View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release 11:00 a.m.
December 13, 1965 E.S.T.




Remarks of J. L. Robertson
Member of the Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System
at the
American Conference on
"The Atlantic Community and Economic Growth"
Crotonville, New York
December 13, 1965

Banks and the Balance of Payments Problem

My assignment is to give you a report on the progress
of the part of the President's balance of payments program
administered by the Federal Reserve. In general, I can re­
port , that program has been highly successful and the coop­
eration of the financial institutions to which it applies
has been magnificent. Although it might come more appro­
priately from one whose background is linked closer to world
financial centers than to Broken Bow, Nebraska, I would like
to place that particular segment of the balance of payments
program in a broader context. In particular, I would like
to review the course of our balance of payments over recent
years and to bring out the nature of the problem that has
called for specific corrective action.
There is no doubt that the balance of payments pre­
sents a real challenge to government policies and business
decisions in the United States. For us, in contrast to so
many other countries, this is a new challenge. For many
years, we as a nation were able to ignore the net balance
of our international transactions. But those days are over
and it is probably safe to predict that they will not re­
turn. We must be prepared to have a deliberate balance of
payments policy aimed at maintaining equilibrium in our ex­
ternal accounts.
The need for responsible public and private actions
aimed at encouraging a vigorously growing domestic economy
without inflation has been generally recognized and accepted
in the United States. This commitment is expressed in the
Employment Act of 1946, and was implemented by the actual
policies pursued during the postwar period. We accept the
fact that the achievement of our domestic objectives cannot
be left fully to market forces but requires the overall in­
fluence of governmental policies as well. We must now recog­
nize that the achievement of balance of payments equilibrium
also requires governmental policies. Such policies recog­
nize that private economic decisions are basically made in
response to market incentives. But the net outcome of a
myriad of private decisions to buy and sell and to borrow
and lend does not necessarily or automatically result in
economy or in our bal-




- 2 -

These observations are confirmed by our balance of
payments experience in recent years. Ever since 1958, the
United States has each year incurred a deficit in its bal­
ance of payments equal to several billion dollars. The
first fact to observe about our persistent balance of pay­
ments deficit is that it is not of the classical textbook
variety. It does not result from excessive spending or in­
flation at home which inevitably spills over the borders,
leading to an excess of imports over exports. On the con­
trary, the United States has consistently exported more
goods than it has imported. Furthermore, the surplus of
our exports over imports has been increasing significantly
in recent years. The annual surplus on goods and services,
including investment income in our receipts and all govern­
ment expenditures (including capital outlays) abroad in our
payments, has grown by $3-1/2 billion between 1960 and 1964.
This, in itself, is a remarkable performance. It is
clear that some form of adjustment process has, in fact,
been at work. In significant degree, this large improve­
ment in our basic trading position is attributable to our
success in maintaining price stability at home while prices
abroad rose considerably.
Nevertheless, we still have a balance of payments
problem. For while our current account surplus has in­
creased so much, the net outflow of capital from the United
States has also increased sharply. There are many reasons
for the surge of capital outflow, and I shall discuss some
of these in a moment.
It is not my intention to disparage the contribution
of capital outflow - either private or governmental - to
economic growth abroad and to our own exports as well as to
our other earnings abroad. On the other hand, it is an un­
deniable fact that not all capital outflow is immediately
offset by corresponding earnings from exports or investment
income.
It seems fair to describe our balance of payments
problem in the following way: There is a tendency for capi­
tal outflow from the United States to exceed the surplus we




- 3 -

are able to earn on our transactions in goods and services,
including investment income, if we regard government ex­
penditures and outlays abroad as a necessary deduction from
that surplus. Certainly, we have every reason to encourage
and foster a growing surplus of exports over imports and
thereby enable us to make increased amounts of credit and
capital available to other countries. This is in our inter­
est and in the interest of other countries, especially less
developed countries that are striving to cope with a short­
age of savings in their efforts to accelerate their growth
rates. But one must conclude from the experience of recent
years that from time to time there will be a tendency for
the flow of capital over our borders to exceed the size of
even the most favorable account surplus, net of our govern­
ment payments abroad, that we can reasonably expect to
achieve.
Let me turn, therefore, to the question why there
is a tendency for American capital to flow abroad in such
large and growing amounts. For one thing, the U. S. econ­
omy during much of the 1960’s had unutilized resources of
manpower and plant while Western Europe and Japan tended to
experience the opposite problem, excess demand and inflation.
In the circumstances, with policies here designed to stimu­
late aggregate demand and policies abroad attempting to
limit total spending, our interest rates and credit condi­
tions were especially conducive to lending and investing
abroad. Thus a part of our capital outflow in recent years
is explained by a difference in domestic economic conditions
and in domestic economic policy as between the United States
and other developed countries.
There is every reason to believe, however, that even
in the absence of this difference in domestic resource uti­
lization, there would have been a strong tendency for foreign
demands for funds to converge heavily on U. S. banks and cap­
ital markets and for U. S. investors to be strongly attracted
overseas. Here are some of the reasons for these tendencies:




(1)
Developed countries abroad, in attempting to
cope with domestic inflationary pressures, have leaned
more heavily on monetary than on fiscal policy. In




- 4 -

fact, some developed countries have even eased their
fiscal policies in the face of domestic inflationary
pressures, while tightening monetary policy further.
Such actions have inevitably tended to raise interest
rates and to make capital inflow more attractive in
countries that were already experiencing surpluses in
their balances of payments. In the United States the
mix of fiscal and monetary policies has, I think, been
more appropriate to our combined internal-external po­
sition. We have used fiscal policy more forcefully
than monetary policy in attempting to restore full use
of domestic resources. This has meant that we have not
lowered our own interest rates as much as we might have
and, in fact, have tended to raise them while pursuing
policies designed to stimulate domestic incomes and
output. But, because of the overemphasis on monetary
policy abroad, interest rates there have advanced at
least as much if not more than rates here. What is
needed in many foreign countries is greater develop­
ment and more flexibility of fiscal policy to cope
with domestic problems. Of course, this is desirable
in any event, quite apart from the problem of balance
of payments adjustment.
(2)
In addition to these differences in policy,
there are important structural differences between
capital markets here and abroad. The United States
capital market is the largest, most efficient, and
most accessible in the world, and, until recently,
there were no governmental restrictions on foreign
borrowing in this market. In contrast, most foreign
capital markets are relatively small and fragmented,
hemmed in with restrictions on borrowing by outsiders,
and subject to exchange controls that limit the abil­
ity of their own residents to invest abroad. The
enormous size of our country and the correspond­
ingly large flow of funds from savers to investors
through our markets mean that even large amounts of
foreign borrowing can be accommodated with only mar­
ginal impact on our financial markets. By the same
token, it requires a large change in the flow of funds
through our markets to affect significantly the flow
to foreign borrowers, if we attempt to cope with the
problem through general monetary restriction alone.

- 5 -

(3) American financial institutions, both bank
and nonbank, are more willing (and often much freer)
to extend long-term credits than their counterparts
abroad. They have become accustomed to providing
liquidity to the funds they gather while satisfying
a need for long-term accommodation on the part of
those to whom they lend. This helps to explain both
the smaller differential between short- and long-term
interest rates in the United States and the ready
availability of long-term funds to both foreign and do­
mestic borrowers.
(4) American banks are highly competitive, avidly
seeking to satisfy the needs of foreign as well as do­
mestic borrowers, in contrast to the more cartelized
banking systems in most foreign countries. Both the
lower cost and the greater availability of funds have
tended to encourage bank lending abroad.
(5) American corporations have faced numerous
special incentives to make direct investments in Conti­
nental Europe. Rapid growth in the Common Market coun­
tries, combined with the prospect of relatively higher
tariffs on imports from outside that area, has pro­
vided a strong attraction to American corporations to
locate there. The rapid development of mass-consumption economies in the Continental European countries,
together with their success in overcoming their tech­
nological lag as well as their currency problems, is
too well known to need elaboration. These dynamic
changes, after almost three decades of depression,
instability, war, and reconstruction, have provided
an environment conducive to a surge of investment, and
hence to an unusually heavy demand for investible funds.
Not all of these factors that I have referred to as
tending to cause a large flow of capital from the United
States to other developed countries will necessarily per­
sist year-in and year-out. Some will change with the busi­
ness cycle and others will experience a gradual alteration
over time. For example, there is evidence that the unusu­
ally large profit margins abroad are declining to levels
comparable with those earned at home.




- 6 -

But I wish to stress two conclusions that follow
from these observations. The first is that the tendency
for capital to flow from the United States to other coun­
tries in large volume and particularly to other developed
countries is not simply the result of inadequate policies
within the United States. It should be clear from what I
have said that much of the explanation - and I am not speak­
ing in terms of blame but solely of explanation - lies in
the institutions and policies found elsewhere. This does
not mean that we in the United States must not cope with
our own balance of payments problem as best we can; it
does mean that the measures we adopt to cope with the
problem must recognize its true nature.
In response to these special influences, American
capital has moved abroad in a great surge in the first half
of the 1960*s, offsetting in part at least the distinct im­
provement in our competitive position. To cope with this
tendency, a series of policy measures has been adopted in
recent years. You are familiar with them and I shall only
mention them in passing. Beginning early in the 1960’s,
the Federal Reserve began to conduct its monetary policy which was naturally preoccupied with the high unemployment
rate and the large volume of idle capacity in industry - so
as to maintain upward pressure on short-term interest rates
and thereby to discourage tendencies toward the outflow of
short-term funds.
The investment tax credit, enacted in 1962, was a
measure designed to enhance the incentive to undertake plant
and equipment spending here. It might be regarded as the
equivalent of a substantial reduction in long-term interest
rates, but one that serves to curtail rather than encourage
the outflow of investment funds.
In 1963, the Interest Equalization Tax was proposed
as a measure, operating through the market system, to dis­
courage American purchases of securities issued by, and
other long-term credits to, borrowers in developed coun­
tries abroad (with exceptions for Canada and Japan).




- 7 -

And in early 1965, President Johnson announced a
balance of payments program that was highlighted by vol­
untary efforts aimed at further reducing the flow of cred­
it and direct investment from the United States to de­
veloped countries.
Our guidelines, under the Federal Reserve's part
of that program, suggested that banks restrain their to­
tal credits to foreigners in such a way that outstanding
credits at any time during 1965 would not exceed 105 per
cent of the amounts outstanding at the end of 1964, thus
reducing the outflow of dollars through the expansion of
bank credit from $2.4 billion in 1964 to not more than
$500 million. They also suggested (as do the new guide­
lines for 1966) that absolute priority be given to bona
fide export credits, and highest priority, among other
credits, to loans to less developed countries; that cred­
its not be reduced to Britain, which is suffering from pay­
ments difficulties of its own, or Canada and Japan, which
are highly dependent for their economic growth on the in­
flow of U. S. capital and credit; and that any needed re­
duction in credits in order to meet the target be confined
to other developed countries, especially those enjoying a
payments surplus, such as the countries of Continental
Western Europe.
For financial institutions other than banks (e.g.»
insurance companies, mutual funds, finance companies, pen­
sion funds, foundations, and the like), the guidelines
suggested a reduction of liquid funds invested in foreign
money markets to the 1963 level. They suggested also a
limitation of credits and investments with maturities not
exceeding ten years similar to those in the guidelines for
banks. But they did not suggest any percentage limitation
of long-term credits and investments in regard to less de­
veloped countries, Britain, Canada, and Japan. Thus, non­
banking institutions (which had increased their foreign
credits last year by over $1 billion) were asked to use
greater restraint than banks in regard to the placement of
liquid f^£ds; were treated like banks in regard to shortand mediuifi-term credits, in which they compete most nearly
with barges; and were treated more leniently in regard to
credits with a maturity of more than ten years. This more




- 8 -

lenient treatment was designed to make sure that the prog­
ress of less developed countries and the economic growth
of Canada would not be hampered by our credit restraint
efforts.
Both banks and other financial institutions have
abided not only by the letter but also by the spirit of
those guidelines. They have displayed to the world their
willingness to cooperate wholeheartedly in a voluntary ef­
fort to solve this national problem - in part, no doubt,
because they are particularly qualified to appreciate its
full significance. By the end of September 1965, total
foreign credits of participating banks actually were be­
low the amounts outstanding at the end of 1964; and total
credits and investments of other financial institutions
were only 4.8 per cent above the 1964 level.
Even more gratifying than these overall figures
was the degree of compliance with the suggested priori­
ties. Banks reduced their short-term credits and in­
creased their long-term credits to foreigners, and espe­
cially long-term credits to less developed countries. In
fact, their total credits to those countries rose substan­
tially, in spite of the drop in overall credits to foreign­
ers.
Nonbank financial institutions reduced their liquid
funds held abroad, kept their other short- and medium-term
credits virtually unchanged, and increased their long-term
credits and investments by $700 million. While by far the
largest single increase was in long-term credits to Canada,
there also was a substantial increase in investments in
less developed countries. In contrast, long-term credits
and investments in developed countries other than Canada
and Japan were substantially reduced.
The reduction in the outflow of bank credit, in
compliance with the guideline targets, was much larger
than the entire improvement in the U. S. payments balance
from the first three quarters of 1964 to the same period
of 1965. Claims of banks on foreigners rose in the first
three quarters of 1964 by $1.4 billion but remained virtu­
ally unchanged in the first three quarters of 1965, with




- 9 -

a large outflow in the first quarter almost exactly off­
set by repatriations in the second and third quarters.
This change alone would have accounted for an improvement
in the U. S. payments balance by $1.4 billion. Since the
U. S. deficit for the first three quarters of last year
also happened to be about $1.4 billion, this improvement
should have been sufficient to eliminate virtually the en­
tire payments deficit for the first three quarters of this
year. Actually, however, the overall improvement in our
balance of payments amounted to only about $400 million calculated on the basis of the so-called regular transac­
tions, which exclude special payments by foreign govern­
ments to the U. S. Government from U. S. receipts. In
other words, other items in our payments balance deteri­
orated by about $1 billion so that the overall improvement
fell short of our hopes.
Part of this shortfall is more apparent than real.
Foreign sales of U. S. securities rose by $400 million. It
is no secret that this figure presumably reflects sales of
securities owned by the British Government and put into
liquid assets in order to help finance, if necessary, the
payments deficit of the United Kingdom.
But there was some genuine deterioration in other
items. First, while our exports rose by about $500 mil­
lion in comparison with the first three quarters of last
year, our imports rose by $1-3/4 billion.
Second, while we do not know yet the exact amount of
direct investments abroad of U. S. nonfinancial corporations
in the third quarter, there can be no doubt that the total
for the first three quarters will turn out to be higher by
many hundreds of million dollars than the already unusually
large amount of such investments in the first three quarters
of last year.
It seems clear that the balance of payments results
for 1965 will show a definite improvement over the record
for the earlier years of this decade. But we still are far
from reasonable equilibrium. In fact, we have barely reached
the half-way mark between our huge 1964 deficit and our goal




- 10 -

of payments balance, and the second half of the road may
be even more difficult than the first half has been.
These considerations have made it necessary to con­
tinue the voluntary restraint effort, at least for the time
being. The effort has, in fact, been made more stringent
for that part of the program that is under the guidance of
the Commerce Department and that relates to foreign invest­
ments of nonfinancial corporations. Fortunately, because
of the excellent results achieved by banks and other finan­
cial institutions, we were able to permit our Federal Re­
serve guidelines to remain essentially unchanged.
Even though the banking and financial system as a
whole has stayed well under the suggested ceiling for 1965,
some leeway for further expansion in 1966 was deemed appro­
priate for two reasons. First, I am sure that financial
institutions will continue to cooperate with the spirit as
well as the letter of the program, and will expand their
foreign credits only to the extent necessary to meet pri­
ority credit needs. Secondly, I wanted to make doubly cer­
tain that export financing will be available in adequate
amounts, and that the credit needs of less developed coun­
tries will continue to be met.
Consequently, under the 1966 program, commercial
banks are requested to restrain any expansion in foreign
credits to such an extent that the amount outstanding does
not exceed 109 per cent of the amount outstanding on De­
cember 31, 1964. Further, in order to spread throughout
the year any outflow necessary to meet priority credit re­
quirements, it is requested that the target be only gradu­
ally approached, and therefore the ceiling was raised by
one per cent per calendar quarter. Special ceilings for
banks with small bases, to enable them to meet needs for
priority credits (but only those) will add about one per
cent to the total, bringing the possible expansion in 1966,
for the banking system as a whole, to about the same amount
as would have been permissible in 1965.
The 1966 guidelines for nonbank financial institu­
tions are again broadly comparable with the bank guidelines.




- 11 -

All of us realize, however, that the present volun­
tary programs by their very nature can only be stopgaps.
We hope that structural changes may occur that will elimi­
nate at least some of the incentives mentioned before, which
have been responsible for the excessive capital outflows of
recent years. But we cannot rely merely on good luck.
As we think about where we go from here, perhaps
we can start from the following propositions:




(1) The United States must have a balance of pay­
ments policy and a policy that is conducive to rapid
growth and price stability in our own economy and in
the rest of the world, and that is geared as closely
as possible to market processes. As is true of gen­
eral fiscal and monetary policies, our balance of pay­
ment policies should leave decisions as to spending
and investing and lending and borrowing to private
decision-making as much as possible.
(2) The achievement and maintenance of balance
of payments equilibrium requires action, not only by
countries in deficit, but also by countries in sur­
plus. Just as it takes two to tango, it takes two to
eliminate imbalances in international payments. Thus,
while the United States continues to exert its strong­
est efforts to return to equilibrium in its balance
of payments, one may hope that countries in surplus,
especially those in Continental Europe, will bend their
efforts to eliminating restrictions and reducing tariff
barriers on imports, encouraging capital outflow, espe­
cially to developing countries, modernizing and improv­
ing their capital and money markets, and endeavoring to
make their fiscal policies more appropriate to their
own economic situations, and more flexible as well.
(3) Finally, and in summary of what 1 have been
saying, there are no simple solutions to this problem.
It should be clear from what we know of the underlying
forces responsible for the deficit that monetary pol­
icy alone cannot solve either our balance of payments
problem or that of other countries. Monetary policy




- 12 -

in the United States has played a role in the improve­
ment in our foreign position and will continue to do
so. But it cannot by itself restore and preserve bal­
ance of payments equilibrium while also performing its
main task - namely, fostering a vigorously growing and
healthy domestic economy, without inflation, in the in­
terest both of our own citizens and of people around the
world.