View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

B O A R D OF G O V E R N O R S
OF THE

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E SYSTEM
WASHINGTON
JAMES LOUIS R O B E R T S O N
MEMBER

ar

THE

OOARO

December 9, 1965
Dear Mr. Pattnan:
In response to your request that members of
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
appear before your Committee on Monday, December 13,
I regret to advise you that because of an out-of-town
engagement related to the President's Balance of Payments Program, I will be unable to appear on that date.
However, in order to assist as fully as possible in the achievement of your objective of disclosing the factors that entered Into the Federal Reserve's
recent decision to raise the discount rate and the ceilings on interest rates payable on time deposits, X am
enclosing copies of two statements which set forth my
own reasons for opposing both actions. The one relating to the discount rate increase was presented to the
Board at the time that action was taken. The one opposing higher maximum interest rates was written subsequent
to the meeting and submitted for the Board*s record.
These statements include the main points that X would
make orally if it were possible for me to be present
Monday.
In the event you wish to make these statements
available to members of your Committee, its staff, and
other interested people, I am submitting additional
copies herewith.
Sincerely,

Enclosures '
The Honorable Wright Patman
Chairman, Joint Economic C
Congress of the United States
Washington, D. C.

• ' ^

Statement of Governor Robertson's Reasons for Opposing an Increase In the Discount Rate, December 3, 1965
Changes in monetary policy should not be triggered
by fear of prosperity.

A prosperous and growing economy

has been the goal of public policies, and substantial achievement in that direction in the 1960Ys should be a cause of
<

gratification rather than concern.

It is not inevitable

that inflation, boom, and bust must follow from the kind of
prosperous performance the United States economy has been
giving, and consequently there are no valid grounds for arguing that tightening now is needed to forestall inflationary
developments that are sure to come later.
This is not to deny the need for very careful scrutiny of the progress of economic events and a willingness
to act to further restrain credit if and as excessive demand
pressures actually emerge.

I conceive of the present as a

time of delicate balance in the economy.

Supply and demand

forces seem so tentatively poised that abrupt action to
change monetary conditions could tip the scales significantly - towards inflation if policy was actively eased, or
on the other hand, towards recession if credit availability
were sharply tightened.
Financial markets have only recently calmed somewhat
after being buffeted by rumors of an impending discount rate

-

change.

2

-

Such a rate increase now would come as a distinct

surprise, with reactions aggravated by the impending seasonal
peak of money market pressures.

Such action would insure

undoubtedly that the heavy volume of Treasury cash borrowing to be done in January would have to be undertaken at
substantially higher interest costs to the government.
If, for whatever reasons, a tightening action is to be
initiated, it would be far preferable to use a subtle rather
than a slam-bang method. An appropriately mild and indirect
line of action might be to (1) dampen bank issuance of promis
sory notes by defining them as deposits; (2) hold Regulation
Q ceilings on time deposit interest rates at existing levels
for the time being; and (3) take no action on the discount
rate, expecting that banks would undoubtedly have to cover
some portion of their net December loss of CD*s by substan> I

tial temporary resort to the discount window. This combination of steps should serve to moderate somewhat the rate of
advance in bank credit, while not triggering immediate expectations of higher interest rates in thq market and yet,
at the same time, placing banks in a position of dependence
on the discount window that could lead fairly naturally to
a more overt tightening of monetary policy should inflationary developments begin to appear.

-

3

-

Whether or not a breakout of inflationary pressures
will in fact occur cannot now be predicted.

Accordingly,

the best practical course is to adopt a policy of "watchful
waiting", meanwhile continuing to supply a reasonable flow
of reserves to finance much-needed economic growth.

Despite

large and sustained expansion since the last recession in
1961, a small but significant margin of human and real capital resources remains unutilized in this country.

Further

orderly expansion in aggregate demand can effectively employ
some of these resources.

The accompanying growth in credit

and money during this period has been orderly, and has contributed to overall economic growth.

Continued orderly credit

expansion is needed if our economy is to move on up to the
goal of sustainable full employment of available resources.
The price pressures to date from this economic growth
have been small and selective, stemming mostly from worldwide shortages of particular nonferrous metals, temporary
scarcities of certain agricultural products, and market•»

testing mark-ups in a few administered-price industries.
These are not the types of price increases appropriately
dealt with by a dampening of aggregate domestic demand.
The temporary nature of some of the recent increases is

-

4

-

Indicated by the fact that the rate of rise in the wholesale price index has already slowed since mid-year from an
annual rate of 2 per cent to 1 per cent. Meanwhile, recent
successful Administration actions against aluminum and copper prices reduce the likelihood of other administered-price
increases.
The U. S. balance of payments performance does not
now supply reasonable grounds for further monetary tightening. The chief burden for further improvement in the balance
falls on other policies.

The allegedly interest-sensitive

components are already performing very well under the discipline of the Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint program.

I

see no sign that this program is weakening in so far as its
influence on financial institutions is concerned.

Corporate

direct investment abroad, the category of capital flow that
has been least reduced to date, is notoriously insensitive
to changing general credit conditions in the United States.
U. S. interest rates are already high by historical
standards, and I believe they are generating all the credit
restraint that ought to be attempted in the current delicate situation.

The federal fiscal position will be shift-

ing to a somewhat less stimulative policy for a time after

the turn of the year, and we should be wary of imposing a
coincident restraining influence from additional monetary
tightening at this juncture. The appropriate monetary
policy for later in 1966 can be best judged after we have
the benefit of the official federal budget message in January and see the public reaction thereto.

Statement of Governor Robertson*s Reasons for
Opposing an Increase of the Ceilings on Interest Rates Payable on Time Deposits from 4 and
4-1/2 per cent to 5-1/2 per cent, December 3, 1965
Governor Robertson dissented from this action generally for the same reasons given for his dissent from the
action to raise the discount rate.

The latter action, he

assumed, was designed to tighten credit, in view of the
rapid expansion of bank credit; it surely was not designed
• 8Imply to raise interest rates.

However, in his view, the

raising of the ceilings on interest rates payable on time
deposits would - in virtually the same breath - enable
banks to acquire more funds to expand their lending but at
higher rates, and thus ndt serve to reduce bank credit expansion - if that were the aim.

In addition, he felt, the

larger banks would be able to attract funds away from
smaller financial institutions which did not actively engage in the issuance of time deposits but relied on inflows
of savings and demand deposits with which to meet loan demands, or, alternatively, to force those smaller banks to
also engage in the risky business of competitively bidding
for highly interest-sensitive short-term funds with which
to make long-term loans.