in grants budgeted for this
fiscal year—then it should be accom ­
plished through direct rather than
indirect means. At present, the Federal
government loses more than $4 billion in
revenues annually from the unpaid
taxes investors normally would pay on
bond-interest income, while states and
municipalities gain perhaps no more than
$3 billion from the lower level of interest
rates they pay on tax-exempt securities.
Reformers thus claim that the Federal
government loses much more than stateand-local governments gain in the form of
lower interest costs. O n the other
hand, many observers argue that the taxexemption privilege is a basic constitu­
tional right, going back to the Supreme
Court's decision in 1819 in M cCulloch vs.
Maryland. In this view, if the Federal
government begins to pay some sub­
stantial share of the interest on municipal
debt, it might next move to exercise control
over the issuance of that debt. These
observers thus fear a definite threat to
the sovereignty and independence of
state-and-local governments.
Any attempt to reconcile these conflict­
ing viewpoints should include several




basic safeguards. State-and-local govern­
ments must preserve their freedom to act,
independent of Federal control, on
matters of purely state-and-local con­
cern. Moreover, any Federal interest
subsidy must be automatic and irrevocable,
and at least as generous as the present
financial advantage which the states and
municipalities enjoy by virtue of tax
exemption. In practice, a governmental
agency— at its own option— might ask
underwriters for bids on both a taxable
and nontaxable basis, accepting the bid
with the lowest net interest cost. The
issuing agency thus would have the ability
to utilize whichever segment of the
market that provides it with the broadest
access to funds.
Concluding Remarks
Measures for broadening the market
represent only one aspect of the desper­
ately needed cure for state-local finan­
cing problems. I suggested at the outset
that there is no long-run solution to these
problems without a cure for the basic
ills— recession and inflation—that are
now wracking the entire national econo­
my. But there's more involved than that. A
glance at those communities that
manage to operate within their budgets,
despite all sorts of econom ic difficulties,
suggests that good management is an
essential element in the overall solution.
A basic requirement for every govern­
mental jurisdiction is to give constant
attention to appropriate levels of taxes,
wages, pensions and services.
Still, the most crucial requirement is an
unremitting attack on inflation. It is
inflation that has caused the worst budget
distortions for state-and-local govern­
ments, forcing them into increased
reliance on capital markets—which



with their inflationary high yields, then
consign these borrowers to the end of the
queue. Other borrowers are also
affected by this type of predicament, but
perhaps none so much as state-and-local
governments. To break out of that vicious
circle, we must severely limit the size of
Federal deficits, first in order to reduce
the inflationary pressures generated by
on-the-cuff spending, and second in
order to reduce the capital-market pres­
sures which limit so severely the scope of
municipal borrowing.
I don't wish to end on a gloomy note, and I
certainly don’t intend to give any support
to those investors who would simply
dump their muni-bond portfolios.
State-and-local governments generally
were in good shape in the early years of this
decade; thus, for most of them, the
basic problem tends to be cyclical rather
than structural in nature. The market is
trying to put across one simple message—
namely, that a return to fiscal health
requires strong management policies at
the local level, as well as strong anti­
recessionary and (above all) antiinflationary policies at the Federal level.