View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release 7:00 P.M.
Central Daylight Time
____ May 4. 1966____




Remarks o£ J. L. Robertson
Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System
at the
Annual Dinner of the Bankers Club
of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
May 4, 1966

Toward Balance in Our International Payments

Little more than one year ago the President’s balanceof-payments program, with its emphasis on foreign credit re­
straint, drove home to every banker in the United States the
importance of restoring balance in our international payments.
How to attain and maintain that balance has been the
subject of heated discussion for years. Uncertainty as to
the best long-run solution continues to prevail - in places
like my home town of Broken Bow, Nebraska, as well as in the
nation’s capital.
At first glance, the problem seems to be simple enough.
For many years, we have been paying out more dollars to for­
eigners than we receive from them, and since we cannot go on
doing so, it might seem, offhand, that the obvious thing to
do is to restrict our spending by means of tougher fiscal and
monetary policies, and thus reduce payments to the level of
receipts.
But if the problem were that easy, it would not be a
problem. So, to get into realistic focus, let us examine
more closely, first, what we mean by balance in our interna­
tional accounts; second, what we have been doing so far to
achieve balance; and third, what remains to be done.
What do we mean by payments balance?
In international economics, as in daily life, the
words we use often condition our thinking. Let us take the
term "deficit". When individuals or enterprises complain of
a deficit, they mean that they are operating at a loss, that
they are depleting their substance. And, indeed, quite a
few countries suffer from just such a deficit in their inter­
national accounts. They import more than they export, they
exhaust their reserves, they run deeper and deeper into debt.
Obviously, unless they change their policies they are headed
for serious trouble.
But that is not our situation. Our export earnings
nts for imports, even when we
are much higher than our
include in these paymen
ge expenditures for miliproblem is that the export
tary and economic assi




- 2 -

surplus is not large enough to cover, in addition, our cred­
its to foreigners and our investments abroad. This means
that we are not getting poorer internationally; on the con­
trary, our total claims on foreigners - our assets abroad have been rising much faster than our total liabilities to
the rest of the world. But our international liquid assets principally our gold reserves - have been declining while
our less liquid assets have grown rapidly as the result of
loans and investments abroad. Hence, our problem is better
described as a decline in our international liquidity posi­
tion than as a balance of payments deficit.
Now, from the standpoint of national welfare - or for
that matter, of the welfare of an individual or an enter­
prise - a decline in liquidity may be good, bad, or indif­
ferent. It all depends upon the circumstances.
It is sometimes said that nobody should borrow short
and lend long or, in other words, reduce his liquidity posi­
tion. If this were true, banking would be impossible. No
bank could survive if it invested its demand deposits only
in demand loans. A bank fulfills its economic functions by
converting demand deposits into a variety of loans - of lim­
ited maturity, to be sure, but certainly not all callable on
demand. It always borrows short and lends long in that sense.
This analogy is especially relevant to the United
States, since this country serves in effect as a bank to
the rest of the world. Our currency is used by foreigners both private and official - as international money. A sub­
stantial part of international trade between non-dollar coun­
tries (as, for example, Japanese exports to Latin America) is
invoiced and settled in dollars; and foreign central banks
hold over $13 billion of their official reserves in dollars.
A nation, like a bank or any other enterprise, can
have too much as well as too little liquidity. There is no
inherent virtue in maximizing liquidity, or in maintaining
forever a given liquidity position. And there is no inher­
ent vice in reducing liquidity.
If the United States had decided at the end of the
Second World War to maintain its then existing international




- 3 -

liquidity position, vie would have hoarded the 60 per cent
of the world’s gold we then held and refused to countenance
an increase in our liabilities to foreigners, thus leaving
the rest of the world extremely illiquid. The result would
have been an agonizingly slow recovery in international trade
and in the economic vitality of the free world.
What we did instead was to undertake programs like
the Marshall Plan, which had the dual effect of redistrib­
uting some of our gold holdings and of supplying dollar bal­
ances to the rest of the world. In the pure accounting
sense, these reductions in our gold holdings and increases
in our dollar liabilities constituted a deficit in our bal­
ance of payments. Yet the rest of the world was quite
pleased that we were incurring such deficits. In a true
sense, therefore, our deficits in the early and mid-fifties
were not a sign of payments imbalance; on the contrary, the
corresponding decline in our liquidity was beneficial to all
parties.
Nevertheless, the growing concern over the persist­
ence of the decline in our international liquidity has not
been unwarranted. A decline in the liquidity of a financial
institution becomes hazardous if it goes so far as to gen­
erate - rightly or wrongly - a lack of confidence in the in­
stitution’s ability to meet its obligations. The question
confronting us today is whether, under the conditions exist­
ing here and now, the United States as the world’s banker
can afford much further decline in its international liquid­
ity without risking a diminution of confidence in a payments
system based on the international role of the dollar.
This question, together with the answer to it, has
two important implications. On the one hand, it provides
some guidance to the appropriate size of a deficit in our
payments balance. On the other hand, it explains why the
major trading countries and the International Monetary Fund
are engaged in discussions concerning new facilities for
providing international reserves that would supplement gold
and dollars.
Regarding the appropriate size of a U. S. deficit, I
am increasingly skeptical about attempts to define the goal
of our payments policy in terms of figures, say, in terms of




- 4 -

a maximum permissible deficit or, more correctly, of a maxi­
mum permissible decline in our international net liquidity.
Any figure named may turn out to be too high, or too loto.
Rather, the criterion of our payments policy should be the
willingness of foreigners to add to their holdings of dol­
lars as working balances and reserves. Our international
accounts are in disequilibrium only when our deficit tends
to exceed the total amount by which (1) foreign private mer­
chants, investors, and bankers are willing to increase their
dollar holdings, and (2) foreign central banks wish to accu­
mulate additional dollars to hold as reserves.
Under this criterion, it is clear that our payments
balance was in equilibrium from the end of the Second World
War through 1957, even though our statistics show a substan­
tial payments "deficit" for the period. It is equally clear
that our balance of payments has been in disequilibrium since
1957. Hence, in the short run, our main task in the field
of international financial policy is to correct, and even
overcorrect, the disequilibrium - perhaps by eliminating our
payments deficit completely. We may need to redouble our ef­
forts for the time being - in both the private and the pub­
lic sectors - to curtail the outflow of dollars.
Over the longer run, however, our policy goals will
be somewhat more complex. A modest payments deficit may
well turn out to be consistent with equilibrium. It is to
be expected that private holders of dollars abroad will wish,
as they have in the past, to add to their holdings in line
with the requirements of expanding international trade and
finance. And many official holders - central banks and
treasuries - will continue to find it desirable, convenient,
and profitable to hold part of their growing reserves in the
form of dollar balances.
In both cases, the decisions to hold and add to dol­
lar balances are, needless to say, completely voluntary - at
the discretion of the foreign holder. Hence, it is impos­
sible to predict with any degree of assurance the exact
amounts of dollars which foreigners will wish to accumulate.
It may be that foreign-held dollar balances will not increase
as they have in the past. But it seems fairly clear that the
needed growth of official reserves will exceed the supply of




- 5 -

new gold, even if Soviet gold sales continue to supplement
production and even if private gold hoarding were to recede
from recent peak levels.
For these reasons, among others, the United States
has joined with other countries in the Group of Ten and the
International Monetary Fund, as 1 mentioned before, in seek­
ing a new means of creating international reserves - a means
that would make the world less dependent on limited gold sup­
plies and an unpredictable outflow of dollars from the United
States.
How have we tried to restore payments balance?
Appropriate balance in our international accounts is,
and must be, an important goal of our policy. But obviously
it is not the only goal. Measures designed to restore bal­
ance, like all other measures of our economic policy, must
always be judged on the basis of two fundamental considera­
tions.
First, they need to be compatible with the domestic
goals set by the Employment Act of 1946, which enjoins us
to seek maximum production, maximum employment, and maximum
purchasing power, in an environment of stable prices.
Second, they need to be compatible with the interna­
tional goals inherent in the financial, economic, and politi­
cal position of the United States within the free world, which
impels us to promote continuing progress in international eco­
nomic welfare.
What would have happened if over the past six years
we had followed the advice given in some quarters, abroad as
well as at home, to solve our payments problem by restricting
domestic economic expansion? We would not only have imposed
stagnation and depression on our domestic economy; we would
also have spread stagnation and depression to the rest of the
world. Even if (as seems questionable) such a policy had en­
abled us to restore payments balance faster than the methods
actually employed, too high a price would have been paid and paid by the entire world.




-

6

-

On the other hand, what would have happened if we had
followed still another recommendation for solving the pay­
ments problem - that we abandon the present fixed value of
the dollar in order to gain greater freedom for expansionary
domestic policies?
This is not the place to go into all the ramifications
of whether, by reducing the established par value of the dol­
lar, we could have accelerated our domestic recovery. Even
if this had been possible, such a course would have been ir­
responsible. The dollar serves as an international standard
of value as well as an international means of payment and a
monetary reserve asset. Tampering with its value would have
undermined international commerce by saddling international
transactions with added risks and costs, upset the interna­
tional monetary system, and thereby frustrated the achievement
of maximum international economic welfare.
It is true that in rejecting the advice given on both
sides, we seemed to abandon all "orthodox" efforts to solve
our payments problem. For "orthodox" economists have long
believed - and some still believe - that there are only two
ways of correcting a payments deficit: by restrictive finan­
cial policies or by currency devaluation. In the situation
in which the United States found itself after 1957, neither
of the "orthodox" remedies was applicable. Our domestic sit­
uation clearly demanded the use of expansionary rather than
restrictive policies. And the international role of the dol­
lar clearly forbade any attempt at devaluing the dollar in
terms of foreign currencies. This was the famous "dilemma"
of U. S. policy, and it led to some interesting experiments
in international financial policy.
Let me briefly summarize U. S. actions of recent years:
First, at a time when flows of short-term funds seemed
to be playing an important role in our payments deficit, the
Federal Reserve and the Treasury employed what has been called
"Operation Twist". The purpose was to keep short-term inter­
est rates relatively high, so as to reduce incentives for the
outflow of money-market funds, while permitting long-term
rates to remain relatively low, so as to encourage domestic
investment demand.




- 7 -

Second, the United States made use of changes in the
so-called "mix" of fiscal and monetary policies. While mone­
tary policy became less easy, fiscal policy was eased sub­
stantially. The investment tax credit, enacted in 1962, pro­
vided a stimulus to investment outlays similar in its effects
to a substantial reduction in long-term interest rates, while
avoiding the encouragement to capital outflow that might have
accompanied a sharp reduction in long-term rates. Further­
more, the income tax reduction of 1964 represented a substan­
tial easing of fiscal policy, which helped move the economy
further toward full use of its resources while interest rates,
instead of declining, were permitted to rise further, in the
hope of reducing incentives to capital outflows.
Third, in a more drastic departure from traditional
policy, the United States in 1963 introduced the Interest
Equalization Tax in order to insert a degree of insulation
between the domestic and international capital markets. The
tax initially applied to portfolio investment by Americans in
developed countries, with exceptions for Canada and Japan.
In 1965 the tax was expanded to cover bank loans of one year
or more, but it still excluded direct investments abroad of
U. S. enterprises. The tax made purchases of foreign securi­
ties relatively less attractive to Americans than purchases
of domestic securities, and it did so without raising inter­
est rates in the United States to levels prevailing abroad,
which would have been incompatible with expansion of the
U. S. economy.
And finally, in 1965 the United States introduced the
Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint programs for business cor­
porations and for banks and other financial institutions.
These programs applied to all types of loans and investments,
including direct investments, and thus supplemented the In­
terest Equalization Tax. As in the case of the Interest
Equalization Tax, the VFCR programs encouraged a shift from
foreign to domestic credits and investments. The voluntary
programs recognized important priorities, such as for export
credits and for credits to less developed countries. And by
enlisting the cooperation of business, the danger of avoid­
ance and evasion was minimized.




- 8 -

Incidentally, since the Board has assigned me the
responsibility for administering the voluntary program on
foreign credits of banks and other financial institutions,
let me take a moment to report on its most recent accom­
plishment. In 1965, banks increased their foreign credits
by only $155 million, as contrasted with $2.4 billion in
1964, so that at year-end they were $320 million below the
guideline target. For 1966, the guideline was set so as to
permit the target to rise by 1 percentage point per quarter to reach 109 per cent of the end-of-1964 level by the end of
1966. But in the first three months of this year banks ac­
tually reduced their outstanding foreign loans and invest­
ments by a further $290 million, so that today they are more
than $800 million below the target. This is a remarkable
record of performance.
Turning back to the experimental measures of the
1960*s, some of them have been highly successful. It is
true that our payments position still has not returned to
equilibrium, but on the basis of our conventional calcula­
tion, the "deficit" has been cut in half. And this improve­
ment has taken place in the face of the difficulties caused
by massive conversions of dollars into gold by one of our
European allies, by the recurrent sterling crises, and by
the war in Viet Nam. At the same time, the payments system
has continued to work well enough to permit an unprecedented
expansion of international trade and investment, and - most
importantly - well enough not to impede substantial progress
toward our domestic goals. After five years of uninterrupted
growth, the U. S. economy has returned to nearly full employ­
ment of its manpower and capital.
Without the help of the policies I have outlined, we
could hardly have escaped even more serious payments diffi­
culties, which would have badly interfered with our domestic
progress. In this sense, our international financial poli­
cies have, in my judgment, served well the purposes for which
they were designed.
What remains to be done?
It has been recognized from the beginning that the
kind of selective international financial policies recently




- 9 -

introduced in the United States could only be applied suc­
cessfully under certain limited conditions. Those policies
were never meant to replace general policy measures, but
only to supplement them in times when the general measures
could not be expected to work. Furthermore, these measures
were designed not to eliminate capital outflows from the
United States - which as the richest nation is a natural
source of capital for the rest of the world - but to reduce
such outflows so as to bring them closer into line with the
U. S. surplus of exports over imports.
It must be recognized that selective policies have
inevitable shortcomings. Money is fungible, and any attempt
to force money into, or out of, specific channels is haz­
ardous. For instance, arbitrage will always restrict the
possibilities of a "twist” between short- and long-term in­
terest rates. Fiscal and monetary policies are so closely
interrelated that there are limits to feasible changes in
the "mix". Restrictions on capital outflows by selective
measures can in time be evaded and avoided. Finally, vol­
untary cooperation in restraint programs is difficult to
sustain if the measures impinge too severely upon the prof­
itability of enterprise.
For all these reasons, we must continually review
our policies in order to make sure that we do not use any
tool longer than needed. Just as we should not let dog­
matic orthodoxy prevent us from using selective tools, we
should not let dogmatic selectivism prevent us from return­
ing to more "orthodox" methods when changing conditions make
that advisable.
And conditions have changed radically over the past
twelve months. Not only has our payments deficit declined,
but our domestic situation has turned from under-employment
to nearly full employment, and perhaps beyond sustainable
full employment to a state of emerging inflationary pres­
sures .
These radical changes in underlying conditions have
brought with them the need to review policies. No longer do
we need to keep interest rates low to stimulate domestic




-

10

-

investment; on the contrary, we need to restrain investment,
which is running ahead at an excessive rate. No longer do
we need to accelerate growth in our national income; on the
contrary, we are currently obliged to curb demand so as to
keep it in line with the expansion of available resources.
Under these conditions there is clearly no longer any
reason for fiscal and monetary policies to be employed in op­
posite directions. On all fronts, firmness is the order of
the day, and only the degree, the pace, and the form of firm­
ness can be a matter of differing judgments. If present
trends in money and credit markets continue, we may find
that capital outflows are discouraged quite independently
of the Interest Equalization Tax and of the foreign credit
restraint programs. If and when this happens, and in suffi­
cient magnitude, we should be prepared to dismantle unneeded
selective restrictions.
We should be careful, however, to do so only in favor
of more generalized policies, not in favor of selective re­
strictions in other spheres, and especially not in favor of
restrictions on imports of goods or services. I can conceive
of no circumstances under which restrictions on imports would
be superior to selective restrictions on capital outflows.
If we restricted imports we would invite retaliation and
thereby jeopardize our exports; we would disrupt not only
the efficient international division of labor but also the
optimum allocation of resources in our domestic economy; and
most importantly, we would hamper our fight against the dan­
ger of inflation. Especially when we need to maintain domes­
tic price and cost stability, freedom of imports is an in­
valuable tool for restraining cost and price increases over
the wide range of import-competing industries here at home.
If, at an appropriate moment, we were to give up some
or all selective restrictions on capital outflow, this would
not mean that we should turn our back on them for good. Even
if selective measures were to become inappropriate in the
foreseeable future, they might well become appropriate again
at a later time. The combination of domestic under-employment
and payments deficit is not unusual, and we should expect
similar constellations to appear in the future. It is only
necessary to recognize the possibility that from time to




-

11

-

time, though we hope not continuously, the private capital
flow from this country will tend to be excessive - that is,
the capital outflow will, given the size of the current ac­
count surplus and government outflows, provide more dollars
to foreigners than they are willing to hold.
More generally, we have to face the fact that the
United States needs continuously to have balance of pay­
ments policies, just as it needs to have domestic policies.
Just as equilibrium in the domestic economy does not occur
automatically, the net outcome of private decisions to buy
and sell abroad and to borrow and lend abroad does not auto­
matically result in payments equilibrium.
We can all understand the desirability of having
stand-by measures available for use in the case of necessity.
Among such stand-by measures, there is one to which I invite
your thoughtful attention. I refer to a stand-by authority
to impose a tax (similar to the Interest Equalization Tax)
on international credits and investments. The tax should
be flexible and should cover all forms of capital outflow,
especially to fully developed countries. It should be cap­
able of being raised or lowered or taken off altogether by
executive action, in accordance with balance of payments
needs as reflected in the movement of U. S. reserves and the
willingness of foreigners to hold additional dollars. Once
the deficit in our international accounts has been reduced
to suitable size, we must place our nation in a position to
act speedily and comprehensively if and when restrictions on
capital outflows again become necessary.
It is probable, and certainly to be desired, that such
a tax could, as a rule, be kept on a stand-by basis, to be
used only when capital outflows were clearly excessive, under
conditions that would make inadvisable the use of general re­
strictive fiscal and monetary policies. The experience of
the past few years indicates, in my judgment, that a stand­
by authority such as this is not only desirable, but is
necessary if monetary policy is to continue to serve its
vital function with respect to the domestic economy.