View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Statement on "Window Dressing” in
Banks' Reports of Condition
by
J. L. Robertson, Member of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Legal and Monetary Affairs Subcommittee of the Committee
on Government Operations of the House of Representatives

October 2, 1963
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:
“Window dressing" is a convenient and colorful ex­
pression and undoubtedly will continue to be used to de­
scribe the problem that concerns this Committee, but we
should be aware that it is a misnomer.

A merchant dresses

his show window to display attractively the merchandise
that is for sale in the store.

If the window contains

Paris gowns and only inferior copies are for sale inside,
in time the merchant would lose the public's confidence
and its patronage.
What is called "window dressing" in the case of banks'
reports of their condition is also deceptive, I am afraid.
However, it is less easily detected than the merchant's
pretense, and some banks seem to be satisfied that the
practice will attract more business and that the decep­
tion will be noted by only a few.

But although its ill

effects on banks may be less direct than on merchants,




- 2 -

eventually it could cause erosion of the banking communi­
ty's most valuable asset - public esteem and trust.
Window dressing by banks has two aspects.

It involves,

first, deceptive transactions that have no genuine business
purpose, and, second, a deceptive balance sheet resulting
from those transactions.

The main purpose of window dress­

ing is to display to the public a "report of condition'*
(in other words, a balance sheet) that presents the bank
more favorably than its normal condition warrants.
For those who are interested in the devices employed
in window dressing, there is being submitted, for inclusion
in the Hearing record, an outline of procedures that have
been used.

The actual results, however, can be described

very briefly.

Occasionally a bank uses window dressing to

hide the fact that it is in debt, but usually the bank's
purpose is simply to look bigger than it is.

By various

arrangements, a bank with "real" deposits of $900 million,
for example, can plausibly inform the world that its de­
posits are more than a billion dollars, and that conse­
quently it is the largest bank in the city or State.

Natu­

rally, this distresses its rival with bona fide deposits
of $950 million, so the next time it understandably is




tempted to window dress, "just to present the true rela­
tive picture!»

This is why window dressing tends to spread;

in fact, it is surprising to me how many bankers have
earned our praise by refusing to climb on the merry-goround .
The impression apparently has been created, in some
quarters, that window dressing relates only to reports of
condition that banks publish pursuant to requirements of
law - the so-called “call reports".

If that were true,

the problem of minimizing or eliminating window dressing
would be relatively simple.

But the facts are otherwise,

and much harm has been done by intimating that bank super­
visors could end the practice simply by suitable call re­
port procedures.
This point is cnicial, and I want to explain it as
clearly as I can.

As long as a bank skirts the criminal

false-entry laws, it is free to publish a balance sheet a "report of condition" - whenever it wishes, as of any
date it selectsj and in whatever form and size suit its
purpose.

Most banks are required by law to publish their

balance sheets several times a year in a form and as of a
date specified by their governmental supervisors.




But

- 4 -

these required publications may be compressed into a few
square inches in an obscure corner of a newspaper of.small
circulation, while the bank's ’voluntary” .advertisements
may be - and often are - large and striking displays, as of
dates selected by the bank itself, published in journals
with immense circulation among the class of readers the
bank is most anxious to reach.

Does this begin to suggest

the fallacy of the contention, recently advanced, that the
window-dressing problem can be readily solved by issuing
all calls on a "surprise” basis?
Perhaps 1 should make clear that a "call” is issued
by a bank supervisor to all banks under its supervision,
for a report as of a-prior date.

F^r example, the Comp­

troller of the Currency may inform every national bank, on
March 5, that it must promptly submit, to him, and publish
in a local newspaper., a report of its condition - a balance
sheet in prescribed form, as I said before - as of March
3.

That date having already passed, the bank cannot retro­

actively juggle its accounts or engage in specious transac­
tions to hide any weaknesses in its actual condition.

Un­

less the bank was able to anticipate the date of the call,
this produces an accurate report of its normal condition.




- 5 Real understanding of the situation requires knowledge
of the origin, the history, and the functions of call re­
ports.

The

practice of requiring banks to submit reports

of their condition to governmental supervisors, and to pub­
lish such reports for public.scrutiny, began over a century
ago.

It began against a background of so-called :,wildcat"

banking of a kind that is difficulc for us to envision to­
day.

B^th internal and external controls were scanty; bank­

ing standards were high in some areas but extremely low in
others.

A bank's condition might vary greatly from month

to month, and bank insolvencies were frequent as a result
of over-extensions of credit, other unsound policies, and
’’runs".
In these circumstances, unexpected calls for reports
of condition served two principal purposes.

The supervisor

received información that enabled him to decide whether any
dangerous trends were developing; if there were, he might
dispatch an examiner to make a special examination of the
bank or to discuss the facts of life with its board of di­
rectors .
Equally important was the information available to
che banking public in the report of condition published in




the local newspapers.
be remembered.

In this connection, two facts must

Fifty or a hundred years ago commercial

banks' customers were almost exclusively people of sub­
stance, to use a phrase of the time.

Wage earners and

white-collar workers-fc&rely had accounts.

Typical cus­

tomers were manufacturers, well-to-do farmers, and whole­
sale and retail merchants.

This was long before the days

when 49 of every SO bank depositors were completely covered
by deposit insurance.

In that era, the. majority of bank

customers could and probably did read reports of condi­
tion, to decide whether the bank

looked safe" or whether

it might be advisable to shift to a stronger institution.
It is important to bear in mind also that, in those days,
the bank statements so published in accordance with law
were practically the only •'statements that were published
at all.
In our lifetime’the significance of .required reports
of condition lias changed greatly..

Today, I venture to as­

sert, only a tiny fraction of bank customers pause to read
items headed 'Report of Condition of XYZ State Bank...Pub­
lished in Accordance with Call Made by /appropriate authori­
ties/ ; instead, they relax calmly in the shelter of Federal




- 7 deposit insurance.

Those who are interested in the condi­

tion of a bank - such a3 the treasurers of corporations
with millions on deposit - are seldom misled by window dress­
ing.

They know it exists and make necessary allowances,

checking against the ^’surprise'-' reports, and often they can
directly ask banks for the information they want.
For bank supervisors also, call reports are less im­
portant today as instruments of supervision,

Jith extremely

rare exceptions, the general condition of a bank does not
alter substantially from month to month.

Furthermore,

supervisors have developed better alternative sources of in­
formation.

During my thirty years of bank supervision, I

do not recall a single instance in which a dangerous trend,
calling for corrective action, first came co our attention
through a call report.

But reports of condition today serve one important
purpose that hardly existed in 1900.

In economic analysis

and planning, and particularly in the formulation of mone­
tary policy, reliable bank statistics are a principal tool.
Reports of.condition, I venture to say, are the number one
source of these statistics for the American banking industry.




- 8 -

Fot statistical information of this kind, standardiza­
tion of reporting dates is of great value.
asset and liability categories, seasonal

In many bank
even intra-

weekly - variations are astonishingly large.

If reports

were called for as of December 26 in one year, Decemb.er 5
in the second, and December 15 in the third, even our
skilled statisticians would not bé able to measure, with
reasonable accuracy, movements in such basic items as de­
posits, business loans, and many others.

Moreover, since

most noiibank statistics to which banking data must be re­
lated are end-of-mohth figures, variable bank -reporting
dates detract considerably from the suitability of banking
data for analyses of this character.

Even the accuracy of

the actual data reported would be better under fixed date
reporting than under surprise calls.

Bankers have repeat­

edly informed us that it is most difficult to reconstruct
an accurate report of condition retroactively for items not
regularly covered in cheir daily trial balances.

Because

of these difficulties, many banks resort to estimating pro­
cedures that are often subject to a troublesome margin of
error.

With fixed-date reporting at the mid-year and year-

end, banks could arrange in advance for an accurate tally
for each reported item as of the reporting date.




Against this background, I return to the fallacy that
might be called the "surprise call panacea".

Plainly stated,

this is the argument that all the benefits of call reports
would be retained and perhaps even enhanced and the evils *
particularly window dressing ~ would disappear, if all calls
were made on a "surprise" basis,

vj’hat I have already said

suggests some of the weaknesses of that argument.

However,

to evaluate it effectively, understanding of the actual call
report situation is essential.
Under section 7 of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act,
almost all banks in the United States are required to make
four reports of condition annually £o their Federal super­
visors.
banks.

The date of such balance sheets is the same for all
In actual practice, the regular custom has been to

call for two of these reports, each year, on unexpected
dates, usually in the spring and fall.

The remaining two

ordinarily are called for on or about June 30 and December
31 of each year.

The latter are the principal source of

the financial statistical series that I have mentioned.
rfe see, then, that ordinarily there are two "surprise"
calls every year.

To the extent that publication of re*

ports of condition called for unexpectedly are of benefit




- 10 -

to the public, such benefit is derived from chese calls.
(However, in the opinion of at least one Federal super­
visor, it appears, publication of those surprise call re­
ports is of little benefit to che public.

The Comptroller

of the Currency has authorized national banks to omit currenc publication of those reports,, requiring publication
only, as an adjunct co the reports thac are customarily called
for as of June 30 and December Jl.)
The *'surprise call fallacy11 amounts to a contention
that all benefits of call reports would be retained and all
detriments eliminated if June 30 and December 31 were avoided
as dates for the remaining two calls.
this is far from the case.

Actually, however,

As I mentioned, a "call’1 as

of December 13 would not prevent banks from window dressing,
if they cared to, in preparation for a widely publicised
year-en.d voluntary statement.

In other words, even if the

supervisors called for a report as of December 13, and in
that report - because of its unexpected date - there was
little or no window dressing, the report that actually comes
to the public's attention^ and which is the basis of the
semi-official si¿e rating of the bank, would be a voluntary
year-end statement, which would contain just as much or as




- 11 -

little wirido.j dressing as the bank might wish.

From that

viewpoint, the only zesult of the December 13 call would be
to impose upon all banks (including the vast majority that
do not indulge in window dressing) the work and expense in­
volved in the preparation and publication of two year-end
statements instead of one.
Occasional issuance of an end-of-year call as of a
date other than the last business day of December has at least
one advantage - it helps to reveal to supervisors and other
interested persons the extent of window dressing.
demonstrated in 1952.

This was

Reports of condition were called for

as of Friday, L-cember 2o, which, for most banks, was just
one business day before the end of the year.

It can be as­

sumed chat since banks are accustomed to December 31 calls,
the December 23 figures were noc appreciably inflated by
window dressing.

Most banks (particularly large banks)

published noc only their call reports as of December 23,
1952, as required by law, but also voluntary reports as of
December 31 - the latter in more eye-catching form.
Comparison of the figures of these two statements just one business cay aparc - was instructive.

The hundred

largest banks in the country (according to a compilation
published in che American Banker) furnish a striking example,




- 12 -

although similar conditions exist in smaller banks as well.
Those hundred banks showed total deposits of $121 billion
on December 28, and by che end of December 31 this had in­
creased to almost $129 billion - a.difference of more than
3 per cent.

Among the hundred, nine banks showed deposit in­

creases, in one business day, of more than 10 per cent.

In­

dividual figures ranged up to a high of 34 per cent expan­
sion.

It is obvious chat most of these increases were due

to window dressing.

Consequently, last year's experience

provided a good picture of the magnitude of the problem.
Although window dressing sometimes has been attacked
for the wrong reasons, the undesirability of the practice
must not be underestimated.

It is not a negligible problem.

The aggregate volume of window dressing, I suspect, does
not vary so greatly, from year to year, as to distort seri­
ously the bank statistics ye need, but I have no doubt that,
although allowance may be made for window dressing, the
figures on which we depend would be more realistic and re­
liable if window dressing could be done away with.

In addi­

tion, there is inequity in a system that enables a bank to
pretend to the public that it is the largest in the com­
munity or State, when in fact it is not.




Personally, I

- 1J do not: believe banks gain or lose much by this "numbers
game", but some banks take it very seriously indeed, and
that is why window dressing sometimes threatens to get out
of hand as banks try to out-maneuver each other.

One is

reminded of vihat the Ped Queen said in Through the Looking
GI p ^s :

".. ,h?.re, you see, it takes all the running you can

do, to keep in the same place.

If you want to get some­

where else, you must run at least twice as fast as that!"
Window dressing, then, is an undesirable practice * an
untruthful, unfair, wasteful, and misleading device.

There

is little doubt as to how a good banker would react to a
borrower's statement that was inflated to show a more liquid
position or a larger volume of business than in fact existed.
To the degree these efforts succeed, they result in deceiv­
ing the public.

And, to the degree they are recognized and

discounted, they result in raising doubts as to the reli­
ability of bank statements and of bankers' statements.
All bank supervisors, and most banks as well, would
like t) see the last of window dressing.

But the "all-

surprise-cair* approach clearly is not the answer.

As I

have said, it would impose additional burdens on banks,
would not materially improve public understanding, and




-

lA

-

might weaken essential statistics rather than improve them.
(In fact., an ^11-surprise program actually would eliminate
the only existing penalty for window dressing.

At present,

a bank chat window dresses its ycar-end report pays a larger
deposit insurance premium, and this deterrent to window
dressing, for uhatevsr it is worth, would be lost if the
reouired reports, on which the insurance assessment is
based, were called for as of December lu, let us say, rather
than December ¿1.)
As the Committee may know, a number of efforts actu­
ally have been made to diminish window dressing.

Perhaps

the most effective has been moral suasion - efforts to con­
vince bankers that the practice is morally unworthy, that
it could be injurious to the prestige of the banking in­
dustry - that is, to public confidencc in the ethics of
banks - and that the game simply is not worth the candle,
in the long rup.
In my judgment, moral suasion is not only the most
promising avenue toward the elimination of window dressing,
but also the most desirable.

Because of the complicating

factors I have described, I am inclined to believe that
the problem could not be solved by governmental fiat with­
out an excessive degree of regulation and control.




- 15 *

Actual experience indicates that bankers are prepared
to stop this practice "if che other Cellow will".

Many are

convinced chat competing in window dressing is an unprofit­
able tug of war, but each participant hesitates to let go
for fear that his opponent will carry off the pri-ie.

I be­

lieve ¿hat if the bank supervisory authorities, acting
vigorously and simultaneously, would request banks through­
out the councry co quit window dressing, the likelihood of suc­
cess would be excellent.

But I emphasize that such an ef­

fort would certainly fail unless it was based on complete
cooperacion and coordination, most careful preparation, and
determined face-to-facc discussion with the bankers in every
cicy where the practice prevails.

And after initial success,

the supervisors would have to remain alert, to chop off any
new sproutings of this unhealthy growth.
A supplementary line of approach would be to require
call reports to include daily-average figures for important
items.

This might also be helpful from the statistical

viewpoint, although it would add to the reporting burdens
of banks - including the majority which do not window dress and it would noc, by icself, prevent window dressing in
the year-end balance sheet, and that is where it id prin­
cipally used.




I should like to summarise my ideas on this subject.
Uindou dressing is an undesirable practice.

Every reason­

able effort should be made to eliminace ic.

Galling for

all reports of condition on surprise dates is not a satis­
factory answer.

I believe that bank supervisors are in a

position to develop a program, oased on moral suasion,
that will enable American banking to rid icself of this
detrimental practice.

If that is the answer, or if some

other effective answer is found, it will be transmuted
from a hope to a reality only through painstaking study of
this complex question, with full and frank incerchange of
ideas and criticisms leading to cooperative action, among
bank supervisory agencies and the industry itself.

I hope

that these conditions will prevail, so that efforts to
solve this problem, and the many other problems chat con­
front bank supervisors, can take place under conditions
that offer the greatest likelihood of success.







Devices limnlcvcc to "V.'indcw Dross11 Bank, Condition Statement«
Called for bv Supervisory Authorities

Round-robin exchange of interbank deposits among three or more banks
which increases both deposits and cask-equivalent assets to m:.ke the
bank appear larger and more liquid than it normally would. At least
three banks must participate, since reciprocal deposits between two
banks are required to be reported ''net" in official condition
report?.
Short-term reductions in borrowings, which member banks may offset
by larger borrowings on other days of the reserve-comrutation
period to maintain the required level of average reserves. This
docs not inflate the report's figures, but it does show a debt-free
condition in published stateirents of the borrowing bank, although
the pay-off of the borrowing may be in the call on the statement
date and the loan account of the lending bank may not be reduced.
Arrangements with large depositors to increase their deposits
temporarily by ¿rawing drafts against their accounts at other banks.
These drafts are credited to the customer's account immediately but
are in the process of collection on the statement date and arc not
charged‘against the "account'at the other bank* until after the state­
ment date. This transaction may be reversed immediately after the
statement date, so that there is no change in the allocation of the
depositors' balances in the long run.
Very short-term loans to cooperating customers the proceeds of
which are credited to the customers' accounts on the statement
date and repaid immediately afterward. Similar results may be
obtained by purchase of bank acceptances or opon-market paper from
brokers or nonbank dealers or by shifting of loan participations
among banks. Payment is credited to the seller's account and the
drafts usod in payment are in transit on the statement date so
that both loan and deposit totals arc inflated.
Delayed processing of items presented for collection, or of inter­
office clearings in a branch system. This is a simple and
practically uadetectible way of inflating total deposits and liquid
assets and can be accomplished by holding back only a relatively
few large checks without disturbing normal processing arrangements
and witiiout resorting to collusion with other banks or with
cus tomcrs.

-2Inflation of Flpuros in "V.)luntftr■" ite^li.shud S'..toi..cnts i»y
Methods chat are not Permitted in Official Condition Reports
1.

Voluntary statements may include reciprocal interbank balances vlsich
arc required to be reported "net" in official reports of coruliticn.

2.

Voluntary statements may incorporate the assets and liabilities of
foreign branches, which must be excluded from official condition
reports.

3. Loan and investment totals and capital accounts may include bad debt
reserves and other valuation reserves. They are required to be
excluded from totals in the official condition reports of most banks.