View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Infrastructure for a Market Economy

Jerry L. Jordan
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Distinguished Speaker Series
Graduate School of Business
University o f Chicago
Chicago, Illinois

May 11,1999

Good afternoon. Thank you for inviting me to be a part of your Distinguished
Speaker Series. Naturally, I feel honored that you have asked me to be a part of this great
tradition at the University of Chicago and for giving me this opportunity to share my
thoughts with you this afternoon.
Even busy college students have probably seen a bit of the world news about on­
going economic crises in Asia, Russia and Brazil. In the midst of such events, some
people say, “After the crisis is over, we should start thinking about fixing the
fundamentals.” I disagree. I think a crisis atmosphere should be viewed as an
opportunity to get fresh thinking about what went wrong and what might provide
enduring reforms. I say that because I agree with former Federal Reserve Chairman,
Arthur Bums, who liked to say, “you only get fundamental reforms during times of
crisis.”
The theme of my remarks this afternoon is that the underlying economic
infrastructure is crucial to sustainable prosperity.
In 1776, Adam Smith published An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes o f the
Wealth o f Nations. He was interested in explaining the large differences in prosperity
observed across economies. That inquiry continues today, and for the same reason: The
gap that separates rich from poor economies remains huge. We see not only large
differences in wealth, but also tremendous variation in development.
If we ask a simple question like, “Why are some economies rich and others
poor?” or “Why do economies grow at different rates?” we get a simple answer: Rich
economies have greater resources per capita—more capital, both human and nonhuman,
and better technology connecting the two. But this answer only begs another question:




2

“Why do some economies have high levels of capital and technology, while others do
not?”
I believe it is a nation’s choice of institutions, the totality of which we call the
economic infrastructure, that determines wealth and development. What separates
economic “haves” from “have nots” is whether the role of an economy’s institutions—
particularly its public institutions—is to facilitate production or to confiscate it.
We can describe an economy’s infrastructure as the climate created by institutions
that serve as conduits of commerce. Some of these institutions are private; others are
public. In either case, an institution’s role can be conversionary—helping to transform
resources into output—or diversionary—transferring resources to non-producers. Most
private institutions are sustained by the value they add—either they produce, or they fail.
But the same cannot be said of public institutions that are sustained by the power of the
state.
Controlled experiments are not possible in economics, but on occasion natural
experiments present themselves. During this decade, economists had a unique
opportunity to study the economic infrastructure’s role in influencing prosperity. At least
15 newly created market economies have emerged within the former Soviet Empire, in
addition to the newly liberated Eastern European countries. Perhaps not surprisingly,
these emerging economies have experienced vastly varying degrees of prosperity.
Other examples can be found in the East Asian economies, whose spectacular
ascent was almost as dramatic as their subsequent collapse. What went wrong? These
are all countries that have espoused the philosophy of capitalism without having a culture
of capitalism. Here I do not use the term culture in its usual sense—as a set of values and




3

customs that bind citizens together. These, I suspect, are overemphasized, if not wholly
unimportant. What counts is a nation’s attitude about the free and uninhibited use of
private capital—the culture of a market economy.
Many of the developing economies that are experiencing turmoil have only
recently embraced a market orientation. Their difficulties have led some to suggest that it
is the capitalist system that has failed. In Malaysia, for example, the President has
declared that “the free market has failed disastrously.” Has it? Of course not. Many had
tried to paste a free-market veneer over a state-managed economic structure. These were
economies where free-market principles were given lip-service, but where a free-market
culture was not integral to the economic infrastructure.
A few basic questions can help reveal whether the reliance on markets is real or
only superficial. How deep is a nation’s commitment to the rule of law and does it have
strong, impartial courts? Is there an orderly succession of power? Is there little risk of
expropriation through nationalization and confiscation? Do they honor public contracts
and uphold private contracts? And are private institutions free from political pressures?
Many of the so-called “miracle countries” of East Asia, for example, do not score
highly by these factors, despite more than a decade of rapid growth. I think it is clear that
their recent implosion was attributable to the lack of a strong economic infrastructure. In
many of these countries, there was an indistinguishable line between public and private
interests. This was particularly true in banking, where government-directed investments,
or “connected lending,” were common.
Implicit governmental guarantees, without adequate market oversight, create the
potential for a nation’s asset values to be determined by things other than the




4

investment’s underlying contribution to the world economy. In most of these countries,
institutions similar to the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission are largely
ineffective or nonexistent; internationally accepted accounting standards are not
followed; and regulations requiring full disclosure are frequently absent. This means
investors have little ability to ascertain an investment’s actual economic performance.
Regrettably, these shortcomings did not deter foreign lenders and investors, who kept
adding to the flow of “hot money” swelling the bubble until it finally burst.
As one smart economist said, “Things that are unsustainable have a habit of
ending.” The end for the miracle economies came once it became clear that their
governments lacked the resources to support bad investments indefinitely. The collapse
of asset prices led to the insolvency of banking institutions and the attempted withdrawal
of foreign investors. The real economic costs in terms of lost output and employment are
still unknown.
Unfortunately, the worst may still lie ahead for some developing countries. Many
lack the mechanisms that allow resources to move freely to their most productive uses.
Their economic infrastructure is incomplete. Indeed, if history is a guide, the first
recourse of troubled nations is to block the operation of the marketplace by attempting to
prevent the outflow of foreign capital. Often they put severe regulatory restrictions on
financial intermediaries, nationalize some portion of the financial sector—either
explicitly or by bailing out sick institutions—all the while pointing to some foreign
culprit to justify the construction of capital controls, trade barriers, and other isolationist
measures. In short, they try to circumvent those parts of the economic infrastructure that
offer the only lasting solution to their economic problems.




5

The repeated bailouts of private financial intermediaries have the effect of
reducing private banks’ incentives to allocate funds effectively among competing
financial endeavors. This process stunts development of the banking skills and
supervisory arrangements necessary to prevent future crises. In short, the expectation that
the state will repeatedly commandeer the nation’s resources virtually guarantees more
frequent and more serious crises in the future. In the end, a nation is left with an
infrastructure that is incapable of supporting a growing and vibrant economy.
At the most basic level, there can be only two rationalizations for the state’s
participation in an economy. The first is as a social equalizer, redistributing the fruits of a
nation’s production under the presumption that a particular social need takes precedence
over private desires. The second justification for government participation is the
assertion that markets fail to produce an efficient outcome.
Where equity issues are concerned, the role of the state is unambiguous. Society
chooses to accept a lower average level of wealth in exchange for some presumably
higher social objective.
It is the state’s role as a promoter of market efficiency that raises the most
complex questions. Even if the objective is to overcome a particular market failure, once
the state has involved itself in the economy, its influence will have wide-ranging and
unanticipated consequences. And these institutions, which are not bound to obey market
forces, exert influence long after their usefulness has passed.
While I doubt that market failures are as common as activist policymakers
presume, it is clear that they do occur. The most frequently cited example is “public
goods,” where providing a good for anyone makes it possible to provide it for everyone




6

with no additional costs. A legal system and national defense are such public goods. So
too is a stable currency. These functions become part of the economic infrastructure
called “the protection of property rights,” which means, more or less, that individuals can
expect to receive the product of their labor. Although people could privately undertake
actions to prevent diversion of their output (by burglary, for example), it is widely
accepted that a social institution (such as a police force) is a less costly means of
protection. Let us be clear, however. In order to pay for the police, courts, or jails,
resources must be diverted to the state from private persons in the form of taxes.
Indeed, once introduced into the economic infrastructure, the state cannot help but
tax the system’s productive capacity. Sometimes, these taxes are direct and sustain the
government activity. But direct taxes are probably only a small part of the overall cost to
the economy. Also important are the costs borne by private agents who invest resources
to minimize their tax burdens, either through tax-avoidance schemes or through attempts
to influence the taxing authorities.
This is the paradox of any state enterprise. While the state may be the most
effective instrument for minimizing resource diversions (for example, by protecting
property rights and enforcing contracts), it simultaneously introduces the potential for the
debilitating diversion of resources for the state’s own account. This, I think is where the
differences between economies are grossly understated.
A common distinction among governments is whether they are called “capitalist”
or “socialist”—terms that broadly define the diversionary appetites of governments.
Certainly a government committed to allowing private ownership of capital is, all other
things equal, more committed to establishing an economic infrastructure that favors




7

creation over diversion. But this is only part of the story. Laws that protect against the
threat of expropriation or government repudiation of contracts—all of the rules that
cumulatively sum to the protection of property rights—are important.
These are the common set of characteristics that make an economy prosperous.
According to some studies, these characteristics are substantial enough to explain most—
if not all—of the differences in economic performance among nations today, and I
suspect that the same set of characteristics separated the wealth of nations in Adam
Smith’s time.
One thing that has changed since the time of Adam Smith is money. Economic
exchange involves information and transaction costs that require real resources. These
costs, which influence the extent of trade, the degree of specialization, and the economic
benefit derived from goods, stem primarily from the difficulty of acquiring information
about the quality of the goods—their true worth as opposed to their money worth. The
lower the information and transactions costs, the greater the opportunities for individuals
to undertake exchanges that maximize mutual welfare. When we find ways to conserve
productive resources that had been devoted to gathering information and conducting
exchange, we liberate them and make them available for creating consumable output. In
this way, sound money promotes prosperity.
Of course, a nation must be concerned not only about the integrity of its money,
but also about the stability and reliability of its financial system. The condition of a
nation’s financial intermediaries and financial (asset) markets may influence a monetary
authority’s policy actions, but need not compromise its objectives. Unsound financial
institutions and inefficient financial markets may impede, but do not preclude, the




8

achievement and maintenance of a stable currency. Nevertheless, if ex ante concerns
about, or ex post responses to, the condition of financial intermediaries, or markets, divert
monetary authorities from a disciplined, sound policy stance, then overall financial
instability can result. While adverse real economic effects of shocks to the financial
sector can never be eliminated, their disruptive influence can be minimized if monetary
authorities continue to provide a stable monetary unit.
Economists are accustomed to talking about the quantity of money; I suggest
thinking more deeply about its quality. A society will choose to use as money that form
which enables people to gather information and conduct transactions with the minimum
use of resources. Indeed, the worldwide use of the U.S. dollar alongside local currencies
illustrates the point that monies do compete along the quality dimension.
While central banks around the world have begun to understand the long-term
efficiencies that stable money can provide, they are also part of a fiscal regime that
includes strong incentives to violate the public’s trust by generating unanticipated
inflation. Through unanticipated expansions of fiat money, central banks can levy an
unlegislated tax, reduce the real value of the government’s outstanding debts, or attempt
to exploit a short-term tradeoff between growth and inflation. Governments, and
especially those that heavily discount the future, will always be tempted to instruct, or to
pressure, their central banks to issue excessive amounts of money.
The effects of such short-sighted government policies are transitory at best. As
people alter their behavior in the face of inflation, there is an increase in the costs of
conducting exchanges. The additional resources expended on gathering information and




9

on protecting the real value of wealth would otherwise have been available for growthenhancing activities.
Governments with a longer view typically attempt to ensure the quality of their
monetary unit by adopting institutional arrangements that restrict their own monetary
discretion. Certain types of rules can enhance a central bank’s reputation by signaling the
government’s intention of maintaining the quality of its currency. Examples include
explicit price-level targets or other legal imperatives that place monetary stability above
other objectives. Such arrangements may be particularly important because a reputation
for monetary integrity is built very slowly.
CONCLUSION
Globalization is a common buzzword in political economy circles today. It means
an increase in both private-sector and public-sector competition as people and resources
move freely across borders. Given the choice and the opportunity, individuals gravitate
toward the institutional arrangements that best reduce transactions costs and raise their
living standards. This includes the monetary units in which they denominate their wealth
and conduct their transactions.
Central banks are successful when households and businesses base their decisions
on the assumption that all observed changes in money prices are relative price changes,
and all observed changes in interest rates are real changes. Fortunately, global
competition among national monies seems to be imposing a discipline that cannot be
ignored.
I began my remarks today with a simple premise—that the economic
infrastructure plays a major role in determining economic prosperity—and that




infrastructure depends crucially on the culture of the institutions that are supported by the
state. The best economic performance occurs where the state has fostered an
infrastructure that functions as, in the words of Vaclav Klaus, the former Prime Minister
of the Czech Republic, a “market economy without adjectives.”
Protections often taken for granted—patents, copyrights, and other intellectual
property rights—are largely unknown or are ineffective in many places in the world
today. Without such protections, incentives for creative talents to design and develop
new products and services are substantially weakened.
In the final analysis, sustainable long-term prosperity, whether at the global or the
local level, occurs when human action is focused on converting productive resources into
marketable goods. It is no longer useful to think of the government’s relationship to its
citizens as that of an architect, engineer, carpenter, or any other metaphor implying
activism. Instead, the role of the state is to nurture an economic garden-assuring a fertile
soil to allow growth to take root, warding off pests that seek to feed off the budding crop,
and keeping weeds from suffocating the plant before it achieves its potential. Simply
espousing the virtues of a market economy, without establishing the proper economic
infrastructure is like planting one seedling in a rocky, infertile ground. We would not
expect either to survive for very long.
Thank you for your courteous attention and thank you for inviting me to
participate in your program.