View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

PROGRESS REPORT BY
J. L. ROBERTSON
MEMBER OF THE BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL FINANCE OF THE
SENATE BANKING AND CURRENCY COMMITTEE
ON THE PROGRAM FOR VOLUNTARY RESTRAINT OF FOREIGN CREDIT
BY BANKS AND OTHER FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS
August 5, 1965
Mr. Chairman, I appear in response to your request for
information on the voluntary foreign credit restraint program, under
which financial institutions are taking part in the President's program
to improve our payments balance, in accordance with guidelines issued
by the Federal Reserve System.

Copies of these guidelines and accompanying

news releases have been furnished to your Coor.mittee.
This program includes two separate but interrelated parts.
The first aims at reducing the expansion of bank credit to foreigners;
the second seeks to limit the expansion of credits and investments abroad
by other

financial institutions, such as mutual funds, insurance companies,

and pension and other trust funds.
Credits and investments of financial institutions played an
increasingly important role among the factors responsible for last year's
deficit in our payments balance.

While it would be impossible to state

that any special item of our payments balance "caused" the deficit to the
exclusion of the others, it certainly should be considered significant
if one item deteriorated while the others improved.

And this is what

happened last year in the case of capital flows*
The outflow of U.S. private capital, excluding direct investments
of U.S. firms abroad and net purchases of foreign securities, averaged $1.4
billion annually in the years 1960 through 1963.




In the same period, our

-2 payments deficit, as calculated by the Department of Commerce, averaged
$3.5 billion per year.

Hence, that outflow was equal to just about

40 per cent of the total payments deficit.
But in 1964, this ratio suddenly changed.

The payments deficit

declined slightly to $3.1 billion but the outflow of capital (again
excluding direct investments and purchases of securities) rose to $3.4
billion.

In 1964, therefore, that outflow was equal to 110 per cent of

the total payments deficit and at least two-thirds of that outflow
reflected transactions of banks and investment concerns.
These figures should not be interpreted as meaning that our
payments balance would have improved in exact proportion to a decline
in the capital outflow.

No doubt, part of the bank credit expansion

was connected with the rapid increase in our merchandise exports, which,
rose by $3.2 billion between 1963 and 1964.

And the newly extended

credits and investments also yielded seme income in 1964.

Nevertheless,

a large part of the newly extended credits had no connection with exports
of U.S. goods or services, and the increased returns attributable to
the increased capital outflow obviously did not offset more than a small
fraction of that outflow.
For these reasons, it seemed clear at the time of the President's
message of February 10, 1965--and it seems even clearer today, when we
have better statistics on the subject— that any decisive improvement in
our payments balance would be impossible without a reduction in the outflow
of capital provided by banks and other financial institutions.

This

reduction is the goal of the voluntary foreign credit restraint program.




-3 Let me stress that our program is designed to limit, not to
eliminate, the expansion of our credits to foreigners and of our investments
abroad.

We are fully aware of the need for a steady expansion of those

credits and investments.

Such expansion is needed to support expanding

exports of U.S. goods and services; to make more private capital available
for the development programs of less developed countries; and to help»
meet the financial needs of such nations as Canada and Japan, which have
traditionally depended on the inflow of U.S. funds.

Nothing in our

program should be interpreted as indicating that we regard credits to
foreigners or investments abroad as harmful in themselves; on the contrary,
we know very well that the world-wide activities of our banks and other
financial institutions are not only an important source of future income
for our economy but also an important means of contributing to the
expansion of international commerce and hence to the economic growth of
the free world as a whole.
But just because the international activities of our banks
and investment concerns are so important, it is necessary to avert the
danger of excessive and unsustainable expansion, which would risk harming
the international position of the dollar, with ail its potential
implications for our domestic as well as the international economy.
Under our bank guidelines, banks are requested to limit the
increases in their foreign credits so that their outstanding credits
to foreigners will not exceed 105 per cent of the amount outstanding
at the end of 1964.

Since the latter amount was approximately $10

billion, this means that the banks are requested to limit their net




-4 credit expansion in 1965 to approximately $500 million, as compared with
an average expansion of about $1 billion annually in the years from 1960
through 1963, and a record expansion of more than $2 billion in 1964.
Financial concerns other than banks are requested to limit similarly
those credits and investments in which those concerns are likely to
compete with banks; this means primarily credits with a maturity not
exceeding ten years.

While those concerns are not requested to limit

credits or investments of more than ten years to any specific amount
or percentage, they are requested to avoid any increase in the total
of such credits or investments in foreign developed countries other
than Canada, Britain, or Japan.

Moreover, they are requested to reduce

their holdings of liquid funds abroad to the 1963 level.
Within the limits of the expansion target, both banks and
investment concerns are requested to give absolute priority to credits
providing bona fide financing for exports of U.S. goods and services.
On the basis of data furnished by the banks themselves, we calculated
that the target gave ample room for any foreseeable need to expand
export financing.
Second only to that absolute priority, all institutions are
requested to give priority to credits to less developed nations.

Moreover,

the exemption of credits and investments with a maturity of more than
ten years granted to investment concerns removes any obstacle under the
program to such long-term credits to, and investments in, less developed
countries--the type of credits and investments which is considered most
beneficial to these countries.




-

5

-

And thirdly, all institutions are requested to avoid restrictive
actions that (night embarrass Canada and Japan, which are traditionally
dependent on financing from U.S. sources, and Britain, which is suffering
from a serious balance-of-payments problem of its own.

Again, the guide­

line provision regarding long-term credits and investments of institutions
other than banks removes the danger of inhibiting the expansion of such
credits to, and investments in, the Canadian economy.
The three categories of priorities, incidentally, broadly
parallel the provisions of the Interest Equalization Tax, which generally
exempt export credits and credits to less developed countries and which
permit certain exemptions for countries such as Canada and Japan.

Our bank guidelines, including 14 specific points, were issued
on March 5, 1965, after consultation with the Treasury and other interested
government agencies and after obtaining the views of experts from the
banking community; since then, two of these points have been amended in
order to clarify their intent.

In addition, requests received from banks

for advice on controversial points have been answered by a set of
interpretations, designed to help the banks to participate in the program
in line with its purposes.
Formulation of guidelines for investment concerns was complicated
by two factors.

First, the Federal Reserve was less well acquainted with

the practices of those concerns than with the activities of commercial
banks; and second, the statistical material available on the international
credit activities of those concerns was quite fragmentary, in contrast
with the data regularly collected from banks by both the Treasury and




the Federal Reserve.

For these reasons, the Board of Governors felt

compelled at first, on March 8, 1965, to issue only tentative guidelines
for investment concerns.

After consultation with experts in that field

and aftex. analysis of improved statistical material collected for that
purpose, we issued revised guidelines for those concerns on June 21,
1965.
Both sets of guidelines are based on the principle of minimizing
interference with the business of the participating institutions, and
especially with individual business decisions.

Within the broad targets,

it is left to banks as well as to investment concerns to choose the best
way to abide by the guidelines.

In particular, the Board of Governors

as well as the Federal Reserve Banks, through which we maintain close
contact with participating institutions, have attempted to answer
questions of interpretation in terms of general principles, and to
avoid passing on individual cases.

In this way, we have avoided the

risk of letting the voluntary restraint program turn into a partial
system of exchange controls.
Needless to say, we do not regard our guidelines as sacrosanct*
We are constantly consulting with other government agencies and with
experts from the participating banks and other institutions on the
problems raised by the program, and are following closely the statistics
collected under the President's program in order to evaluate the current
status of our payments balance as well as the success of, and continuing
need for, foreign credit restraint.




-7 So far, the program has proved outstandingly successful.

This

success is due to the splendid cooperation of the participating banks
and investment concerns.

Each institution willingly cooperates because

it knows the "rules of the game," and realizes that it receives exactly
the same treatment as all other institutions of its kind, wherever located,
with no individual exemptions or exceptions.
Adherence to the program has meant giving up many opportunities
to engage in profitable business transactions, and it is truly voluntary.
Nevertheless, the financial community has responded to the President's
appeal with a spontaneity and unanimity that has not only astonished
our foreign critics— who at the beginning had dismissed the idea of
voluntary restraint at best as an utopian dream or at worst as fatuous
make-believe— 'but even some of us here at home.
A few figures will show you what I mean.

In the first two

months of 1965, bank credits to foreigners rose at a monthly rate of
nearly $200 million.

In March, the first month under the voluntary

restraint program, the expansion fell to less than $50 million--and
presumably most of that outflow was the consequence of earlier binding
commitments, which the institutions are, of course, obliged to honor.
And in the second quarter, the net expansion was replaced by a net
reduction in credits to foreigners, averaging more than $100 million
per month* Consequently, at the end of June 1965, total bank credits
to foreigners were only about $100 million higher than at the end of
1964.




8
Incidentally, these figures are based on special reports of
the participating banks to the Federal Reserve, and are not strictly
comparable to the data on capital flows generally used in the analysis
of our payments balance,

I am submitting for the record a statement

presenting additional statistical information regarding the foreign
lending activity of commercial banks under the program.

Financial institutions other than banks have also cooperated
well in the restraint effort.

In 1964, the concerns participating in

the program had expanded their credits to foreigners and investments
abroad by nearly $1 billion; in the first six months of 1965, according
to preliminary and incomplete data, the expansion was on the order of
$100 million.

Liquid funds held abroad were reduced by more than $100

million; credits and investments with a maturity of not more than ten
years rose very little; and long-term credits and investments expanded
by nearly $200 million.

The pattern of these changes fully conforms to

the intent of the guidelines.
Needless to say, the gratifying results to date
entirely be attributed to the program itself.

cannot

For instance, the dock

strike of January-February 1965 inhibited the growth of exports and
hence also of export credits during that period; and more recently,
the measures taken by industrial countries to combat

inflationary

pressures and reduce payments deficits, as well as less favorable
developments in the international trade position of less developed




-

9

-

I may say, incidentally, that the recent slowing down in our
exports can by no means be attributed, even in part, to the voluntary
restraint program:

not only because the guidelines do not permit the

participating institutions to take the program as an excuse for denying
needed export credit accommodation to any creditworthy applicant; not
only because all our inquiries so far have failed to unearth a single
actual case in which an export transaction failed to materialize because
of denial of credit to a creditworthy borrower under color of the
restraint program; but also because the very fact that the banks as a
whole are considerably below the suggested credit target proves that
the banking system has, indeed, ample room for increasing its export
credits without risking a violation of the suggested ceiling.
A second reason for the virtual cessation of credit expansion
independent from the restraint program probably may be found in the
unusually large rise in credits during the last quarter of 1964 and the
first six weeks of 1965.

Some foreign countries or individual borrowers

may well have exhausted the credit lines envisaged by the managers of
prudent banks and investment concerns.
A third factor—*almost needless to say— was the extension of
the Interest Equalization Tax to bank credits with a maturity of at
least one year, together with the proposed subjection to the tax of
nonbank credits with a maturity of at least one year but no more than
three years.

In recent months, however, some European and Japanese

borrowers have been willing to reimburse the tax to U.S. lenders so
that the tax alone would not have made credits to those borrowers




10
unattractive.

-

In these cases, the voluntary restraint program has

served to supplement and reinforce the Interest Equalization Tax.
When the voluntary restraint program was started, we knew
that in view of the large credit expansion of January and February
quite a few banks already were above the target suggested for the
entire year. We also knew that others would necessarily exceed that
target sometime during the year because the guidelines requested banks
not only to honor any binding commitments but also to extend bona fide
export credits, even if such extension meant a temporary excess over
the suggested ceiling.

Subsequent statistics showed that, at the end

of March, about 60 participating banks were above the suggested ceiling
by a total of $275 million.

Representatives of some of these banks

assured us that it would be impossible for them to reduce outstanding
credits fast enough to get below the suggested ceiling before the end
of 1965, unless they were to violate the provisions in regard to binding
commitments and priority credits.

For this reason, the guidelines

stated that a bank finding itself on those grounds in excess of the
suggested ceiling would not be deemed to have failed to conform to
the guidelines, provided it managed to get below the ceiling not later
than one year from the issue of the guidelines, i.e., not later than
in March 1966.
But by the end of June 1965, the aggregate amount by which
banks exceeded the ceiling had dropped to $100 million; this means
that these banks as a group have reduced their excess by two-thirds
within as short a period as three months.




Equally important, most

-

11

-

banks now in excess are so by very small amounts or for clearly temporary,
sometimes seasonal, reasons; not more than a handful still have substantial
excesses that may pose some problem for bank management.
The most gratifying part of the program has been the compliance
of banks and other institutions with the suggested credit priorities.

I

have already mentioned that, despite some rumblings about interference
of the restraint program with the export drive, no concrete instance of
unjustified refusal of export financing has been discovered— although
export financing is often less profitable than other forms of credit
and some banks might have been tempted to keep within the overall ceiling
by means of curtailing export credits in favor of other more profitable
transactions.
Bank credits to less developed countries also have been expanded
in accordance with the guidelines.

True, short-term credits to those

countries have hot risen, in line with the lag in the expansion of our
exports to those countries; but in the first half year of 1965, the
annual rates of commitments on, and actual disbursements of, bank loans
to less developed countries with a maturity of one year or more compared
favorably with those for 1964.
In the first half of 1965, again according' to incomplete figures,
investment concerns increased by $300 million their long-term credits to,
and investments in, the less developed countries as well as Canada and
Japan, while reducing them by $125 million in other industrial countries.
The figures were roughly equivalent to the half-yearly 1964 averages for
the less developed countries and Canada, and substantially more favorable
for Japan, which suffered a reduction in long-term credits last year.




-

12

The restraint program has resulted in some withdrawal of
American funds from the so-called Euro-dollar market, both directly
and through the shift of liquid funds out of Canadian banks, which
usually invest at least part of such funds in the Euro-dollar market.
This withdrawal caused some stiffening of rates in that market.

But

this stiffening in turn has induced more European funds to flow into
Euro-dollars, and by the end of June rates in that market had returned
to their earlier levels, about 1/2 of 1 per cent above rates for
certificates of deposit in New York.
The guidelines aimed at reducing the outflow of financial
capital by curtailing these flows to Continental Europe.

Continental

Europe has a chronic surplus in its payments balance with the rest of
the world.

European central banks therefore have urged, and later

welcomed, the reduction in the inflow of funds from the United States,
which not only added to their payments imbalance but also, in their
opinion, to domestic inflationary pressures in Europe.

It is true

that the success of our program may have curtailed that inflow more
than they had thought possible.

And the recent tendency of European

subsidiaries of American firms to cooperate in the balance-of-payments
program by seeking financing in Europe rather than in the United States
may have added to the credit stringency in some European countries.
But this development, although perhaps in some cases temporarily
embarrassing for those countries, actually is contributing to the
restoration of financial stability throughout the world.

It induces

and permits the central banks of the affected European countries to




-

13

-

relax their credit restraints without risking domestic inflationary
pressures--the mere substitution of domestic for foreign funds without
a change in total domestic investment cannot have inflationary repercussions.
And at the same time, the resulting narrowing of differences in credit
conditions between Continental Europe and the United States will permanently
help to reduce the payments surplus of Europe together with the payments
deficit of the United States.
I should like to close on that optimistic note; but it is my
duty also to point to some less reassuring consequences of the very
success of the restraint program. According to present indications, the
second quarter of 1965 has shown for the first time in many years a
surplus in our payments balance.

This is, of course, highly satisfactory.

But the change in the flows of bank credits to foreigners, alone, is about
as large as the entire probable improvement in our payments balance between
either the first quarter of this year or the quarterly average of last
year, and the second quarter of this year.
This is disquieting because our voluntary restraint program
is meant to be a temporary expedient, and in fact cannot be expected to
work smoothly except on a temporary basis.

We may hope that it will lead

to the better realignment of American and European capital markets,
mentioned before.

But it would probably be unrealistic to expect that

this realignment alone will be sufficient to eliminate our payments
deficit for good.

To that end, we need renewed improvement in our

current balance as well as further domestic economic expansion, to make
investment at home more attractive than investment in foreign industrial
countries and especially in Continental Europe*




-

14

-

Our monetary policies must be consistent with both these
endeavors:

firm enough to prevent price and cost increases from

endangering our international competitiveness; but not so firm as to
let a stringency of credit endanger the financing of continued domestic
growth.

The voluntary credit restraint program is no substitute for

these general policies; but I hope that it will continue to supplement
them until the improvement in our more basic international economic
relations has led to payments equilibrium without the need for
specifically restraining credits -to foreigners.

I am looking forward

to the day when we shall be able to discontinue our voluntary credit
restraint efforts— as eagerly as does the financial community itself.




Statistical Information Regarding the
Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint Effort of
Commercial Banks
Submitted to the
Subcommittee on International Finance
of the
Senate Banking and Currency Committee
by
J. L. Robertson,
Member of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System
August 5, 1965
Summary figures regarding the position of the banks at the
end of each month since February are shown in Table 1. This tabula­
tion includes only those banks with total foreign assets in excess of
$500,000; the number of banks included varies somewhat from month to
month.
Table 1.

Foreign Credits of United States Banks
(Dollar amounts in millions)
February March

Number of banks

April

May

June

145

145

150

154

156

Total foreign claims subject
to 105 per cent ceiling

9839

9883

9748

9663

9579

Target ceiling (105 per cent
of December 1964 base)

9953

9953

9958

9972

9963

Net expansion of claims since
December 1964

360

405

264

165

88

Net expansion of claims
remaining within target
ceiling

112

70

211

308

384




- 2-

Tables 2 and 3 present certain data regarding banks having
outstanding foreign credits in excess of 105 per cent of their base
as of the end of each month.

The specific banks included in this

group vary from month to month.

Many banks are relatively close to

the 105 per cent ceiling, and a small change in outstanding credit
may thus cause them to shift from a position of just under to just
over the target, and vice versa.
Table 2. Foreign Claims of
Banks in Excess of Target Ceiling
February March
Number of banks
Net reduction in claims
necessary to achieve target
($ million)

April

May

June

56

56

53

48

52

265

275

197

109

110

Table 3. Analysis of Foreign Credits of
Banks in Excess of Target Ceiling, June 1965

Number of
Banks
4
10
8
30

"Excess"
Credits of
($ million)
More than 4.9
2.0-4.9
1 . 0- 1.9
Under 1,0

Amount of
Credit in
Excess of Target
($ million)

Credit
Increase
Jan. ..June 1965
(per cent)

56
28
11
13

8.9
17.4
6.3
12.2

Repdrting by commercial banks under the voluntary foreign
credit restraint effort has also provided, for the first time, accurate
information on the total foreign claims of U.S. banks.




The following

3tabulation is based on foreign claims subject to the restraint effort;
that is, it excludes credits guaranteed by or arranged through the
Export-Import Bank as well as loans made by foreign branches, but it
includes long-term securities, real assets, and the net investment in
foreign branches and subsidiaries.

It differs from the data on foreign

assets reported by U.S. banks, as currently published in the Federal
Reserve and Treasury Bulletins, mainly in that it does not include
assets held for the account of customers nor does it include foreign
assets of U.S. agencies of foreign banks.




Table 4. Foreign Claims of
United States Banks by Size Group, December 1964
(Amounts in billions of dollars)
Banks Ranked
by Size of
Foreign Claims

Total of
Group

Total, 154 banks

9.5

5 largest banks
Banks 6-10
Banks 11-15
Banks 16-20
Banks 21-25

5.0
2.1
0.6
0.35
0.25

Cumulative Total
Amount Per Cent

5.0
7.1
7.7
8.05
8.3

53
75
81
85
87