View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech to a Community Outreach Luncheon
Boise, Idaho
By Janet L. Yellen, President and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
For delivery September 7, 2006 – 12:40 PM Mountain Time, 2:40 PM Eastern

Prospects for the U.S. Economy

Good afternoon. I'm delighted to be with you today. I'd like to start by saying
how much I appreciate the very warm welcome we've received here, especially from
many of our past and present Directors. They have done a great job of arranging for us to
see some of the highlights of your beautiful city. High on the list, of course, was the
Basque Museum, which reflects the many cultural and economic contributions Basque
immigrants and their descendants have made to this area and, indeed, to the nation.
Unfortunately, that tour was scheduled during our Board meeting, so I had to miss it. My
envy was soothed a bit, though, because I was able to attend a special presentation and
demonstration of the research being done at the Center for Ecohydraulic Research at the
Idaho Water Center, clearly a worldclass scientific research facility. So, all in all, I have
to agree with what Money Magazine had to say recently about Boise: It definitely
deserves its ranking among the top ten "Best Places to Live" in the country.
Although I obviously get a lot of personal pleasure out of traveling around the
District to places like Boise, I'm also here for important official reasons. One of the great
strengths of the Federal Reserve is its connection to the citizenry of the country. In this
respect, the twelve Reserve Banks play a particularly important role. Through our
directors, our advisory councils, and through meetings like this one, we can get some
insight into the public's viewpoint on issues that are vital to the conduct of monetary
policy—issues like labor market conditions, expectations about inflation, and industry-

specific developments, to name just a few. So I'm very much looking forward to the
question and answer session that will follow my remarks, because I'm sure that I'm going
to learn from you as much as you're going to learn from me!
My remarks today will focus on conditions in the U.S. economy and their
implications for monetary policy. But before I begin, let me note that my comments
represent my own views and not necessarily those of my colleagues in the Federal
Reserve System.
The last time I spoke publicly was a little more than a month ago. Since then,
something unusual happened. After raising short-term interest rates at every one of its 17
meetings beginning in June 2004, the Federal Open Market Committee decided not to
tighten the stance of monetary policy at its last meeting, which was last month. As a
matter of fact, the August meeting was the first since I became President of the Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco that the Committee didn't raise rates. The August pause
may seem a bit puzzling to some, since we had some rather bad news on inflation for
several months in a row. Today, I'd like to focus my remarks on why I think the pause
was a good idea, and, of course, in following that theme, I'll need to get into the prospects
for the U.S. economy.
I'll start with a quick review of recent developments. The U.S. economy has
suffered some significant shocks in the past couple of years: in particular, a sustained
surge in energy prices and the devastation from the twin hurricanes just over a year ago.
Despite these challenges, the economy grew at a solid clip, averaging just over 3¼
percent for the past two years.

This pace of growth is moderately above current estimates of the growth rate that
is sustainable in the long run, and it has lasted long enough to eliminate much of the slack
in labor and product markets that was apparent a year ago. Over that time, both the rate
of unused capacity in the industrial sector and the civilian unemployment rate have fallen
noticeably. Indeed, the unemployment rate dropped by about three-fourths of a
percentage point, coming in at 4¾ percent in August. This rate is actually a little bit
lower than conventional estimates of so-called "full employment," and therefore suggests
that there may be some tightness in labor markets.
Turning to inflation, the recent news, as I said, hasn't been what I'd like to see.
Headline inflation, as measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index,
showed an increase of three and a half percent over the twelve months ending in July.
While this is an important and comprehensive index of changes in the cost of living, the
Committee also focuses on a different measure—the core number, which excludes the
volatile food and energy components—because it is a better indicator of underlying
trends in inflation. This measure rose at an uncomfortably high rate of nearly 2½ percent
over the past year. Although it is encouraging that the rate has edged down recently, it
has remained a bit above my "comfort zone"—a range between one and two percent that I
consider an appropriate long-run inflation objective for the Fed.
With labor and product markets close to full utilization and inflation above the
comfort zone, one of the key questions for policy is whether economic growth will
proceed at a moderate enough rate, and stay there long enough, to avoid a sustained
buildup of inflationary pressures. And that is my next topic.
Prospects for Economic Activity

Recent data suggest that the needed slowdown is indeed underway. After hitting
a rapid 5½ percent pace in the first quarter, real GDP growth slowed in the second quarter
to a rate of just under 3 percent. In looking ahead to the rest of the year, I see factors
working both to support economic activity and to restrain it somewhat. Taken together,
these lead me to expect that we'll probably see growth that is healthy, but somewhat
below the rate that is sustainable in the long run.
The factors working to support growth include ongoing strength in business
demand, fueling relatively rapid growth in spending on nonresidential structures as well
as in business investment in equipment and software. This sector, of course, includes
high-tech industries, which are important to Boise. To the extent that business
investments in computer equipment continue to grow, this will help sustain your area's
rapid economic expansion, which has been propelled in part by the success of local hightech companies in recent years.
As for factors that could restrain the nation's growth, one immediately thinks of
energy prices, which have surged over the past couple of years. This increase has been
due to developments on both the demand and the supply sides of the market. Demand for
energy has been quite strong, not only from industrial economies, but also from emerging
markets, most notably, China. On the supply side, there are reports of limited capacity to
expand production, not to mention extraordinary events that threaten to restrict supply,
like disruptions in the Middle East.
It appears that the resulting higher energy prices have restrained consumer
spending, even while offsets from job gains, as well as growth in wages and wealth have
kept it rising overall. Of course, further increases in energy prices could imply some

additional restraint. However, futures markets expect energy prices to stabilize around
current levels. If they do, then the restraint we've felt this year should evaporate over
2007, and that could actually contribute to a pickup in growth next year. But that's a very
big "if." The fact is that futures markets haven't done such a hot job at predicting where
these prices are headed. Ever since energy prices started to rise in 2004, futures markets
have usually predicted a relatively flat path going forward. When oil was $30 a barrel,
they implied the price would flatten out. At $40 a barrel, they implied the price would
flatten out. At $50 a barrel—well, you get the picture. And here we are with oil
fluctuating around $70 a barrel. So energy prices are a bit of a wildcard.
Another factor restraining growth is the rise in interest rates over the past couple
of years as the Fed has removed monetary policy accommodation. Since this process
began in mid-2004, short- and intermediate-term interest rates are up substantially. Longterm rates present a more mixed picture, with some—such as mortgage rates—up
slightly, and others down slightly. The overall effect of these rate changes should be to
reduce demand, particularly in interest-sensitive sectors, such as autos, consumer
durables, and housing.
Indeed, we already have seen clear evidence of cooling in the housing sector.
Nationally, housing permits are down noticeably—by more than 20 percent—from a year
ago. In addition, inventories of unsold houses are up significantly, sales of new and
existing homes are off their peaks, and surveys of homebuyers and builders are showing
much more pessimistic attitudes. Even in a market that has been as hot as Boise's, some
recent evidence points to cooling in the pace of home sales and residential construction
activity.

The national data on residential investment reflect all of these developments and
enter directly into the calculation of real GDP growth. After adjusting for inflation, (real)
residential investment dropped at nearly a 10 percent annual rate in the second quarter
following two small declines in the prior two quarters.
The effects of the housing slowdown go beyond their direct contribution to GDP.
In particular, what happens to house prices could have important effects on consumer
spending, which is a very big part of the economy—roughly 70 percent. As we all know,
the pace of house-price appreciation has definitely moderated, after rising at heartstopping rates in recent years. And there are signs that it may continue. For example,
rents are finally moving up more vigorously after a long period of stagnation. This may
reflect, in part, expectations that house-price appreciation will continue to slow, as
landlords raise rents to try to maintain the total rate of return on rental properties and as
those in the market for housing grow more inclined to rent than to buy.
Slower increases in house prices could weaken consumer spending in a couple of
ways. Both of them have to do with what I'm going to call the "piggy bank"
phenomenon. To be honest, I've stolen this term from some news stories I've seen, but I
think the crime is worth it because the description is apt. Back when house prices were
rising so fast, people saw that more and more equity was being built up in their house
values; in other words, they saw their houses as piggy banks that got fuller and fuller,
faster and faster, by just sitting there. Insofar as the piggybank of house value makes up
a good chunk of many households' portfolios, they might well have felt that they could
afford to spend pretty freely. In economic terms, this is called the "wealth effect." A
second factor stimulating spending relates to the ease with which households can now

pull money out of the piggy bank. With home equity loans, refinancings, and so on, the
piggy bank is now pretty simple to access. So it's no surprise that homeowners seized the
opportunity and drew some of the money out to support their spending. Now, with the
pace of house-price appreciation slowing, of course, the piggy bank is not getting so full
so fast anymore, which may weaken the growth in consumer spending.
While it's likely that the slowdown in the housing sector will have only
moderating effects on economic activity and will continue to unfold in an orderly way, I
should note that we can't ignore the risk that a more unpleasant scenario might develop.
In particular, we have heard a lot in recent years about the possibility that there is a
house-price "bubble," implying that prices got out of line with the fundamental value of
houses and that the current softening could be just the beginning of a steep fall. While I
doubt that we'll see anything like a "popping of the bubble"—in part because I'm not
convinced there is a bubble, at least on a national level—it is a risk we have to watch out
for.
Another risk has to do with household saving behavior. In the U.S., the personal
saving rate has been declining for more than a decade. During the 1980s, it averaged 9
percent. This July, it was all the way down to minus 1 percent. Frankly, it's hard to see
how it could go much lower. So the risk is that a sustained rise could occur, which would
put a real crimp in consumer spending and therefore in overall economic activity.
Though there's some uncertainty about why the saving rate has fallen into negative
territory, I strongly suspect that part of it is related to the growth in consumer wealth over
the last several years both through rising housing values and through rising stock values.
Therefore, the more recent softening in both of those sources of wealth may provide a bit

more impetus for a reversal in the saving trend; in other words, it is conceivable that
people will shift gears and try to build up savings the old-fashioned way, by spending
less. Whatever its source, the very low—in fact, negative—saving rate represents a
downside risk for the economy, with the chance of sizeable drop-off in consumer
spending likely to be bigger than a surge in spending.
Prospects for Inflation
This brings me to the outlook for inflation. As I've indicated, core consumer
inflation has been a bit above my comfort zone recently. Therefore, in keeping with the
Committee's responsibilities for promoting price stability for the nation, I believe it is
critical that inflation trend in a downward direction over the medium term. Indeed, my
expectation is that this is the most likely outcome.
That said, I must admit that I'm also less sanguine than I was a month ago about
one particular factor in the inflation process—namely, labor compensation. This factor is
a major component of business costs and can therefore affect the prices that firms charge
for their products. A month ago it appeared that compensation was growing quite
modestly. Moreover, for nonfarm businesses, markups of product prices over costs have
been near historic highs, which means that businesses have had room to absorb higher
costs rather than passing them on to their customers. These two developments together
gave me considerable comfort in thinking about the inflation outlook. However, recently
revised information on compensation per hour suggests that wages and benefits are
growing rapidly. This blurs the picture considerably, since another measure, the
Employment Cost Index, shows only moderate growth. Of course, we also look for
information about labor markets from people around the District. Here in Idaho, our

contacts tell us that they have noticed shortages of skilled workers, and they also are
seeing increasing difficulties recruiting unskilled workers, all of which has put strong
upward pressure on wages in the state. While reports like these do heighten my sense of
concern, I still draw some comfort from the fact that markups remain very high. So, even
with more cost pressures, firms would have the room to absorb the increases without
fully passing them on into their prices if competitive conditions in product markets
induced them to do so.
Beyond this, I would point to several factors that could make inflationary
pressures recede. The first factor I want to discuss is a somewhat technical point. Try to
bear with me on this, because it does matter. In statistical analyses of inflation, the data
historically have exhibited persistence. This basically means that, when you're
forecasting inflation, it works pretty well to assume that the rate in the future will be the
same as it is today. The implication of persistence is frankly worrisome: Since inflation
is too high today, persistence implies it could stay too high for an extended period.
However, recent research at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco has shed
new light on this issue. 1 It finds less evidence of persistence during the past ten years.
That is, rather than sticking at a certain rate, inflation has tended to revert to its long-run
average, which, over that period, is within my comfort zone. Admittedly, the past ten
years constitute a relatively small sample from which to draw definitive conclusions.
Nonetheless, this evidence is important because, if it holds up, it implies that inflation
may move down from its elevated level faster than many forecasters expect.

1

John C. Williams, “The Phillips Curve in an Era of Well-Anchored Inflation Expectations,” unpublished
paper, http://www.frbsf.org/economics/economists/staff.php?jwilliams.

Interestingly, this apparent decline in the persistence of core inflation has
occurred at roughly the same time that long-run inflation expectations appear to have
become well anchored. The behavior of long-run inflation expectations can serve as a
kind of proxy for the Fed's credibility as an inflation-fighter. For example, in the face of
the large energy price increases we've seen in recent years, this credibility shows up in
the stability of survey and market measures of inflation expectations covering the period
five-to-ten years ahead. This may not be a coincidence. Research suggests that if a
central bank's commitment to price stability has gained credibility with the public, then
the persistence observed in the inflation data will tend to be dampened.
I would like to stress that our Bank's recent research on persistence concerns
simple correlations in the inflation data that can be used for forecasting only, and it does
not necessarily inform us about how policy decisions affect the economy or about the
best course for policy. In other words, low persistence is no reason for the Fed to rest on
its laurels of credibility. Rather, credibility is something that neither I—nor my
colleagues—take for granted for a moment. We know full well that maintaining
credibility requires that we act when necessary to keep inflation under control.
Another reason to expect inflationary pressures to lessen has to do with energy
prices and what is called "passthrough." Even though higher energy prices do not seem
to have boosted long-term inflation expectations, the energy shock may have been passed
through to recent results for core inflation itself. This might seem surprising, since core
inflation excludes energy prices. But even so, it is possible that higher energy prices
have passed through into the prices of core goods that use energy as an input to
production—airfares are a good example. Now it's true that recent research suggests that

the extent of passthrough for any given rise in energy prices has been lower in the past
twenty-five years than it was back in the 1970s. However, it seems likely that energy
passthrough probably has played at least some role in recent core inflation movements.
In this case, if energy prices level out, as expected by futures markets, this upward
pressure on core inflation is likely to dissipate at some point, and this would help on the
inflation front.
Finally, as I've explained, the economy appears to have entered a period of
slightly below-trend growth. If it continues, as I think is likely, it would tend to moderate
any underlying inflationary pressures over time. This factor, together with the others I've
discussed, provides reason to think that the most likely outcome is that inflation will
move gradually lower. However, I am keenly aware that this pattern has yet to show up
in the data. The inflation outlook remains highly uncertain, and until we actually see
inflation begin to slow down, I will be focused on the notable upside risks in the outlook.

Policy issues
This leads me to the concluding topic in my presentation today—monetary policy.
As you know, in August the FOMC decided not to raise the funds rate for the first time in
more than two years. I think this was the prudent course of action that properly balances
the dual mandate given to the Fed by Congress—to foster price stability and maximum
sustainable employment.
Given that inflation is outside of my comfort zone, why do I think it makes sense
to pause? In these circumstances, it might be thought that policy should continue to
tighten until the inflation data move back to a rate consistent with price stability. But I

would argue that a gradual approach is likely to be better because there is a need to
incorporate lags between policy actions and effects on the economy. We don't know
what the lags are with precision, but we still need to do the best we can to take them into
account. We simply don't get the necessary feedback on the effects of our policy actions
for a long time. So if we kept automatically raising rates until we saw inflation start to
respond, we most likely would have gone too far, which would unnecessarily endanger
the economic expansion. Instead we need to be forward-looking.
And, by a variety of measures, it appears that the current stance of policy will
move inflation gradually back to the comfort zone while giving due consideration to the
risks to economic activity. By a variety measures, I'm referring to my forecast that I have
outlined today, as well as the recommendations from commonly used monetary policy
rules that are used to gauge the stance of policy. Taken as a whole, these rules indicate
that the funds rate is currently within the range that appears appropriate, given the current
condition of the labor market and the position of inflation relative to my comfort zone.
However, since all such approaches are inherently imprecise, policy must be
responsive to the data as it emerges. The advantage of pausing is that it allows us more
time to observe the data. When I say that policy should be responsive to the data, I mean
that any additional firming should depend on how emerging developments affect the
economic outlook. And when I say data, I don't just mean data on inflation, output, and
employment. I also mean data on factors that might affect those variables in the future—
such as energy prices, the dollar, the stock market, long-term interest rates, housing
prices and inflation expectations.

The bottom line is this. With inflation too high, policy must have a bias toward
further firming. However, our past actions have already put a lot of firming in the
pipeline. With the lags in policy we haven't yet seen the full effect of our past actions.
These will unfold gradually over time. By pausing, we allowed ourselves more time to
observe the data and more time to gauge how much, if any, additional firming is needed
to pursue our dual mandate.
Thank you for having me today, and I will be pleased to address your questions.

###