View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE ROLE OF STRUCTURE IN ECONOMIC DECISION-MAKING
Dr. Jerry Jordan (Speech Version: J0RDAN5)
National Association of Business Economists, Cleveland Chapter
September 23, 1992
I. The Value of Economist's Opinions
I learned early in my career as a business economist that perhaps the
worst answer an economist can give to a question is; "I don't know".

And

having spent much of my life in the company of economists, I can honestly say
it is a response I've not often heard.

I am reminded of the remark Walter

Heller once made of Milton Friedman--"I wish I was as certain about anything
as Milton Friedman is about everything."

And so it i s , I suppose, we may be a

profession that is frequently wrong, but we're never in doubt.
But the value of an economist's opinion is not in it's "correctness"
in the sense that we can always, or perhaps not even often, foresee the
chaotic patterns in economic events.
As I started to make notes for this talk, I thought about the
criticism directed at business economists and their forecasts.
basically two types of criticism.
forecast very accurately.

There are

The first is simply that economists don't

The second criticism, which is usually directed

from the academic community, is that economists should not be expected to
forecast because the pursuit of self-interest on the part of millions of
people with 'rational expectations' implies that there is no model that
provides a basis for saying anything about the future with consistent
accuracy.

2
To say Chat economic forecasting can't be done is ludicrous. To borrow
from Descartes,

"I exist, therefore I forecast."

No human action, whether

economic or otherwise, is made without at least an implicit assumption about
future events.

The choices individuals make involve intertemporal

considerations, so an opinion about future events is implied in their
behavior.

Often what the forecaster is doing is helping to make explicit, and

internally consistent, what otherwise was implicit in the actions of society.
Arguing that economic forecasting shouldn't be done is equally absurd.
Academic economists often malign the worth of forecasts even though the single
unifying principle in our science is that consumers, motivated by self
interest, generally determine what will be produced and producers, motivated
by profit, endeavor to satisfy that demand.
of value than that given in the marketplace.

I know of no better determination
We need only consider the large

number of competing forecasts and the expense of producing this information to
appreciate that if forecasters even marginally reduce uncertainty about future
business conditions, the savings to business is potentially huge.
Nevertheless, I believe that economists' ability to predict
macroeconomic variables is a poor standard by which to evaluate most economic
models, and an even poorer standard by which to judge the contribution of
business economists, and we must not equate economists' forecasting record
with the presumption that the role of business economists has been diminished,
or that as a profession, economists have in large measure failed to add value
to decisionmaking.

3

What, then, is the value added by the opinions of economists? It is,
I believe, our ability to provide a model, a structure, to a complex economic
environment.
I use the term 'structure' here in the sense that our judgements are
based on a logically consistent framework.

And, such a structure is not

necessarily built with the goal of foretelling the future.

Imagine you're at

a ballgame, and consider the question; can you see the game better if you
stand up?

The quick answer is yes, of course.

lacks the structure of a model.

But, this answer obviously

An economist understands that our ability to

see depends upon the combined actions of those around you, and if your action
of standing induces those around you to stand, your sight will be obstructed.
This is what we mean by a "general equilibrium" framework.

This is the proper

answer, I think, even though it is likely to be a poor forecasting device.
People frequently stand at public events.

II. Forecasting and the Policymaking Process.
Ultimately, a model must be judged by it's usefulness.

And in some

cases, usefulness is defined by the ability to predict future events.

For

example, time-series models, which possess a mathematical structure but no
economic theory, have little value other than their ability to provide a
forecast.

But clearly, there is no such thing as the best model, for "best"

must always be defined in terms of the use to which the model is being
applied.

4

We are all familiar with, and have, perhaps, taken comfort in the
classic debate between Ptolemy's model of the solar system, which placed the
earth in the center, and Copernicus' model, which put the sun in the center.
The Ptolemic view was based on the moral assertion that the center was the
only proper place for the earth to be, and consequently, where we wanted it to
be.

Despite the glaring inability of the Ptolemic view to conform with the

celestial evidence--obvious flaws of the model known to the scientific
community at the time--it nevertheless provided reasonably accurate forecasts
of the movements of the planets and was therefore popularly used.
Fundamental to all economic analysis, then, is the simple question;
To what end is this model to be applied?
to know?

Or, even more simply; Why do we want

Herein lies and important difference between forecasting in the

private sector and forecasting in the public sector.
At a recent conference, I was approached by a business reporter and
asked the question:
flip response was,

"What's your outlook for the economy?"
"I don't have one."

face was that of disbelief.

My unintentionally

The quizzical look on the reporter's

How is it that someone who has always had an

economic outlook in the past, now rather suddenly is unable, or unwilling, to
see into the future, particularly when that person is now in a policy-making
position?
The answer to that question is at the center of the policy-making
debate in the country, I think.

Why is it that I no longer find value in

5

business cycle forecasCing when just a few months ago such information was an
indispensable tool of my work?

Quite simply, it's because as a policymaker, I

don't need one.
In the private sector, forecasts are used as devices not only to
reduce uncertainty, but as a framework for comprehending the risks that
business should be aware of, and if possible, protect against.

Unfolding

economic events affect the probabilities of alternate economic states that
eventually impact business profitability.

As a business economist for a bank

whose goal is to maximize the wealth of its shareholders, a potential tilt in
the term structure of interest rates, a shift in loan demand, or a change in
the probability of borrower default, are contingencies that need to be
evaluated and acted upon.

A commercial bank cannot put together a profit plan

or prepare a budget without assumptions about future interest rates, deposit
growth, and numerous other variables.

But, this is not true for the economic

policymaker.
Two years ago tomorrow, Alan Greenspan addressed the annual meeting of
this organization on the topic of forecasting.

"The policy forecaster," he

said, "necessarily focuses on those aspects of the economy that policy most
directly influences."^-

So the role of forecasting in the public sector, it

would seem, is as a conduit of control.

* * * * * * * * * * * * *
1
Alan Greenspan, "Economic Forecasting in the Private and Public Sectors,"
Annual meeting of the National Association of Business Economists, Washington
D.C., September 24, 1990.

6

Regarding the act of forecasting as a control device forces us to
clearly identify those variables that are endogenous to the system and those
that are exogenous.

For the policymaker, that means we must distinguish those

outcomes which we can predictably influence from those which we only wish we
could!
We can think of the policy setting process in three parts:

(1) a goal,

(2) controllable instruments, and finally (3) a model linking instruments to
the goal.

As I review my own experiences with of the policymaking process, I

recall the 1970's as a time when the system attempted to manage real economic
events by judiciously altering the federal funds rate.

Stabilizing short-run

fluctuations in the business cycle and maintaining a low rate of unemployment
among our citizenry are, without question, admirable goals.

And, I certainly

recognize that the Federal Reserve has been able to control the federal funds
rate when it chooses to (although I have never accepted this instrument as an
appropriate policy indicator.)
But, like a C o p e m i c a n in a Ptolemic world, I believe there are
logical flaws in a model that presumes to link the level of short-run nominal
interest rates to GDP and employment growth.

This Phillips curve (or "gap"

model), is founded on an empirical observation that we all know to be
theoretically flawed in the sense that it is not consistent with fully
informed, optimizing behavior.

And, as control mechanisms, gap models proved

to be unstable when policymakers attempted to exploit the economic

7

inefficiencies they implied, eventually contributing to exaggerated business
cycles and reduced productivity growth.

To rephrase an old expression, in the

long run, it made us dead.

III. The Importance of Long-Run Structure to Policy-making
The lessons of the 1970s pointed the way to a new procedure for the
implementation of monetary policy.

In 1980, the Federal Open Market Committee

expressly recognized the limits of monetary management, confessing that it is
not within the powers of policy to always ensure a fully satisfactory economic
performance.

"Nonetheless, the appropriate direction of policy is clear.

The

greatest contribution the monetary and fiscal authorities can make is to
impart a sense of long-range stability in policy and in the economic
environment."^
Chief among Fed objectives was the restoration of price stability, or
in the words of the 1980 monetary Report to Congress;

"wringing inflation out

of the economy over time," a goal that is understood to be the exclusive
province of the monetary authority.3

The instrument for achieving price

stability was a strict adherence to monetary targeting.

Such targets have two

benefits, they provide a benchmark against which to judge the performance of

* * * * * * * * * * * *
2

Monetary Policy Report to Congress, March 1980, pg. 2.

3

Monetary Policy Report to Congress, March 1980, pg. 3.

8

policy and are a clear means of conveying policy intent, both of which would
seem to be necessary preconditions for a policy that "is to impart a sense of
long run stability."
But, as you are no doubt aware, several developments recently seem to
have diminished our ability, if not our resolve, to eliminate inflation.

For

one, the recession of 1990 and our subsequently slow economic recovery have
helped to divert attention once again to the performance of real economic
variables, such as employment growth.

At the same time, the linkage between

the short-run policy instrument, the fed funds rate, and M2 growth, has not
maintained its former reliability.

•

Some monetarist economists argue that the sluggish economy is
compelling evidence that M2 is still a valid indicator of the thrust of
monetary policy and we must not be so quick to dismiss it.

Others, including

the Shadow Open Market Committee and several of my own staff at the Cleveland
Fed, have advised me to be wary when interpreting the behavior of M2.

The

monetary stimulus implied by recent M2 growth may be understated because of
the diminished importance of commercial banks as financial channels.

It is

tempting in such an uncertain environment to allow more discretion in the
decision making process.

However, it is precisely at times such as this that

structure is most important, so that the stance of monetary policy is not
among the uncertainties that business much guard against.

XV. The Implicit Promises of Policy Behavior

9

Changes in structure are, of course, inevitable, and it may be years
before a change is clearly identifiable.

We do not now know the significance

of the M 2 -fed funds rate discrepancy and we may not know for an indefinite
period of time.

This is why it is important for policy makers to target

long-run outcomes, not short-run instruments.
The long-run objective of monetary policy is still the promotion of
economic growth through the elimination of inflation, in the sense that
inflation no longer enters into the short or long run decisions of households
and firms.

Historical relationships between broad measures of money and price

indexes give me reason to believe that the monetary policy of the past several
years is consistent with a continued reduction in the rate of inflation.
But, while I may believe that a disinflation groundwork has been laid,
inflation expectations are still an integral part of decision-making by the
private sector.

The historic steepness of the yield curve, surveys from

households, and private forecasts, all reveal a long run inflation expectation
at, or above, the post-WWII average inflation rate.

And why not?

In the past

several years, the public has become conditioned to the idea that policy
actions are determined by the current state of the real economy, and in
particular, monthly e m p l oyment rfovth.]

(
funds rate to 3%, there have b^en

■With the recent cut in the federal

Setfc-A
m k

\

occasions since December 1990 on which

the funds rate was reduced on the same day as a weak employment report--a
timing of policy actions that implies a commitment to, if not a responsibility
for, short-run employment patterns.

10

Without an explicit commitment to a long-run inflation objective, with
inconsistency in the targeting of the monetary aggregates, and with policy
actions taken in concert with data on the real economy, can we expect
households and firms to take seriously our disinflation rhetoric?
Given the relatively poor performance of the labor market since 1989,
the implied responsibility for monthly employment conditions has no doubt been
uncomfortable for the Federal Reserve.

And, so it should be.

If we act as

though we are trying to affect monthly employment growth, then is it
unreasonable to be held accountable for not achieving better results?
Indeed, among the deficiencies for which the Federal Reserve is likely
to be held accountable in 1992, I fear that the implicit employment target we
seem to have set will be given greater significance than the shortfall of our
explicit M2 target.

By appearing to dismiss the shortfall in M2, we risk

damaging credibility about our resolve to achieve future targets.
I understand that there are very good reasons to be skeptical about
the interpretation of slow M2 growth and I will not recount them here.

But,

we must, above all else, endeavor to provide clarity and stability--in a
word, structure--to the monetary decision-making process.

V. Conclusion
Economists are human, therefore they have opinions.

Whether they are

more informed opinions than non-economists depends on their rigorous adherence
to a framework of analysis--a model.

While we may not be able to reduce

all, or, perhaps not even most, of the uncertainties facing business,

11

economists nevertheless provide a consistent basis for discussing and
evaluating the problems businesses face.

Such frameworks are useful even in

their shortcomings, by revealing that which we do not understand.
As a policymaker, whose actions affect the private sector, structure
is necessary not only as a guide to policy decisions, but as a means for
transmitting the significance of policy decisions to the marketplace.

For

this reason, it is crucial that policy pre-commit to goals that it can be
counted on, and held accountable to, achieve.
In the year of his death, Copernicus wrote:

"Finally we shall place the Sun himself at the center of the Universe.
All of this is suggested by the systematic procession of events and t-h&
harmony of the whole Universe, if only we face the facts, as they say,
"wi th both eyes open." "
For the astronomer, this meant placing the center of the Universe not
where you want it to be, but rather where the facts tell us it must be.

For

the policymaker, it means we should be careful what we promise, either by our
implied actions or by our explicit neglect.