View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:15 a.m. EST
March 13, 1996

Remarks by

Janet L. Yellen

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at the

National Association of Business Economists

Washington, D.C.

March 13, 1996

Monetary Policy: Goals and Strategy

I'm delighted to appear today before the National Association of Business Economists.
To provide some background for your thinking about the conduct of monetary policy going
forward, I'd like to discuss the appropriate ultimate objectives for the Federal Reserve and the
strategies for attaining those goals. A backdrop for my remarks is the worldwide upsurge in
sentiment supporting price stability as the primary long-term goal for monetary policy. In
several foreign countries this sentiment has been reflected in a move to explicit inflation
targeting, which I'll discuss. I'll touch on some innovative recent research by economists
which highlights the advantages of employing policy feedback rules to implement a price
stability objective. Are such approaches useful in the United States? This will be the focus
of my talk.
Any discussion of the strategy for conducting monetary policy must begin by
specifying the appropriate goals. In my view, the appropriate primary long-term goal for the
Federal Reserve should be price stability, an objective which no one would deny is within the
power of the central bank to accomplish. This view will probably not prove controversial
here. Inflation clearly creates costs: it distorts price signals, complicates business planning,
induces arbitrary redistributions of wealth and, under the current tax system, likely raises the
cost of capital, diminishing the incentives to save and invest. Uncertainty about inflation is
reflected in risk premia embodied in interest rates and in increased concern by households
about their future financial security.

Recent history has provided all too many country case

studies—from Latin America, Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union—which exemplify
the economic disruptions which inflation causes when it reaches high or hyperinflationary
levels. But even when inflation is far lower—as in the United States during the I970's and

2
early 80's—it still imposes costs.
While few economists would deny that price stability should be the primary long-run
goal of a central bank, some would argue that it should be the one and only goal, because the
Federal Reserve can contribute little else. This wrongminded conclusion cannot be justified
by appeal to the well-known natural rate hypothesis, according to which, there is no long-run
tradeoff between unemployment and inflation. Like most mainstream economists, I accept the
natural rate theory, as a first approximation, of how the inflation process works in the United
States. Accordingly, I believe that any attempt to push the economy to operate with labor
market slack below some minimum level is apt to entail not just higher but accelerating
inflation—a clearly unacceptable outcome. That minimum rate-the natural rate or NAIRU-importantly reflects a number of structural aspects of the economy, including the efficiency of
the labor market in matching workers to job vacancies, the geographic mobility of workers,
the quality of the skills they bring to the labor market, the demographics of the labor force,
and the extent of structural mismatch between job vacancies and unemployed workers. This
rate can vary over time.
According to a simple version of the natural rate hypothesis, the NAIRU is immune to
the conduct of monetary policy. Conceivably, however, a protracted period of high
unemployment could cause an increase in the NAIRU. This could occur if workers who are
unemployed for a long period of time find that their job skills deteriorate and so their labor
market attachment decreases. As a result, they may~by their disengaged unemploymentafford over time a lower level of effective restraint on the wages of employed workers. Some
evidence for such hysteresis effects can be found in European countries, but not, thus far, in

3
the United States, apparently because of the flexibility of our labor markets.
Even if we assume that Federal Reserve policy has no impact at all on the natural rate
of unemployment, it does not follow that the Fed should focus exclusively on inflation.
Indeed, I think that the Federal Reserve should, can and has done more. In my view,
monetary policy is needed, and has succeeded, in smoothing the ups and downs of the
business cycle—mitigating economic fluctuations and stabilizing output and employment in the
U.S. economy. Fluctuations in output and jobs diminish welfare, impede business and
household planning and create uncertainty which is harmful to investment. Volatility in
employment impairs the job security of workers. Households and businesses dislike
fluctuations in output and employment. Their preferences aren't foolish or irrational—they are
extremely sensible. It thus follows that stabilization of output and employment is a second
appropriate goal for the Federal Reserve.
In some academic audiences steeped in rational expectations theory, I would feel
compelled to explain how the Federal Reserve can have any systematic real short-run effects
on the economy. But I need not convince this audience that we can influence real interest
rates, which in turn will impinge on real economic activity. I believe this point is amply
demonstrated by U.S. experience ranging from the recession of 1981-82 through the current
lengthy economic expansion. I further think that this experience suggests that our actions on
balance have worked to stabilize real output and employment. I recognize the difficulty of
conducting monetary policy over time in a way that will damp business cycles, and I will
return to this subject later in my talk. But I do not concede that uncertainties of economic
forecasts and long and variable policy lags inevitably doom our best efforts to failure. The

4
record to me indicates that within limits "tuning" works, even if it's not fine.
Because the American people possess multiple goals, and because the Federal Reserve
can have a desirable short-run effect on economic performance across multiple dimensions, I
think it follows almost automatically that the Federal Reserve should be directed to pursue
multiple objectives simultaneously. Some people wonder whether the Federal Reserve can
simultaneously pursue both price and output stability as dual objectives when the Fed has
only one tool-the Federal funds rate-at its disposal. They argue that with one tool, the Fed
should focus on just one goal and ignore all else. As I see it, in the world of the natural rate
theory, there is no conflict whatever between pursuing price stability as the primary long-term
goal while simultaneously operating to help stabilize the economy's real economic
performance. During the transition toward price stability, placing weight on the output
stabilization objective implies that progress in reducing inflation should be gradual. Even
after price stability has been attained, there will remain some tradeoff between reducing the
volatility of real outcomes and reducing the variability of inflation around whatever measured
target is deemed to correspond to price stability. On many occasions though, as when the
economy is buffeted by demand shocks, the Federal Reserve's usual policy of leaning against
the wind serves the dual objectives of reduced output volatility and low and stable inflation
simultaneously.
The existence of policy tradeoffs requires a strategy for managing them. John Taylor,
of Stanford University, has designed a policy rule of thumb that neatly illustrates how a
central bank can pursue stabilization policy without losing its focus on the long-term price
stability goal. According to the Taylor rule, the Fed's key instrument, the federal funds rate,

5
should respond to gaps between actual and ideal performance on each of the Fed's dual
objectives-price stability and output stability. The Taylor rule calls for the Fed to adjust the
real federal funds rate above his estimated 2% "neutral" or "equilibrium" level, by an amount
which depends on the deviation between actual and potential output and the deviation
between actual and target inflation. More precisely, as Taylor originally formulated his rule,
the "real federal funds rate"--measured as the gap between the nominal funds rate and the 4
quarter rate of change in the GDP deflator-was set at 2% + 1/2 the gap between actual
output and potential output + 1/2 the gap between actual inflation and Taylor's assumed 2%
target. If both gaps are zero, the central bank sets the real federal funds rate at 2 percent, by
setting the nominal funds rate 2 percentage points above the inflation rate over the last four
quarters. (That is, the nominal funds rate would be 4 percent.) Taylor set the long-run
inflation target at 2 percent, referring to the implicit GDP deflator. If real output were to
move up relative to its potential, or the inflation rate were to rise above its target, say by 1
percentage point in either case, then the central bank would respond by moving the real
federal funds rate up by 1/2 percentage point.
As a general strategy for conducting monetary policy, this rule-of-thumb has several
desirable features. By incorporating an explicit long-run inflation target, it affords the
macroeconomy a built-in nominal anchor. When output is at its potential, the rule implies
that the real federal funds rate will be above its long-run equilibrium level when the trend
inflation rate exceeds its long-run target. By this measure, the degree of monetary tightness
would be proportional to the overshooting of inflation from this target, other things equal.
Following this rule-of-thumb would set forces in motion ultimately leading to attainment of

6
the inflation target. The central bank would not allow the inflation rate to follow a random
walk across business cycles, which in the face of economic shocks could well result if the
Federal Reserve were to focus solely on real economic performance. A central bank that
adhered to the Taylor rule would certainly deserve credibility in the public's mind for its
anti-inflationary resolve. At the same time, the central bank would act to resist business
cycles affecting real output and employment. And here too, the larger the deviation from
potential, the larger the policy response, other things equal.
Another feature of Taylor's specification of his rule is a willingness to accept
somewhat more temporary inflation than otherwise to prevent output from falling further
below its potential in the short run. The central bank would leave the real federal funds rate
unchanged if, for example, the four-quarter inflation rate rose by 1 percentage point while
simultaneously real output fell 1 percent below its potential. In the face of an oil shock,
therefore, the central bank would be willing to accept some near-term worsening of inflation
to avoid even less output in the short run. The Taylor rule, like nominal GNP targeting rules
which are first cousins, embody a strategy for handling tradeoffs on occasions when the need
arises. Sometimes a central bank would lower the real funds rate to combat a rise in
unemployment even with inflation above target, but such steps would be taken in the context
of a systematic long-run strategy geared toward price stability. This acceptance of a specific
short-run tradeoff between the two objectives strikes me as the logical consequence of having
multiple objectives.
A third desirable feature of rules like Taylor's is that they have been shown in
stochastic simulations using large-scale econometric models to deliver remarkably good

7
performance in the face of a wide variety of shocks in circumstances when policymakers
know neither the structure of the economy nor the actual source of shocks which are
operative. Taylor-type rules, with feedback from inflation and output gaps to short term
interest rates, typically earn higher scores than such alternative approaches as pure inflation
targets, fixed exchange rates, monetary aggregate targets, and nominal GNP targets when
social welfare depends on both of those gaps. To the best of my knowledge, no one has
demonstrated that Taylor's ad hoc reaction function is ideal in any sense, and the search for
better feedback rules for monetary policy remains an active research area in academia and at
the Federal Reserve. If one knew the source of a particular shock, whether it were permanent
or transitory, and the appropriate model of the economy, including the precise lag structure of
the effects of policy, or if one were to use forecast values of inflation and output in the
feedback mechanism rather than just the current levels, one could surely do better. The
Federal Open Market Committee is always trying to do better. But unfortunately, I must
confess that just occasionally even your almost omniscient Federal Reserve harbors some
doubt about the source of shocks, the structure of the economy and the reliability of our
forecasts of inflation and output running 6-8 quarters out. So a response system which is
robust in the face of mistakes has a certain appeal.
Finally, the framework of a Taylor-type rule could help the Federal Reserve
communicate to the public the rationale behind policy moves, and how those moves are
consistent with its objectives. For example, if inflation were at its long-run target and output
were below its potential, the Fed might well choose to adopt an easier-than-average stance of
policy. Making reference to the Taylor rule or some similar framework might help the Fed

8

communicate that such a stance was consistent with its long-run inflation objective. Clarity
of communication can make the Fed's task easier by reducing the odds of unpredictable and
counterproductive reactions in financial markets.
Thus, the Taylor rule has appealing properties as a normative description of how
policy ought to be conducted. But as Taylor himself, and more recently Business Week, have
noted, it also does a pretty fair job as a positive description of how policy actually has been
conducted over the past decade or so. That is to say, the prescriptions from the rule capture
the broad contours of Federal Reserve policy during the past decade reasonably well. Perhaps
this is not too surprising, given that the two variables determining the policy stance under the
rule clearly are of central concern to the Federal Reserve.
At the same time, it is also probably not terribly surprising that there have been times
during the past decade when the Fed has departed quite markedly from the path that would
have resulted from a mechanical reading of the rule. By far the most pronounced such
departure occurred during the early phases of the current expansion, in 1992 and 1993, when
the Fed responded to the so-called "financial headwinds" buffeting the economy by holding
short rates well below the levels that would have been prescribed by Taylor's rule. In
retrospect, this departure from the rule appears to have been right on target. Another welladvised departure occurred in the wake of the 1987 stock-market crash, when the Fed moved
quite aggressively to provide liquidity to the markets.
In forming their views about the course of policy, the members of the Open Market
Committee inspect a vast amount of economic data beyond those that are relevant for
discerning the current level of economic activity and inflation. Consequently, while Taylor's

9
rule captures the broad contours of Fed policy, it is not particularly useful for explaining the
precise timing and magnitude of policy actions.
With the Greenspan Fed's policies often approximating the predictions of the Taylor
rule, the American economy has enjoyed a period of remarkably good economic performance.
Progress has been made toward price stability, although we are not there yet, and growth has
been more stable than otherwise, although the business cycle has not been fully conquered. It
should not prove surprising that the Fed is not the only central bank whose behavior can be
approximated by a Taylor-style rule. Recent research suggests that the Bundesbank's policies
can be characterized as following Taylor-like strategies as well, even in the context of its
money supply target. This can be seen in its permitting inflation to rise temporarily following
German unification and cutting interest rates rapidly in 1993 to promote recovery even with
inflation above target levels.
I have used the Taylor rule to illustrate in a concrete way that a sensible approach can
be devised to manage dual objectives, and have emphasized its approximate fit to actual Fed
behavior. The question naturally arises whether I am proposing to downsize the staff, send
the FOMC on vacation, and turn the making of monetary policy over to the Board computer.
Let me immediately and emphatically stress that I do not favor mechanical adherence to the
Taylor rule or any other rule. As I discussed earlier, the Taylor rule is no more than a rule of
thumb which works tolerably well in promoting dual objectives under conditions of
uncertainty. In contrast, the Fed is constantly striving to improve its understanding of the
economy's structure, to uncover the source of shocks and to devise policies to accomplish
more precisely our objectives. Thus, 1 am certainly not proposing the mechanical use of the

Taylor rule. Nor would Taylor himself. Could the Taylor rule, or alternative feedback rules,
play a role in actual FOMC decisionmaking? Speaking only for myself, I would argue that
such rules provide a simple but useful benchmark to assess the setting of monetary policy in a
very complex and uncertain economic environment. Used as a kind of handy cross-check for
reasonableness, the rule can warn against any tendency for the Federal Reserve to go too far
in tightening or easing policy, or to overstay a tight or easy stance longer than desirable. But
circumstances could arise which call for substantial deviations from the rule's prescription,
owing to deviations of the equilibrium real funds rate from 2 percent. Consider, for example,
the two instances I mentioned earlier, namely, the 1987 stock market crash and the situation
prevailing in 1992 and 1993, when a credit crunch resulting from diminished bank lending in
response to a capital shortfall was working against economic recovery. Or consider budget
balancing legislation prospectively.
Thus, using the Taylor rule mechanically in practice is impossible. Even the
mechanical implementation of the rule would require judgment. For example, measuring the
current output gap requires an estimate of potential real GDP. And estimating the level of
potential GDP in turn requires measuring the natural rate of unemployment. Similarly,
judging the bias in price indexes, which bears on the appropriate level for the targeted
inflation rate in the Taylor rule, is a real challenge. These are not simple matters. Clearly,
things would be even more complex if we were to use projections of these gaps. Addressing
all these empirical issues involves sifting through new evidence as it surfaces, weighing
arguments and counter-arguments, and altering one's estimates as dictated by the outcome of
this process. This process, which necessarily underlies the design and implementation of

11
monetary policy, is an appropriate task for the central bank.
Given the possibility and desirability of pursuing two objectives simultaneously,
explicit inflation targeting initiatives, like those undertaken by such countries as New Zealand,
Canada, and the United Kingdom, risk being unnecessarily rigid. I recognize that the use of
bands together with a variety of "escape clauses" for supply-shocks, such as hikes in indirect
taxes or energy prices, provides some flexibility. Even so, I think that a quantitative target
solely for inflation could undercut adequate attention to real variables in the short run.

In

comparison with a strategy of pure inflation targeting, flexible rules, which place some weight
on smoothing output, offer all of the benefits of multi-year inflation targets without the most
serious drawbacks. I'm also aware that some of these countries did not have a tradition of
central bank independence or of sufficient concern for an anti-inflationary goal. A move to
an explicit inflation target agreed to between the government and the central bank is one form
of corrective that harnesses governmental support for resisting inflation. In addition, this
approach in principle could enhance the credibility of the anti-inflationary program and could
lower the transitional output loss involved in reaching the inflation objective. However, the
empirical evidence on international experience with sacrifice ratios unfortunately does not
support any "credibility effect" of imposing explicit inflation targets. I therefore remain
skeptical of this argument for explicit inflation targets. A simple, pure inflation targeting
scheme would enable a skeptical public to monitor what its central bank is doing and evaluate
whether it is fulfilling its proclaimed policy. But more complicated approaches work better at
enhancing welfare, even if they are a little more difficult for the public to monitor.
To my way of thinking, a better approach, at least in the U.S. context, is to codify a

longer-term price stability objective, along with one for real performance, in the legislative
mandate for an independent central bank. Then the government's role appropriately becomes
one of oversight to ensure adequate central bank accountability for its policy intentions and
conduct. In the United States, the Federal Reserve's general success in steering the
macroeconomy over the last fifteen years has taken place under the unchanged legislative
mandate of the Federal Reserve Act. That Act directs the Federal Reserve to pursue
"maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates." This language,
inserted in 1977, represents a clear instruction that the Fed should seek price stability as a
goal; arguably, though, the directive to pursue price stability as the primary long-term goal of
monetary policy could be strengthened. The Act's emphasis on maximum employment
provides, in my mind, a mandate for the pursuit of stabilization policy. In practice, the
current legislative mandate has worked well. In this sense, I do not consider the Federal
Reserve Act to be seriously flawed.
Still, there are some clear problems in existing legislation. The quantitative
specifications of governmental objectives for inflation and unemployment rates in the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act passed in 1978 are mutually inconsistent. In addition, that Act
required the Federal Reserve to report its planned growth ranges for money and credit to the
Congress. This provision was based on a belief that these financial aggregates could serve as
an alternative anchor for the price level to replace the gold standard anchor that had been
completely severed in the early 1970s. But the experience of recent years has underscored
the slippage in the relationship between such financial aggregates and inflation, even in the
longer run. The reporting of target ranges for M2, M3 and debt, do not serve well as a

device for communicating either objectives or strategies. From this perspective, reforming
our legislative mandate to provide an improved framework for the Federal Reserve to specify
its strategy to attain legislated goals would be desirable. Independent central banks make
critically important policy decisions, and they should be expected to account for their actions.
Whether the Federal Reserve Act needs to be changed has been discussed in the past
and will continue to be debated in the future. In 1989, Representative Stephen Neal held
widely publicized hearings on a Zero-Inflation Resolution that would have required the
Federal Reserve to attain price stability within five years. The most recent prominent
initiative in this regard is Senator Connie Mack's proposed reform, embodied in his
"Economic Growth and Price Stability Act" introduced in the Senate in 1995. The Senator's
bill would make price stability the Federal Reserve's primary long-run goal, and would
require the Fed to maintain a monetary policy that effectively promotes this goal. The
requirements governing the Fed's semiannual reports to Congress would also be altered. The
Humphrey-Hawkins requirements for reporting money and debt aggregates would be repealed.
And instead, the Fed would be required to establish numerical definitions of the term price
stability, measures to help assess the attainment of this goal, a description of the intermediate
variables used by the FOMC to gauge the prospects for achieving price stability, estimates of
the length of time needed to attain full price stability, and a plan that takes account of shortrun costs in complying with the price stability goal.
An official Federal Reserve position on the Mack bill has not been determined and it
would therefore be inappropriate for me to comment on this bill in detail. But bringing to
bear the various points that I've made so far in this talk, it should be apparent that there are

14

numerous features of the bill that I would support. However, I would have concerns about
any weakening of the Federal Reserve's mandate to conduct output stabilization policy.
In the coming year, issues concerning the Federal Reserve's mandate, goals and strategy are
likely to come to the fore in the public arena. 1 hope my comments have stimulated your
interest in these important issues of monetary policy design. I'm confident that many of your
voices will be heard in the debate; indeed, I look forward to any reactions to my remarks that
you may have today. Thank you for your attention.