View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:15 a.m. EST (4:15 p.m. CET)
November 7, 2014

Panel Discussion on “Shaping the Future of the Macroeconomic Policy Mix”

Remarks by
Janet L. Yellen
Chair
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
“Central Banking: The Way Forward?”
International Symposium of the Banque de France
Paris, France

November 7, 2014

I would like to thank the Banque de France for inviting me to take part in what I
expect will be a lively discussion.
The suddenness and severity of the global financial crisis forced policymakers to
respond rapidly and creatively, employing a wide range of macroeconomic tools-including both monetary and fiscal policies--to arrest a steep economic downturn and
restart the global economy. Given the slow and unsteady nature of the recovery,
supportive policy remains necessary.
Today I would like to briefly review the evolution of monetary and fiscal policies
following the global financial crisis both in the United States and in other advanced
economies, since we have faced similar experiences and employed similar policy
responses. I will try to draw some lessons and provide some thoughts on the policy mix
going forward.
Policy before the Crisis
Prior to the global financial crisis, inflation rates in the United States and other
advanced economies were near their target levels and most of these economies appeared
to be operating close to their potential. Policy interest rates were similarly in the vicinity
of levels considered to be normal.
Fiscal deficits also appeared to be under control before the crisis. According to
the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), general
government deficits in 2007 were less than 4 percent of GDP in the United States and the
United Kingdom, about 2 percent in Japan, and less than 1 percent, on average, in the
euro area. Still, given relatively buoyant economic conditions, governments probably
should have been doing more to prepare for the long-term challenge of aging populations,

-2which will boost pension obligations and health-care expenditures in coming years.
Moreover, government debt levels were already high in Japan and in some European
economies and not particularly low elsewhere. In addition, some euro-area countries that
appeared to have strong fiscal positions going into the crisis depended partly on revenue
from housing booms that soon went bust.
The Policy Response to the Crisis
When the crisis hit, its global scope and severity were exceptional. Central banks
in the United States and other countries responded by rapidly and sharply reducing their
policy interest rates, lowering them in many cases to near zero. In addition, in their role
as lenders of last resort, central banks acted rapidly to provide liquidity to help stabilize
the financial system and support the flow of credit to households and businesses, in some
cases creating new lending facilities. These extraordinary and creative responses showed
that monetary policymakers had internalized the lessons of the Great Depression.
Initially, fiscal policy also provided significant stimulus. A portion of this
stimulus reflected the operation of automatic stabilizers--higher unemployment benefits,
for example, and a decline in tax payments due to lower incomes--and some came
through cuts in tax rates and increases in discretionary spending. Expansive fiscal policy
served to raise deficits in most countries, some of which faced further costs from
stabilizing financial institutions, pushing deficits even higher. Sharp increases in deficits
led in turn to escalating levels of government debt.
Policy during the Recovery
The combination of increasing debt and depressed output led to rising ratios of
debt to gross domestic product (GDP) in many advanced economies and heightened
concern about whether the growth in debt could be sustained without unsettling financial

-3markets. As a result, early in the recovery governments began to withdraw fiscal
stimulus, and, in most cases, fiscal policy became a net drag on economic growth. This
outcome was most evident in the euro-area periphery, where skyrocketing bond yields
and deepening concerns about default left governments with little choice about whether
to rein in stimulus. In Spain, for example, the OECD estimates that fiscal consolidation
has subtracted an average of 1-1/2 percentage points from GDP growth each year since
2009. But fiscal policy also turned contractionary in countries facing less market
pressure, such as the United Kingdom and the United States. Governments in both
countries embarked on fiscal consolidation programs over the past four years, sharply
reducing their structural deficits, and, as a consequence, creating headwinds that slowed
the recovery.
With fiscal drag weighing on growth and with private-sector deleveraging also
holding back consumption and investment, monetary policy bore the brunt of supporting
the economy. With policy rates at or approaching zero, central banks of necessity turned
to unconventional policy tools such as large-scale asset purchases and enhanced forward
guidance about the future path of policy rates. These unconventional tools have, in my
view, served to support a recovery in domestic demand and, as a consequence, global
economic growth.
Even so, the recovery in most advanced nations has proceeded more slowly than
policymakers would have hoped. This sluggishness has been due in part to the severity
of the financial shock associated with the crisis and the persistent headwinds to recovery
in its aftermath. But the lack of fiscal support for demand in recent years also helps

-4account for the weakness of this recovery compared with past recoveries. 1 In the United
States, fiscal policy has been much less supportive relative to previous recoveries. For
instance, at a comparable point in the recovery from the 2001 recession, employment at
all levels of government had increased by about 800,000 workers; in contrast, in the
current recovery, government employment has declined by about 650,000 jobs.
Lessons
What lessons can we draw from this experience? The first is that governments
need to address long-term challenges and significantly improve their structural fiscal
balances during good times so they have more fiscal space to provide stimulus when
times turn bad. When poor economic conditions drive policy interest rates close to the
zero lower bound, fiscal stimulus may be more effective than usual in boosting aggregate
demand because it will not have the usual effect of raising real interest rates, thereby
crowding out private demand. 2
A second lesson is that, while even if it is appropriate for fiscal policy to play a
larger role when policy rates are near zero, policymakers nevertheless may face
constraints in implementing fiscal stimulus. This means that central banks need to be
prepared to employ all available tools, including unconventional policies, to support
economic growth and to reach their inflation targets.

1

See Greg Howard, Robert Martin, and Beth Anne Wilson (2011), “Are Recoveries from Banking and
Financial Crises Really So Different?” International Finance Discussion Papers 1037 (Washington: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November),
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2011/1037/default.htm.
2
See, for instance, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo (2011), “When Is the
Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 119 (February), pp. 78-121;
and J. Bradford Delong and Lawrence H. Summers (2012), “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 233-97.

-5A third critical lesson pertains to the importance of having a sound and resilient
financial sector with strong capitalization and prudent risk management, supported by
effective regulation and supervision. The recent crisis has appropriately increased the
focus on financial stability at central banks around the world. At the European Central
Bank (ECB), the recent comprehensive assessment is an important step toward building
confidence in euro-area banks. I wish the ECB great success as it takes on its new
responsibilities at the center of the single supervisory mechanism. At the Federal
Reserve, we have devoted substantially increased resources to monitoring financial
stability and have refocused our regulatory and supervisory efforts to limit the buildup of
systemic risk. This macroprudential approach to promoting financial stability will be an
important complement to our other tools for promoting a healthy economy.
Looking Ahead
In advanced economies, the current macroeconomic policy mix generally remains
one of extraordinary monetary policy stimulus and somewhat contractionary fiscal
policy. Considering the headwinds that continue to weigh on growth, employment, and
prices, this situation is hardly ideal. Policymakers face difficult choices as they seek to
balance the need for long-term fiscal sustainability with the need to support their
economies in the near term.
Even so, I continue to anticipate that the headwinds associated with the financial
crisis will wane. As employment, economic activity, and inflation rates return to normal,
monetary policy will eventually need to normalize too, although the speed and timing of
this normalization will likely differ across countries based on differences in the pace of
recovery in domestic conditions. This normalization could lead to some heightened
financial volatility. But as I have noted on other occasions, for our part, the Federal

-6Reserve will strive to clearly and transparently communicate its monetary policy strategy
in order to minimize the likelihood of surprises that could disrupt financial markets, both
at home and around the world. More importantly, the normalization of monetary policy
will be an important sign that economic conditions more generally are finally emerging
from the shadow of the Great Recession.