View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:15 p.m. EST
November 17, 2015

Central Clearing in an Interdependent World

Remarks by

Jerome H. Powell

Member

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at

The Clearing House Annual Conference

New York, N.Y.

November 17, 2015

Thank you for inviting me to speak today. 1 I attended The Clearing House
annual meeting in 2013 and spoke about financial market infrastructure reform.
Two years have passed, and this is a good opportunity to take stock. I’ll start by
reviewing the progress made in strengthening central counterparty (or CCP)
clearing, and then offer some thoughts on expanded central clearing for repurchase
agreement (or repo) markets--an area of significant current interest.
In the years leading up to the financial crisis, the over-the-counter (OTC)
derivatives market experienced rapid growth and an underappreciated buildup of
risk. The huge losses suffered by the American International Group (AIG) on its
derivatives positions and the lack of transparency about the exposures of AIG’s
counterparties were major accelerants to the financial panic that reached its acute
phase in September 2008. In response, in 2009 the Group of Twenty nations
committed to moving standardized derivatives to central clearing, and to requiring
posting of margin for derivatives that are not centrally cleared.2
I am a believer in the potential benefits of central clearing under the right
circumstances. But central clearing is not a panacea. Charts similar to that in
Figure 1 are often used to illustrate the netting of exposures and simplification that

1

These remarks represent my own views, which do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Board or
the Federal Open Market Committee.
2
G20 Leaders Statement: The Pittsburg Summit, September 24-25 2009. https://g20.org/wpcontent/uploads/2014/12/Pittsburgh_Declaration_0.pdf

1

central clearing can bring to an OTC market. The tangled and highly opaque
picture of a purely bilateral market is replaced by the neat hub-and-spoke network
in which a CCP is buyer to every seller, and seller to every buyer, allowing netting
and greater transparency for participants and regulators alike. Of course, reality is
not so elegant, as Figure 2 illustrates. There are multiple CCPs, even within
product classes, and major dealers act as clearing members across a broad network
of CCPs. Clearing members also perform a range of services for CCPs, including
custody, liquidity provision, and settlement. By design, increased central clearing
will concentrate risks in CCPs; it is essential that, as these risks accumulate, the
CCPs build up their ability to manage them. It is often noted that CCPs made it
through the recent financial crisis without direct government assistance. But many
of their major clearing members did receive such assistance. CCPs must now plan
for a world in which these large firms will fail and be resolved without government
support.
Recognizing the importance of strengthening our financial market
infrastructure, the regulatory community has clarified and significantly raised
expectations for CCPs and all key financial market infrastructures (FMIs or market
infrastructures). These heightened expectations are set forth in the Principles for
Financial Market Infrastructures (or PFMIs), which were adopted in 2012 by the
Committee on Payment and Market Infrastructures (CPMI) and the International
2

Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO). 3 The PFMIs lay out
comprehensive requirements for financial market infrastructures, including CCPs.
Clearing and settlement activities are cross-border and indeed global in
nature. Major U.S. financial institutions interact with market infrastructures
around the world. The PFMIs have established a rigorous set of internationally
agreed upon standards for the quality and quantity of loss-absorbing resources and
liquidity, governance, risk management, stress testing, recovery and orderly winddown, and other key areas.
I believe that there has been reasonably good progress in implementing these
reforms here in the United States. For example, according to the Financial
Stability Board, over 70 percent of new U.S. interest rate and credit derivatives are
now centrally cleared. 4 And the Federal Reserve and other U.S. regulatory
agencies have recently announced final margin rules for uncleared derivatives as
well, which should enhance the resilience of trading that still occurs outside of
central clearing. 5

3

Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems and Technical Committee of the International Organization of
Securities Commissions (2012), “Principles for Financial Market Infrastructures,” final report, April,
www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d101a.pdf.
4
See Financial Stability Board (2015), “OTC Derivatives Market Reforms: Ninth Progress Report on
Implementation” (Basel, Switzerland: FSB, July), www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/OTCDerivatives-Ninth-July-2015-Progress-Report.pdf
5
See www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/bcreg20151030b1.pdf

3

But there is still plenty of work left to do. CCPs are implementing the
PFMIs under the oversight of national regulators; clearing members have been
vocal commentators on this process. To assure that the standards are consistently
implemented across jurisdictions and across FMIs, CPMI and IOSCO are
conducting joint reviews of the risk-management practices of a range of global
derivatives-clearing CCPs. Working in conjunction with the Basel Committee on
Banking Supervision and the Financial Stability Board (FSB), they have also set
out a detailed work plan for further enhancing the resilience, recovery planning and
resolvability of CCPs.
Earlier this year, CPMI-IOSCO conducted surveys of more than 30 of the
most systemically important CCPs regarding their stress testing, margin, recovery
planning, and loss allocation frameworks. The survey responses have now been
received and are being analyzed. I expect that these exercises will result in more
granular guidance to CCPs covering a wide set of operational areas, further helping
to ensure consistency of implementation of the PFMIs and market infrastructure
resilience.
Further work on resolution is also necessary. The FSB has conducted a
survey on CCP resolution regimes and resolution planning within its membership,
and found that many jurisdictions are still in the process of developing resolution

4

regimes. As the reform process moves forward, this will be an important area of
focus.
All of these efforts are directly aimed at strengthening FMIs. But the
strength and resilience of a CCP ultimately depends on the strength and resilience
of its clearing members. I’d now like to shift focus to the relationship between
these market utilities and the institutions that use them.
Barring an operational event, CCPs only face credit or liquidity risk when
one of their members fails to make a payment when due. Thus, one effective way
to make a CCP safer is to make its members safer. In that sense, the post-crisis
reforms that have greatly strengthened our largest and most systemically important
banking institutions have directly benefitted CCPs and other FMIs.
While requiring bank holding companies and their associated broker-dealers
to be better capitalized and hold more liquid assets has unquestionably made them
safer, it has also raised their balance sheet costs and thereby created incentives to
scale back on less profitable business lines. Clearing has traditionally been a low
margin business, and broker-dealers have often offered these services to clients in
the belief that doing so may lead to more profitable business. In the new
environment, broker dealers are reconsidering this model, and may reduce services
to smaller clients or move to an agency model with higher fees.

5

Banks and broker-dealers serve not only as clearing members of CCPs, but
also as liquidity providers and as custodians of their cash and securities. CCPs
typically have lines of credit with banks and other arrangements for secured credit
to meet their potential liquidity needs. The higher cost of funding for large
financial institutions has made these liquidity arrangements substantially more
expensive and more difficult to obtain. Given the balance sheet costs involved,
financial institutions may also be less willing to hold cash deposits on behalf of
their CCP clients.
These considerations suggest that there will be a period of adjustment as
firms and market infrastructures adapt their business models to the new regulatory
landscape. This is not necessarily a cause for alarm. To some extent, these
adjustments are desirable. Liquidity risk seems to have been systematically
underpriced before the crisis. Firms are now much more focused on both
managing and more accurately pricing this risk. It is also appropriate that the
pricing of a bank’s services accurately reflect the costs and profitability of different
business lines, which should lead to a more efficient allocation of resources.
One area where market participants are actively searching for new business
models is the repo market, where there are currently several private initiatives for
greater central clearing. Expanded repo clearing could potentially bring a range of
benefits, including greater opportunities for netting and related reductions in
6

balance sheet costs for dealers affiliated with a bank holding company. The
evolution of repo markets and central clearing can serve to illustrate both the
potential benefits and the complexities that arise as the market seeks new
infrastructure models.

Repo Clearing
The U.S. repo market is composed of several segments, as illustrated in
Figure 3. Dealers are at the center of the figure and operate in all five of the
segments shown. In the bilateral market (segments 1 through 3), participants often
impose narrow restrictions on the specific securities eligible for collateral. In this
portion of the market, cash providers tend to be professional investors such as asset
managers (segment 1), or the securities dealers themselves. Cash borrowers
include prime brokerage clients (segment 3). Securities dealers may also borrow
cash in this market, or may borrow it and then redistribute it to other dealers
(segment 2).
The tri-party repo market (segments 4 and 5) is used to finance general
collateral pools rather than specific securities, and trades in this portion of the
market are settled on the books of the two clearing banks, Bank of New York

7

Mellon and JP Morgan Chase. 6 Money market mutual funds and securities lenders
are among the most prominent cash providers in segment 4, while securities
dealers are the primary borrowers of cash. Dealers may use this cash to fund their
own portfolios; they may also lend it to other dealers in the general collateral
finance (GCF) repo market (segment 5). This segment is cleared through the Fixed
Income Clearing Corporation, and is currently the only segment of the market that
is centrally cleared.
Based on figures from September 2015, the size of the tri-party repo market,
segment 4, was approximately $1.5 trillion and the GCF market (segment 5) was
approximately $300 billion. The general lack of data on bilateral repo activity
makes it difficult to know the precise size of each individual segment of that
market, but bilateral repo and securities lending taken together accounted for
approximately $1.7 trillion in outstanding activity. 7
Given its vast scale and position at the center of the wholesale finance
markets, repo is without doubt a critical activity. Repo is a key source of financing
for a wide range of firms, and an important “safe asset” for investors. The GCF

6

General collateral or GC repo involve repo transactions secured by a range of Treasury or other assets that are
accepted as collateral by the majority of intermediaries in the repo market. GC repo assets are high quality and
liquid, but not subject to exceptional specific demand.
7
These estimates are based on the methodology described in Adam Copeland, Isaac Davis, Eric LeSueur, and
Antoine Martin (2012), “Mapping and Sizing the U.S. Repo Market,”
libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2012/06/mapping-and-sizing-the-us-repo-market.html#.VkiGUCtQpps

8

segment, although modest in size compared to the overall market, is a key source
of financing for smaller dealers, particularly in times of financial stress. The
availability of repo funding for a diverse range of participants supports market
liquidity by enabling them to make markets in Treasury and agency securities.
CCPs themselves also rely on these markets, often using repo to earn interest on
cash collateral and counting on access to repo markets in their liquidity planning.
The FSB has called on authorities to “consider the pros and cons of
broadening participation in repo clearing arrangements.”8 What are the potential
benefits of greater clearing in this market? In addition to the potential netting
benefits I mentioned earlier, a CCP typically performs three other beneficial
economic functions: 1) a reduction in the potential cost of counterparty default
coming from the orderly liquidation of a defaulting member’s positions, 2) greater
transparency and a reduction in operational risk from enhanced reporting
requirements and standardization of data, and 3) the sharing of risk among
members of the CCP through some mutualization of the costs of a counterparty’s
default. I’ll discuss each of these in turn.
Orderly liquidation

8

Financial Stability Board (2013), “Strengthening Oversight and Regulation of Shadow Banking: Policy Framework
for Addressing Shadow Banking Risks in Securities Lending and Repos” (Basel, Switzerland: FSB, August),
www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/r_130829b.pdf

9

While repos are generally a low risk, low margin business, they proved to be
vulnerable to runs during the financial crisis, when concerns of possible defaults by
large financial firms led to a sudden withdrawal of funding from repo markets. As
a result, a reform project led by my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York produced a set of measures that have sharply reduced the amount of intraday
credit and improved risk management practices in the tri-party repo market. These
reforms have made the overall structure of that market much safer, and
significantly reduced the likelihood of a borrower default. But if a default were to
take place, some counterparties, particularly those unwilling or unable to hold
sizable positions, would retain strong incentives to sell assets quickly regardless of
the price received.
A repo CCP could help to address this “fire sale” risk. CCPs have rulebased processes to dispose of the portfolio of a defaulted member. CCPs can
transfer positions to solvent broker-dealers, or hedge positions and auction them
off over time.
Greater transparency and reduction in operational risk
Central clearing could also improve transparency and bring a reduction in
operational risks. CCPs are in position to aggregate trade information from all
clearing members, and thus to monitor and manage counterparty and market-risk

10

exposure better than individual members. As I noted earlier, we have relatively
little information on bilateral repo activity, so greater clearing in this segment
could have significant benefits in helping to aggregate market information. CCPs
also provide participants with central confirmation of trades and netting of
positions, allowing their members to reduce operational risk of post-trade
processing.

Risk sharing
In terms of risk sharing, when a CCP clearing member defaults, any
resulting losses are shared among the surviving members and the CCP itself
according to pre-agreed rules. Members of a CCP contribute to a default fund that
can be used to absorb these losses. The degree of risk sharing depends on the
design of the CCP, but transparent rules help to create an orderly, predictable
process for managing a default.9
Finding a way forward
The potential benefits of proposals for expanded central clearing of repo in
U.S. markets are undergoing a period of evaluation by regulatory authorities and
9

While details vary, in a waterfall, to cover losses resulting from a defaulting member, a CCP typically first uses the
financial resources of the defaulting member, including margin and default fund contributions. If losses still exist,
then the CCP uses its capital (skin in the game), followed by the default fund contributions of surviving members.
Further losses could be absorbed by additional assessments on surviving members.

11

market participants alike. For these proposals, it will not be a simple matter to find
a way forward while meeting the heightened regulatory expectations I mentioned
earlier. The liquidity requirement of the PFMIs will present a particular challenge
-- a CCP must have sufficient liquid resources to meet its payment obligations on
time in extreme but plausible market conditions, including in the event of a default
of that participant whose default would generate the largest obligations.10 In repo
trading, unlike in swaps, the full notional principal amount is exchanged at the
beginning and end of the trade. As a result, the liquidity requirements for repo
clearing will be quite high.
Another key question is how great the opportunities for netting actually are,
in light of the dominance of “one-way flows” in U.S. repo markets. Netting for
balance sheet purposes is only permitted for offsetting trades with the same
maturity and counterparty. 11 The many repo market participants who act as either
lenders or borrowers – but not both – have little opportunity for netting. Netting
opportunities are therefore more likely to occur in the interdealer market, so it is
not surprising that the current repo CCP operates in this segment of the market. 12

10

Principle 7 in the Principles for Financial Market Infrastructures, April 2012. Committee on Payment and
Settlement Systems and Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions.
www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d101a.pdf
11
See Financial Accounting Standards Board Interpretation No. 41, “Offsetting of Amounts Related to Certain
Repurchase and Reverse Purchase Agreements,”
www.fasb.org/jsp/FASB/Document_C/DocumentPage?cid=1175801626916&acceptedDisclaimer=true
12
Repo CCPs mainly exist in markets where the underlying flows provide large-scale opportunities for multilateral
netting. For example, CCPs play a large role in the European and the Canadian repo markets, which are primarily
interbank markets.

12

Further gains in netting could arise if clearing expanded to the bilateral market or if
some of the larger end users in the tri-party market, for example money market
mutual funds or hedge funds, were able to gain access to the CCP. This could pose
its own complications, however, as some of these institutions may be unwilling or
legally unable to engage in the risk mutualization that exists in most clearing
models.
Conclusion
Despite these challenges, it is worth noting that, in the right setting, central
clearing can produce significant benefits, including reduced credit and liquidity
risks; improved default management and reduced risk of fire sales; greater
transparency; and improved risk management. Of course, this does not mean that
every product should be cleared, or that every type of repo trading would benefit
from clearing. In my view, clearing should be limited to those assets that are
highly liquid and expected to remain so even in severely stressed market
conditions. While any model for expanded repo clearing will have to satisfy
stringent regulatory requirements, regulators should be open to emerging clearing
solutions where they provide substantial benefits and can meet these standards.
This may be particularly true for repo trading in government and agency securities,
since new regulations require financial institutions to hold such high-quality
collateral under the assumption that it can be quickly converted to cash. It is
13

therefore important to consider ways to support their continued liquidity where
possible.

14

Figure 1. Bilateral and Centrally Cleared Networks

Bilaterally Cleared Network

Centrally Cleared Network

Note: The figure on the left shows a bilateral network in the credit default swap (CDS) market for a single and highly traded CDS contract. The figure on the right shows the
hypothetical network that would exist if the contract were cleared through a single central counterparty. In each figure, a red circle denotes a protection seller and a blue one
denotes a protection buyer. The size of the circle represents the amount of protection bought or sold.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

Figure 2. Direct Links between LISCC Banks and Global CCPs

Note: The figure illustrates the network between banks in the portfolio of the Large Institution Supervision Coordinating Committee (LISCC), represented by blue circles, and
central counterparties (CCPs), represented by red circles. Each connection indicates the relationship between a member bank and the CCP.
Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Figure 3. A Map of the U.S. Repo Market
2
Bilateral Bilateral cash investors:
repo
▪ Asset managers
market ▪ Others

1

3

Bilateral cash borrowers:
▪ Prime brokerage clients
▪ Others

Securities
dealers
Triparty
repo
market

Tri-party cash investors:
▪ Money market
mutual funds
▪ Securities lenders
▪ Others

4

General collateral finance
(GCF)
5