View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE CHALLENGE OF STABILITY:
MEXICO'S PURSUIT OF SOUND MONEY

Remarks by
Jerry L. Jordan
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

DUXX Graduate School of Business Leadership
Monterrey, Mexico

April 29,1999

Mexico needs a stable standard of value. Indeed, no economy can achieve its
potential without a stable standard of value.
Mexico needs to experience another extended period of sustained prosperity as it
did in the 1960s. A necessary condition for prosperity is sound money. So long as fears
of exchange rate or banking crises persist, no country can sustain a period of rising
standards of living.
There is no mystery about what conditions will foster sustainable growth. The
myriad experiences of the transition economies of the former Soviet Union and Eastern
Europe have provided us with many valuable lessons. One of those lessons is that a
market economy requires a Hayekian infrastructure. That is, there must first be a
foundation of enforceable property rights, generally accepted accounting principles,
stable currency, and sound financial intermediaries.
For if public contracts are not honored and private contracts are not enforced,
markets are impaired. If title to property is not certain, normal banking is not possible. If
financial statements are not reliable, investment opportunities are obscured.

Sound Money
Changes in the money prices of goods and assets convey information. If an
economy’s monetary unit is known to be a stable standard of value, then changes in
money prices will accurately reflect changes in the relative values of goods and assets.
That is, price fluctuations signal changes in the demand for, or supply of, goods or assets.
Resource utilization then shifts toward more valued uses and away from those less
valued.
However, if changes in money prices are contaminated by the changing
purchasing power of money, false signals are sent to businesses and households. Bad
decisions are made, and resources are misallocated. Standards of living fail to rise at
their potential rate. Nominal interest rates respond to shifting expectations about the
future purchasing power of money. Changes in real interest rates are obscured. Again,
resources are misallocated. Saving and investment decisions are affected, and growth is
impaired.




2

Neither inflation nor deflation enhance economic performance. Unanticipated
inflations and deflations induce redistribution of wealth—especially between debtors and
creditors—but they leave the average standard of living lower.
A former Fed Governor used to say, “a place that tolerates inflation is a place
where no one tells the truth.” He meant, of course, that true changes in the relative values
of things cannot be observed when the purchasing power of money is not stable.
The standard of value is stable—money is sound—when people make decisions in
the expectation that all observed changes in money prices are changes in relative prices,
and all observed changes in interest rates are changes in real rates.

The Challenge
There is no single best way to achieve and maintain a stable standard of value.
Even the commodity-backed currencies of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries were
subject to periodic inflations or deflations— as when new gold or silver mines were
discovered, or mines were depleted.
Under a true gold standard, a country’s internally and externally held debt both
represent claims to its gold reserves. This effectively limits the government’s ability to
engage in deficit spending.
Under the “gold exchange standard” of the Bretton Woods System, a country’s
externally held debt still represents a claim on its gold holdings. The government’s
ability to engage in deficit spending is constrained by the willingness of its residents to
add to their holdings of government bonds.
Under a pure fiat money system, such as we have experienced since 1973, the
universal challenge has been to find effective constraints on the growth of government
spending financed by the issuance of new debt. In this fiscal environment, achieving and
sustaining stable currencies has been a worldwide challenge for central banks.
This pursuit of sound money has followed several paths. The gold exchange
standard, for example—with pegged exchange rates in the post-World War II period—
helped war-torn countries establish the credibility of their new currencies and central
banks.




3

After the demise of the Bretton Woods System, a few countries—such as Austria
and Holland—were successful in providing relatively stable domestic currencies by
adopting a credible hard peg to a stable foreign standard of value, such as the deutsche
mark. A few countries—such as Switzerland, and later Canada and New Zealand—were
relatively successful with floating exchange rates despite their small, open economies.
At times in history, currency boards also have been successful means of importing
stable standards of value. For countries with historically undisciplined fiscal policies,
currency boards have proven an effective means of achieving a fiscal regime that enables
a more disciplined monetary environment.
The recent creation of a new currency—the euro—to replace the national
currencies of eleven European nations is yet another method of insulating monetary
authorities from fiscal authorities. A successful, stable euro will require fiscal reforms
that might not have been possible in the political environments of the individual member
nations.
And recently, “dollarization” has emerged as still another approach to importing a
stable standard of value. But, like all approaches, there are pros and cons that must be
carefully weighed before a choice is made between alternative monetary regimes.
In principle, Mexico could acquire a stable standard of value in several different
ways. Some of the necessary conditions for success are common to all approaches.
However, the political difficulty of achieving and maintaining these essential conditions
depends on historical, social, and political developments that vary greatly from country to
country.
The ability to achieve and maintain fiscal discipline is a key condition for success.
Even communist governments eventually learned the lesson that what can be distributed
and consumed is limited, ultimately, by what can actually be produced. But as we know,
governments of all types have had a tendency to promise more than is likely to be
produced.
Two crucial developments that led to monetary instability earlier in the twentieth
century were capital markets that permitted greatly increased debt-financed spending by
governments and the spread of fiat currencies issued by central banks. Successful fiscal




4

discipline has been threatened, most recently, by the growth in unfunded pension
liabilities of governments with adverse demographic trends.
In the early 1980s, this linkage between the fiscal regime and the implications for
the monetary environments was labeled the “dismal arithmetic of monetarism.” This
premise held that any country that found it politically difficult to achieve and maintain a
disciplined fiscal policy would ultimately resort to the unlegislated tax of debasing the
currency. In such circumstances, what we call monetary policy becomes a fiscal
instrument—a method of funding government.
This “fiscal dominance” hypothesis of the early 1980s—in an environment of
large national debts and annual deficits all over the world—led to forecasts of high and
rising inflation in both industrialized and developing countries.
Instead, determined pursuit of disciplined monetary policy in many countries
imposed constraints on fiscal authorities. In the case of the euro, political decisions were
agreed to in international treaties to achieve and maintain the balanced fiscal policies
necessary for a successful monetary regime.
The experience with currency boards has been similar. Once a decision is made
to give monetary stability the highest priority, constraints on spending and taxing
authorities are inevitable. Residual uncertainties about the durability of currency board
arrangements stem from uncertainties about the domestic political will to maintain the
fiscal discipline crucial to continued success of the currency board.

Dollarization
In January 1999, following the devaluation of the Brazilian real, Argentine
President Carlos Menem suggested dollarization as a possible means of solidifying his
country’s commitment to sound money. Since 1991, Argentina has operated a currency
board, pegging the peso one-for-one to the U.S. dollar and backing its monetary base
with dollars. Argentina’s currency board has been remarkably successful at fostering
price stability in that country, thereby satisfying a necessary condition for sustained,
long-term economic growth consistent with Argentina’s potential. Nevertheless, foreign
developments—such as the crises in Mexico, Asia, and Brazil—raised questions about
Argentina’s political resolve to maintain a U. S. dollar standard of value.




5

President Menam’s words have been echoed throughout Latin America, where
dollars already circulate widely, but the cry is loudest in Mexico. Supporters see
dollarization as a way to permanently protect Mexico’s growth and prosperity from
devastating, periodic bouts of inflation and peso depreciation.
Like all monetary arrangements, dollarization would impose certain constraints on
political authorities. Public trust ultimately depends on reputations. Constraints on
policy discretion are valuable, because they buy time in which to build these reputations.
These constraints involve both costs and benefits that countries must consider on a caseby-case basis. I do not give policy advice on the issue of dollarization, because not
everyone gains, or gains equally, from the choice of one monetary regime versus another.

Why Sound Money Matters
Money serves to lower the real economic costs of engaging in economic
exchange, but its effectiveness in doing so hinges on the stability of its purchasing power.
If people suspect that a monetary asset will lose its purchasing power, they will reduce
their holdings of it, look for substitute monetary assets (dollarize), and devise
alternative—and less efficient—methods of exchange. When this happens, the costs of
undertaking daily transactions rise as the public diverts real economic resources away
from alternative and more productive uses. Resources are wasted. By conserving these
economic resources, stable monetary institutions promote allocative efficiency and
economic growth.
Although governments generally understand the benefits of stable money, they
also have strong incentives to generate unanticipated inflation. This is especially true of
politically weak governments, who attach a low probability to a long tenure and,
therefore, heavily discount the more distant gains of economic growth. Through
expansions of the money supply, governments can gain seigniorage and levy an inflation
tax—without the consent of the public as expressed through a legislative process. In
addition, through unanticipated inflations, governments are sometimes tempted to try to
exploit a short-term trade-off between employment and inflation.
Once caught offguard, however, the public becomes more wary in the future. For
their own protection they will reduce their holdings of domestic money. The spontaneous




6

dollarizations in Argentina and Mexico in the early to mid-1980s exemplify this
response. Some Latin American governments initially resisted these unofficial
dollarizations, but their responses to currency substitutions (such as capital controls)
tended to compound the inefficiencies associated with monetary instability.
Faced with the public’s clear preference for a more stable foreign currency,
governments may adopt institutional constraints on their ability to inflate—like
independent central banks, exchange-rate pegs, or currency boards. All have been tried,
some have been successful, but most have been abandoned when political circumstances
changed. The small, but persistent, spread between interest rates on Argentine pesodenominated debt and interest rates on dollar-denominated debt reflects the slight
probability that Argentina might break its dollar peg, or alter the rules under which its
currency board operates.
Institutional constraints on monetary policy—by themselves—do not directly
address the fiscal-policy and banking-structure problems that often give rise to monetary
instability in emerging market countries. Moreover, they do not erase the need to re­
think the political and societal infrastructure that restricts a nation’s ability to develop and
grow.
Ultimately, the only way governments can attain the optimal outcome to the fiat
money problem is by developing a reputation for behaving in a responsible manner.
Switzerland, a small, open economy, has achieved sustained economic growth with
reasonable price stability without the aid of a currency board, the European Monetary
Union, or pegging to another currency.
Although the integrity of a stable purchasing power ultimately depends on
reputation, constraints on monetary policy discretion can enhance a government’s
standing—though they do so only as a signal of intentions with regard to other
institutional reforms. Argentina’s currency board has successfully eliminated inflation
while that country adopted more general, market-based economic reforms. Argentina’s
intention to develop the economic infrastructure of a normal market economy has been
made clear. Monetary constraints alone, however, would stand little chance in countries
like Russia that have made little progress in establishing the Hayekian infrastructure
essential for markets and a liberal democratic order.




7

Economic Adjustments Under a Common Currency
Regions, sectors, and industries do not always prosper equally, even in a common
currency area. Regional booms and busts still occur. Some sectors or industries expand
while others contract. This kind of disparate economic performance may have its origins
in the domestic economy or in developments in another currency zone.
For the past couple of years, the U. S. dollar has been relatively strong—
especially compared to currencies in Asia and some in Latin America—and overall, the
U.S. economy is performing very well. Nevertheless, this prosperity is not universal.
Steel companies are losing money, declaring bankruptcy, laying off workers, and shutting
plants. I am certain that steel company executives would like to see a weaker dollar,
especially relative to the Japanese yen and other Asian currencies. The story in textiles is
similar.
The U. S. oil sector is also depressed, so Alaska, Louisiana, and Texas are not
doing so well. Likewise, the Midwest agricultural sector that depends heavily on exports,
or has to compete with imports, is having a hard time. The economy of Hawaii has been
depressed for several years as a result of the decade-long recession in Japan.
All of these adverse economic conditions create political pressures for
government assistance. Sometimes the aid comes in the form of subsidies, sometimes tax
relief, sometimes protection against competition from imports. Ultimately, though, both
labor and other productive resources will leave these depressed sectors and regions and
migrate to areas and industries where opportunities are more promising. The greater the
flexibility and efficiency of labor and capital markets, the better the odds of resisting
pressures for political relief that come from adverse developments.
The recent launch of the euro—a common currency to be shared by eleven
European nations—provides an opportunity to learn more about political responses to the
pressures arising from diverse economic conditions. Whether a single, uniform monetary
policy can serve both the booming economy of Ireland and the stagnating economies of
Germany and Italy remains to be seen.
In addition to labor and capital markets, the health of the banking industry
influences a nation’s ability to adjust to changing economic circumstances. Even within




8

a common currency area, a lack of diversification of assets or funding sources can create
problems for banks faced with regional or sectoral booms and busts. During the oil-price
collapse of the 1980s, for instance, U. S. banks that were tied exclusively to oil-region
economies failed or were acquired by healthy banks in other regions. More diversified
Canadian banks all survived.
Nationwide branch banking in the United States is not yet two years old, but there
is no question that greater diversification has contributed to the soundness of the larger
regional and super-regional companies. The U.S. found that maintaining political
boundaries to branch banking in the common currency area of the fifty states was
destabilizing. Under the currency board arrangement of the past eight years, Argentina
has seen the foreign ownership share of its banking sector grow to fifty percent. There is
little question that the continued success of the currency board has been enhanced by the
financial stability attained by the internationalization of banking.
For the banking system to remain healthy, additional liquidity must be readily
available in times of heightened uncertainty. When truly systemic events occur—the
public desires to hold more currency because of century-date-change uncertainties, or
banks attempt to hold more reserves against their deposits during political crises—the
only source of additional currency or reserves is the issuing central bank. This classic
“lender of last resort” function1can be fulfilled only by the central bank empowered to
expand or contract its balance sheet without limit. In a world of fractional reserve
requirements imposed on deposit liabilities, an elastic source of central bank money is
essential. However, that function need not be provided domestically.
In the modem world, this so-called lending function is typically performed
through open market operations, without any need for direct central bank lending to local
institutions. All that is necessary is that the supply of central bank money in the market
expand as demand increases. Moreover, subsidiaries or branches of foreign banks
effectively diversify a country’s banking system, making it less vulnerable to economic

1 The expression “lender of last resort” emerged when the primary method by which central banks provided
additional liquidity to the banking system during banking panics was by “rediscounting” commercial loans
at the “discount window”. The objective was to reassure a nervous public that they could convert deposit
balances to currency if they so desired. In recent decades, the discount window at the U.S. central bank has
declined in importance as a source of central bank funds. Instead, open market operations have become the
primary method of satisfying increased public desires to add to their cash balances.




9

disturbances. Because of their close ties to the parent banks and access to global
financial markets, they may be more able and willing than local banks to maintain
lending when faced with deposit outflows.

Market Choice and Change
Permitted the choice, people prefer to hold their money in a form that will offer
the most stable purchasing power over time. When countries impose capital restraints, or
establish legal tender rules, they limit their citizens’ ability to protect their income and
wealth from inflation. Argentina clearly signaled its intention to maintain monetary
stability by granting people the legal right to contract under any and all circumstances—
including tax payments and other transactions with the government—in any currency
they might choose. Legislation in Argentina requires courts to enforce contracts in the
currency specified therein. This “specific performance” law2 provides greater assurance
that the effective dollarization will not be reversed.
A dollarization process is already under way—without official sanction—in many
Latin American countries. Permitting parallel currencies would have some of the
benefits of officially sanctioned dollarization, but would maintain greater flexibility
during the transition process. In fiat money regimes, Gresham’s law becomes inverted—
high-confidence monies drive out low-confidence monies. The resulting discipline from
competing standards of value strengthens the political resolve to achieve the fiscal
balance necessary for monetary stability.
A fundamental principle of a market economy is consumer sovereignty. People
will act in a manner that enhances their own well-being. In the process—as if guided by
an invisible hand (to quote a wise man)—they generally promote the best interests of
society at large. The spontaneous, informal dollarizations in many countries over recent
decades demonstrate that people know that sound money serves their personal interests.
National interests also are served by providing a stable standard of value.

2 “Specific performance legislation” is not the same thing as “legal tender laws”. The latter require that
residents of a country accept a certain currency in settlement of a financial obligation, even if they are owed
a foreign currency, gold, or bales of hay. Specific performance legislation means the courts must require
delivery of what was promised in the contract, even if that is the currency of another country, gold, or bales
o f hay.




10

likely be some increased demand for cash, and we remain committed to
meeting any additional demands of the public. That means Reserve Banks
will have sufficient currency in reserve to more than double the amount in
circulation domestically, in the highly unlikely event that this is necessary.
One remaining issue that we're working hard on is how to ensure that this
large amount of valuable paper is where it is needed, rapidly and securely.
Plans have already been developed to address these storage and distribution
issues.

Finally, let me reiterate the necessity for continued focused attention
on Y2K. Despite my reassuring assessment, much remains to be done, and
there are no guarantees of total success. Everyone must concentrate on his
or her own piece of this effort. However, through careful planning and
adequate event management, we believe that the year 2000 transition will be
smooth, and that - like the Federal Reserve’s operations - the transition will
be newsworthy only to the extent that operations are running effectively and
that there is nothing to report.




11

Now, let me turn to monetary policy. I can assure you that the
attention that we are directing to the Y2K issue has not distracted us from
giving careful attention to this responsibility.

[Sandy Pianalto’s email on 4/28 said that Jerry Jordan would fill in this
part.]

Closing Comments
In closing, I’d to again thank you Bluecoats for the work that you do
and your commitment to those in need. I am truly pleased that you have
chosen the Federal Reserve to host your Annual Spring Dinner. I hope that
you will thoroughly enjoy your visit with us.




And now, if there is time, I’ll be glad to respond to a few questions.

mm#