View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release 8:00 p.m.
Eastern Daylight Time
June 16. 1970




Remarks of J. L. Robertson
Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System
before the
Savings Banks Association
of Massachusetts
Hotel Statler Hilton
Boston, Massachusetts
June 16, 1970

Time for Reform
A month ago, in a speech in Phoenix, I tried to
emphasize the need for common effort by government offi­
cials, businessmen, bankers, labor leaders, and consumers,
if we are to win the battle against inflation. I referred
to the need to conform our actions to the public welfare,
and argued that this entails adhering to the spirit as well
as the letter of the law. For examples of what I was talk­
ing about, I could hardly look outside my own field without
being charged with hypocrisy (ample though examples are
elsewhere), so I pointed to some of the ways that commer­
cial banks have endeavored to make end-runs around Federal
Reserve regulations and thereby thwart and delay the effec­
tiveness of our efforts to curtail the amount of money and
bank credit chasing after goods and services, pushing prices
higher and higher.
Well, I soon learned that I had stumbled into a den
of lions. I was accused of being irresponsible, of seek­
ing publicity, and of trying to encourage Congress to enact
restrictive legislation. After the first avalanche of com­
plaints, I recalled that Daniel once entered a similar den
and survived; if he could, perhaps a man from Broken Bow,
Nebraska, could too - even though, in my case, there was
little chance of having the help of an angel. With my
courage thus partially restored, I decided to step forward
again tonight, this time with the explicit purpose of push­
ing a little further some ideas for reform that I launched
several years ago and which are now gaining a few adherents
here and there. Once again, I may be stepping into a den
of lions, but I hope you will hear me out before launching
an attack.
A story told to me by an old friend in Broken Bow,
a history buff, may help persuade you to delay that long,
at least. He said that many years ago a French Count., lead­
ing his troops in battle, was captured and taken to the tent
of the General of the opposing army, where he was interro­
gated. Finally, the General asked for information about
the deployment of his forces. The Count reared back, and
said: "That I will never tell. I am a nobleman. I will
not betray my country." The General was not to be trifled




- 2 -

with, and angrily directed that he be taken to thé block.
The Count was led away and his head placed on the block.
The hatchetman raised his axe high overhead and started
the down-swing. At that precise moment, the Count waved
a hand and cried, ’’Wait! Wait! I'll talk!" But the axe
fell, beheading him. My friend said the moral was obvious:
"Don't hatchet your Counts before they chicken."
You can see that it is with considerable trepida­
tion that I seek your support of two goals for all major
depositary institutions in the 1970's - goals which ul­
timately, directly or indirectly, affect every commercial
bank, mutual savings bank, and savings and loan association
in the nation.
First, all of our 500 or so mutual savings banks and
all of our 5,900 savings and loan associations should be
permitted - at their option - to become broad-scale lenders
and borrowers along the pattern of commercial banks. In
the gradual process of conversion, these institutions would
be expected to take on reserve requirements, tax status,
supervisory safeguards, and other responsibilities similar
to those now applicable to commercial banks.
Second, all federal supervision of bank-type insti­
tutions should be consolidated in one independent agency.
This responsibility is now parcelled out among four sepa­
rate agencies - the Federal Reserve Board, the Comptroller
of the Currency, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
and the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.
Both goals, in my opinion, represent high priority
reforms in the financial area. In lieu of the present
hodgepodge of federal supervision, we need a common and
consistent set of ground rules. These changes toward uni­
formity, I am convinced, are essential steps in bolstering
the ability of our financial system to serve the changing
credit and savings requirements of our expanding economy
in the decades ahead.
The two goals are not novel. In 1966, I suggested
that insofar as federal law is concerned, the powers and




- 3 -

duties of all commercial banks, mutual savings banks, and
savings and loan associations, should be equalized. As
long ago as 1962, I urged that all federal supervision of
banking should be placed in a single banking agency - an
idea, incidentally, that dates back at least five decades.
To speak candidly, in the spirit of Truth in Lend­
ing, I concede that neither proposal received universal
acceptance at the time that it was originally marketed.
Since then, however, consumer resistance has shown signs
of fading. Recognition of the need for change has spread
among both the regulators and the regulated.
Only recently, the President re-emphasized the im­
portance of these two aspects of our financial system by
establishing a new commission whose primary purpose is to
ascertain needed changes in our financial institutions and
their regulatory structure. I submit that among the changes
which are most needed now at the federal level is uniformity
of treatment for all federally insured institutions.
Why Change Is Needed
The logic seems clear why such changes should be the
order of the day, within the context of a dual federal-state
system.
First, uniformity would simplify - and thus enhance
the functioning of - our complex financial system. We need
the strongest possible economy if our nation is to continue
to lead the free world while maintaining maximum scope for
employment, income, and growth at home. One important under­
pinning for such an economy is a smoothly operating system
of depositary institutions. This implies the absence of
unnecessary constraints that can impede the vital process
of gathering savings and allocating credit in open and com­
petitive markets.
Unfortunately, such constraints are all too possible
now at the federal level. There are differing statutes and
regulations affecting different types of banks. There are




-

4

-

also differing controls affecting different types of
institutions, such as commercial banks, savings banks,
and S & Ls. We have, in practice, a jumble of aà hoc
arrangements that makes for incompatibility, controversy,
inefficiency, and competitive inequality. To correct the
situation and provide a uniform basis for serving the
public, these institutions should all be allowed by fed­
eral law to engage in a wide range of activities - includ­
ing, of course, the acceptance of demand deposits as well
as time and savings deposits.
Uniformity in the structure and regulation of these
institutions at the federal level would, as I see it, place
all competition for the public's business squarely where
it belongs - on as close to the same footing as possible.
It would allow them to devote all their time to serving
the public with utmost efficiency. Today, in contrast,
too much time is spent in efforts to protect special in­
terests or encroach on preserves traditionally reserved
for others.
Given a common set of ground rules, I am confident
that all these institutions would have greater opportunity
than ever to innovate. Without the constraints that now
prevail on the rates or the types of instruments that can
be offered to attract additional savings, they could - for
example - compete more flexibly with the securities market
for consumer and business savings. In finding ways to do
so, they could penetrate the market for savings more broadly
and effectively than has been possible so far.
The need for innovation in our financial markets
seems certain to intensify during the 1970's. New forms
of credit demands will inevitably arise with increasing
emphasis on environmental improvements, more efficient
international markets, better neighborhoods, and many
other facets of our economic and social well-being. The
sheer amount of financing that will be required to accom­
modate our expanding economy will be enormous. Based even
on a conservative projection, our economy appears likely
to expand over the next ten years by as much in physical
terms as it did in the past twenty.




- 5 -

Uniformity in the structure and regulation of banktype institutions at the federal level would bring other bene­
fits, too. It would strengthen the hand of the public in
formulating and implementing stabilization policies that
would be more uniformly applicable. Problems of controlling
the expansion of credit, for instance, would be simplified if
all depositary lenders, with expanded authority to accept de­
posits and to serve the public's credit needs, were also sub­
ject to similar reserve requirements. More direct influence
over the assets and liabilities held by the financial system
would accordingly be possible for the monetary authorities.
More equitable treatment of all depositary institutions could
be achieved.
At the same time, uniform powers and duties would allow
any of these lenders to serve particular sectors of the credit
markets. Benefits of scale in operations as well as other
economies of specialization could continue to be realized by
institutions that chose to focus on particular types of lo­
cal, regional, or national credit demands. But such special­
ization would not be required. Nor would it be necessary for
an institution to continue to specialize in a particular sec­
tor if other credit demands became more pressing.
Another advantage of this approach, as I see it, is
that it would lay the groundwork for more direct thrust of
public policy on sectors of the credit markets deemed to be
of the most urgent social priority. Suppose housing, to take
a very realistic example, was placed high on the priority
list. In that case, incentives of an across-the-board na­
ture could be devised in order to encourage all major types
of depositary institutions to direct more of their resources
into that special area. This would allow maximum response by
all of them to the opportunities for both profit and service.
Today, in contrast, our markets are all too fragmented
in terms of varying - and sometimes even conflicting - spe­
cial interests, benefits, and support programs applicable to
particular types of financial institutions. This makes for
difficulty - if not downright confusion - in developing and
administering appropriate overall public policy. It also
makes for obscurity in measuring the net benefits that may
result.




- 6 A direct frontal approach to these problems would
tend to unify rather than fragment the savings and credit
markets. Uniformity in powers and duties - including
equality with respect to special incentives for invest­
ment in high-priority sectors - could virtually eliminate
the burden on the government of supporting and protecting
specialized institutions established solely to serve par­
ticular areas of the credit markets. It would help bring
to light social benefits that might flow from incentives
made available across the board.
Finally, I foresee that uniformity would at long
last assure equity in the federal government's treatment
of all such institutions. That would reduce incentives
for unseemly competitive struggles among the federal regu­
lators. All too often such internecine warfare leads to
competitive laxity in chartering, regulating and super­
vising such institutions. It also makes for wasteful
duplication and for time-consuming - and, all too often,
fruitless - efforts to harmonize conflicting views of
federal supervisors. Divided authority in this field,
I am convinced, is more than an anachronism. It is a
burdensome albatross for any financial system where com­
petition should be based on serving the public rather
than on serving oneself.
Incidentally, I see no insurmountable theoretical
or supervisory barriers to rule out commercial bank op­
erations conducted by mutual institutions. Some special
safeguards might have to be devised in order to compensate
for the absence of a cushion of protection that is ordi­
narily furnished by capital stock, but there is no reason
why this could not be done by suitable reserve require­
ments and liquidity ratios.
Changes under Way
The logic underlying the need for the changes which
I have proposed, and their inevitability, has recently been
reinforced by the sweep of events in the market place. Let
me cite examples.




- 7 -

First, commercial banks in several ways have be­
come more like S & Ls and savings banks during recent
years. They have been competing vigorously in savings
and mortgage-loan markets formerly dominated by the
thrift institutions. From 1965 through 1969, in fact,
commercial banks experienced a larger growth in the dol­
lar volume of their consumer-type savings liabilities
than all S & Ls and all mutual savings banks combined.
They also stepped up their propensity to invest this
type of savings inflow in mortgages.
Second, savings banks and S & Ls, partly as a
defensive reaction, have become more like commercial
banks in the ways they compete for savings. Only quite
recently, federal savings and loan associations were au­
thorized for the first time to accept savings "deposits"
as well as savings "shares". Today, S & Ls can offer
virtually the same line of savings instruments as the
banks, including, to some extent, certificates in de­
nominations of $100,000 and over.
Third, some savings banks and S & Ls are beginning
to provide the convenience of one-stop service for their
customers. Several states have authorized mutual savings
banks to offer checking accounts. Also, Congress recently
authorized the Federal Home Loan Bank Board to permit
S & Ls to offer bill-paying services for their savers.
Fourth, savings banks and S & Ls have become more
like commercial banks in the kinds of loans and invest­
ments they are authorized to make. A tally of legislative
changes affecting the savings bank industry during the past
year alone filled four pages of a recent issue of the Sav­
ings Bank Journal. In an effort to capitalize on these
and other developments, a number of savings and loan asso­
ciations have recently merged with savings banks or com­
mercial banks.
Despite the changes that have drawn all types of
depositary institutions closer to the same mold, demands
have continued for special privileges and protection for
some groups. Such demands have been reflected in the




- 8 -

higher interest rate ceilings that still prevail for
consumer-type deposits at savings and loan associations
and at savings banks compared to those at commercial
banks. Of course, if we achieve both of the goals I
have outlined, and all three types of institutions be­
gin to compete on an equal basis in virtually the same
market for consumer savings, it is possible that Regula­
tion Q ceilings would no longer be necessary. On grounds
of equity, the current interest rate ceilings are objec­
tionable because they discriminate against small savers.
Moreover, while the ceilings limit the price that de­
positary institutions can pay for savings, those insti­
tutions are free to relend the funds at whatever price the
market will bear.
As a practical matter, experience with interest
rate ceilings over the past four years has demonstrated
the limited usefulness of this stop-gap arrangement - even
though that arrangement was indispensable in the circum­
stances prevailing during those years. While the ceil­
ings have protected thrift institutions against the inroads
of inter-group competition, they have not shown any marked
success in channeling savings flows to depositary lenders
against the pull of forces operating in securities markets
where price competition remains strong. Over the three
year period ending in 1968, for example, households placed
an annual average of $22 billion more in savings accounts
at banks and savings and loan associations than they in­
vested directly in the stock and bond market. During 1969,
in contrast, exactly the opposite pattern emerged. In that
year, households put $6 billion more into stocks and bonds
than they did into savings accounts.
Against the background of recent developments, pres­
sures have continued both for still broader lending and
investment powers of savings and loan associations and sav­
ings banks and for more protective measures. Additional
states, as you know, are being asked to authorize unlimited
checking accounts in mutual savings banks. Two recent
studies of the S & L industry - as well as one by a blueribbon industry advisory committee - have recommended
limited checking account privileges for savings and loan
associations.




- 9 -

These and other pressures, in my opinion, merely
emphasize that the time is ripe for reform of our fed­
eral laws and policies so as to permit savings banks and
S & Ls to find their own way in the financial world un­
hampered by arbitrary constraints. Now is the time to
authorize these institutions to begin to evolve gradually
toward the widest possible flexibility in borrowing, lend­
ing, and investment powers that is consistent with their
broadened responsibilities - that is to say, permit them
to perform like commercial banks, even though they con­
tinue to be mutual institutions.
Failure to allow our thrift institutions to become
integral and uniform parts of our general financial system
is bound to perpetuate the risk of inefficiencies, or
worse, that come from overspecialization in some areas
and underspecialization in others. That course of ac­
tion - or inaction - is certain to reinforce demands to
meet newly-emerging credit needs by creating new institu­
tions, with additional special powers, calling for further
protective measures to insulate them from the mainstream
of competition. It is sure to continue the tradition of
shoddy patchwork rather than raise the prospect of last­
ing improvement.
I have detailed on other occasions some of the
conflicts that seem inherent in this unfortunate situa­
tion. I have also pointed out the uncertainties that
such a division of authority at the federal level can
create by resulting in different sets of ground rules,
under which different classes of financial institutions
strive to serve more or less the same public. I have in­
dicated how unification of federal bank supervisory agen­
cies could and should be achieved under a new agency of
government.
As you know, I have called for a Federal Banking
Commission to be headed by five Commissioners, to be ap­
pointed by the President, with the advice and consent of
the Senate. The Commission would have transferred to it
all supervisory powers now exercised by the Federal Re­
serve Board and the Comptroller of the Currency, and all




- 10 -

powers and functions now vested in the Federal Deposit In­
surance Corporation. For the reasons I have suggested to­
day, I believe the idea of the Federal Banking Commission
should be expanded in the '70s to include the supervisory
powers now exercised by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.
A Gradual Transition
In looking to the future of our financial system,
it is often fruitful to recall the experience of earlier
times. The English clergyman and historian, Thomas Fuller,
wrote this in his Worthies of England, some two centuries
ago: "Let him who would be happy for a day, go to the
barber; for a week, marry a wife; for a month, buy him a
horse; for a year, build him a new house; for all his life­
time, be an honest man."
Following this advice, I should hasten to say, in
all honesty, that I do not necessarily subscribe to all
of the Reverend Fuller's recommendations. Nor does the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System neces­
sarily endorse the proposals that I have outlined; they
are offered here solely on my own initiative.
The effort to live up to Fuller's recipe for life­
time happiness, however, compels me to point out that the
reforms that I have proposed would obviously entail farreaching alterations of our present system of depositary
institutions. They could ultimately affect 6,400 savings
and loan associations and savings banks with 5,000 branches
and assets of some $240 billion. Measured in these terms,
S & Ls and savings banks together are now two-fifths as
numerous as commercial banks. They have a fourth as many
branches. Their assets amount to nearly half of the com­
mercial bank total.
Uniformity in the structure and supervision of all
these institutions as lenders, borrowers, and investors
would require extensive legislation by the Congress. It
would mean a drastic reorganization of federal supervisory
agencies in order to consolidate all responsibility where
I believe it rightly should be - in one independent agency.







- 11 -

Although certainly not insuperable, these tasks are
indeed formidable. And anyone who has been observing
Washington from the inside as long as I have knows that
changes of this magnitude in our financial structure and
its supervision will be a slow evolutionary process.
That is exactly the reason why that process should be­
gin now.
The present time is none too early to move di­
rectly toward these goals. Both of them, as I see it,
are desirable today. Both of them appear inevitable to­
morrow, for only by encouraging initiative and competi­
tion, in a climate of equal opportunities and obligations,
can we assure the maximum contribution of our private
financial system to the nation's economic growth and
well being.