View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

O
Assessing the Capital Needs
of Banking

o
Remarks of James E. Smith
Comptroller of the Currency
before the National Correspondent
Banking Conference,
American Bankers Association,
San Francisco, California
November 6,.1973

In preparation for this session, we reviewed some of the
earlier annual reports of the Comptroller of the Currency.

We found

that Comptroller John Skelton Williams, in his 191^ Annual Report,
expressed his concern about the adequacy of the capital of National
banks.

Specifically, he stated:
The view is held by many practical bankers and
experienced economists that it is not sound banking for
an active commercial bank to be allowed to receive
deposits in excess of ten times its capital and surplus.
I am firmly impressed with the correctness of this view,
and respectfully recommend to the Congress that the
national-bank act be amended so as to provide that no
national bank shall be permitted to hold deposits in
excess of ten times its unimpaired capital and surplus.
Perhaps it might be wiser to make this limitation eight
times the capital and surplus.
To put Mr. Williams' recommendation in context, we may note

that as of September 12, 191^-5 the ratio of total deposits to total
capital for all National banks was U.6 .
same ratio for all National banks was n

As of June 30, 1973, the

.h.

Bank regulators must inevitably be concerned with the adequacy
of bank capital.

We in the Comptroller’s Office are giving a good

deal of attention to that question, and I would like to share with
you today our early thinking on some of the issues with which we are
wrestling.
As I see it, there are five major issues.

These are: (l) the

relevance of total economic collapse; (2 ) the weight to be given the




-

2

-

quality of management; (3 ) the role of capital notes and debentures;

(*0 the role of bank capital in bank holding companies; and (5 ) the
usefulness of capital ratios as measures of capital adequacy.

I

will discuss those topics in turn.
The first problem that must be faced in any discussion of
capital adequacy is composing a list of contingencies threatening
bank capital.

At the forefront of that problem is the question:

should the list include total economic collapse?
Perhaps the principal element that may distinguish our answer
to this question today from the answer that may have been appropriate
forty years ago is the changing role of national economic policies.
Most economic authorities are agreed that our knowledge of appropriate
counter-cyclical fiscal and monetary policies is vastly superior to
that available to our policymakers in the early 1930*s.

From this,

one may reasonably assume that an economic debacle of the magnitude
of the Great Depression of the early 1930’s is avoidable.
What does this mean for the stance of the banker and the bank
regulator in connection with capital adequacy?

I think it is defensible

for both bank regulators and bankers to assume that fiscal and monetary
policies will allow the prevention of large-scale economic crises.
We are well aware, however, that cyclical movements have not been




-3abolished, and that periodic recessions of more limited amplitude
are to be expected.

Those swings can bring significant pressures

to bear upon banks.
The second issue to be considered is whether the quality of
management should influence determinations of capital adequacy.

Some

views from outside and inside banking suggest that management quality
has not been given its due.

For example, a major study completed a few

years ago by Professors Robinson and Pettway suggested that bank
examiners "...should take their eyes off bank capital and focus on
the quality of bank management."

The authors continue:

An analogy will help at this point: examiners do
not try to specify the elements of a liquidity policy to
a bank but they rightly critiqize a bank if it does not
have a clearly articulated liquidity policy. By the same
token, why should examiners try to establish capital
standards (which by their nature can't be specified)?
Shouldn’t their efforts and energy be directed to the
problem of making sure that bank managements have clearly
articulated capital policies and that they are implemented
by managers of as high skill and training as possible?
Mr. George Vojta, in his recent monograph, after examining the
body of research dealing with the relationship between bank capital.
and bank failures, concludes that "...the important causal factors
relating to solvency are competence and integrity of management."
The Comptroller's Manual, until its 1971 revision, contained
a section dealing with capital adequacy.




It opened with the statement

that, "The Comptroller of the Currency will not hereafter rely
on the ratios of capital to risk, assets and to total deposits in
assessing the adequacy of capital oi national hanking associations.
That is a strong, unqualified statement, and may account for deletion
of the section in the 1971 revision.

The section also included the

well-known set of eight factors to"...he considered hy the Comptroller
in assessing the adequacy of capital."
was "the quality of management."

The very first factor listed

The other seven were:

(h)

The liquidity of assets;

(c)

The history of earnings and of the
retention thereof; .

(d)

The quality and character of ownership;

(e)

The burden of meeting occupancy expenses;

(f)

The potential volatility of deposit structure;

(g)

The quality of operating procedures; and

(h)

The hank's capacity to meet present and future
financial needs of its trade area, considering
the competition it faces.

Although this list is not contained in the current edition of
the Manual, the factors have not heen disowned by this Office.

Indeed,

to some degree the set of factors has come to epitomize the non-ratio
approach with which the Comptroller has heen identified during the
past decade.
Let me now turn to the issue of capital notes and debentures.
The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency in the early 1960's




-5issued a ruling that encouraged National banks to resort, on appro­
priate occasions, to the sale of debentures to supplement their capital
position.

Until that ruling, senior capital, in the view of many

bankers, was associated only with near-emergency situations at finan­
cially weak institutions.

Our Office has applied a rule of thumb

that limits the proportion of a National bankrs total capital that can
be in debentures to one-third.
Some of the capital formulae applied by bank regulators dis­
criminate against the use of debentures.

For example, one such ratio

involves total equity capital plus reserves on loans and securities,
divided by the sum of total liabilities plus total debentures less
cash and cash items.

It is obvious that a bank with outstanding

debentures is penalized in the application of this ratio, as compared
with a bank that has issued no debentures.
In our Office 3 we believe there is a place for debt instruments
in the capital structure of National banks.

The basic regulatory

function of bank capital is to serve as protection for depositors
and those who assume their risks.

Capital notes and debentures extend

substantial additional protection to bank depositors.

Further, some

market situations would penalize bank stockholders greatly, were the
regulatory authorities to insist upon the sale of equity securities.
Having the option of selling capital notes yields valuable flexibility.
A subsidiary question, in connection with bank debt capital,
relates to the sale by one bank, usually a smaller one, of its




-

debentures to a larger bank.

6
-

There are, I believe, reasons for hold­

ing such transactions to a minimum.

From the standpoint of the entire

banking system, such transactions do not provide any net inflow of
capital.

Were such transactions to proceed on a round-robin basis

throughout the system, it is evident that a substantial watering down
of capital requirements for the system would have occurred.

If the

regulatory authorities desire to reduce capital requirements for
the system, it may be preferable to take such action directly.
Having stated this, I do not today advocate abolition of this type
of transaction.

On occasion, in a particular.situation, this course

of action can be beneficial to both banks involved, and perhaps, to
the mental health of the bank regulator.
Let us now look at the question of bank capital for holding
company banks.
There appears to be fairly general agreement that a bank and
its capital position must be protected, whether or not it is a holding
company subsidiary.

Certainly, from the standpoint of a primary bank

regulator, the relationship of a regulated bank with a parent bank
holding company and its associated non-bank affiliates, should be a
source of positive strength for the bank.

Our Office will oppose any

affiliation for a National bank when that affiliation would tend to
threaten the soundness of the bank.
No single banking agency is responsible for regulating all types
of banking organizations.
is a plus for banking.




In general, that division of responsibility

However, the division of responsibility

-7does lead to some overlap, and to occasional jurisdictional problems.
One such problem involves the adequacy of capital in holding company
banks, where the banks are other than state member banks.
As a primary bank regulator, our Office is concerned with the
soundness of the bank and with its capital position.
We also recognize that the Federal Reserve, as the regulator
of bank holding companies, is legitimately concerned with the capital
position of the holding company per se and its constituent parts.
I would like to offer a suggestion for discussion purposes,
which I plan to pursue further upon my return to Washington.

Would

it be workable for a rebuttable presumption to exist in connection
with the capital position of a subsidiary bank, based on the view of
the primary bank regulator?

In other words, in each case we would

draw a conclusion as to whether or not the capital of a National bank
were adequate.

If our decision were in the affirmative, and if the

bank in question were a subsidiary of a bank holding company, the
Federal Reserve Board would accept our conclusion, unless the Board
found cause for rebutting or attempting to rebut our conclusion.

In

the latter instance, further interagency discussion would be required.
I wish to emphasize that I view such interagency discussions as
a useful, educational exercise for all parties.

Each agency has a

wealth of experience gained from implementing its views of capital
adequacy that has not as yet been fully shared with the other.

No

one, of course, should expect all differences of opinion to evaporate




-

through this sharing.

8
-

However, I am hopeful that major issues can

be resolved.
The fifth and final issue touched on in my introduction relates
to the usefulness of capital ratios as measurements of capital adequacy.
In fact, somewhat more broadly, the question really is: how may the
adequacy of capital be measured?
A variety of capital ratios are used by all bank examiners
as initial screening devices in their attempt to determine whether
an institution under examination is adequately capitalized.

The

loans -to- capital, ratio, the capital-to-total assets ratio, the
capital-to-total deposits ratio -

'j

these and others are among the more

popular measures.
As to the norms or the "acceptable" levels for these ratios,
it is undoubtedly true that the current average figures tend to become
a sort of standard.

In my opening example, I pointed out the sharp

drop in capital ratios over the past 60 years.

This drop illustrates

that we tend to look at the concept of capital adequacy in relative
■berms rather than in absolute terms.
In using ratios, one is often tempted to adopt "minimum"
values for regulatory purposes.

When this is done, there is a natural

tendency on the part of bankers, hard pressed as they are to maintain
a favorable rate of return on capital, to allow their institutions
to slide gradually to the minimum acceptable levels.

The choice of

any minimum which lies below the ratios of a significant number of




-9banks would tend, in and of itself, to exert downward pressure on
the aggregate capital ratios of the system.
I personally believe that no strict formulation can substitute
for the factor of human judgement in determining capital adequacy.
Obviously, if this were not so, the world would be an easier place
for bank regulators.

Were mechanistic judgements to be finally deter­

minative, one perhaps could appoint the latest generation computer
as regulator.

]

\

However, bank regulators do need benchmarks and guideposts,
and I would like to close by describing one exercise in which we are
currently engaged.

Even if this exercise bears fruit, we will not

have altered our basic position that, no strict formula can be finally
determinative of the adequacy of capital.

Rather, we will simply

have another tool to help us in our determination.
As you know, our Office develops classified assets totals for
National banks.

Classified assets are those assets of an institution

which our examiners find to be subject to some type of criticism.
The volume of classified assets is related to the degree of potential
loss in a bank’s asset portfolio.
There are several determinants of the overall classification
of a bank, but a principal one relates to the ratio of classified
assets to gross capital funds.

Gross capital funds include total

stated capital plus reserves on securities and loans.

Banks with a

ratio below 20 percent are A banks, those with a ratio of 20 percent




-

or more but below

kO percent

10

-

are B banks, those With a ratio of ^0

percent or more but below 80 percent are C banks, and those with
a ratio of

80 percent or more are D banks.

We have also divided all National banks into a number of
deposit-size categories.

For our purposes here, let me confine the

discussion to three broad size categories, with the smallest being
those banks with less than

$100 million, and the largest those with

$500 million or more.
The approach we are considering as an additional tool in the
capital adequacy area involves a determination of acceptable limits of
certain capital ratios for banks in each of our groups.

The approach

assumes that the A banks, that is, those banks with relatively low
ratios of classified assets to gross capital funds, can safely reach
higher loans-to-capital ratios than is the case for banks in the D
category.
As of the end of 1972, the ratio of total loans to total capital
accounts for ai 1 insured banks was 7*^»

Taking this as a jumping-off

point, we have explored the question of how many National banks would
require additional capital were various limits of the loans-to-capital
ratio applied to banks in the A, B, C, and D classifications.
In a preliminary exercise, we have applied two different sets
of limits for the loans-to-capital ratio to banks in each classification.
The first ranges from

8.5

for A banks to

range for the second is from




9*0 to 7-0«

6.5

for D banks, wnile the

-

11-

Under the first set of loans-to-capital ratio limits, i.e.,
the set ranging from 8.5 for A banks to 6.5 for D banks, 12.7 percent
of all National banks would need additional capital.

Only 8.U percent

of A banks would require an injection of capital, while the percentages
for the B, C, and D groups would be 30.0 percent,

6!v.6 percent, and

81.3 percent, respectively.
If the set of limits ranging from 9*0 for A hanks to

J.O

for

|

D banks were to be applied, 8.1 percent of all national banks would
fall short.

This would include h .8 percent of A banks, 20.3 percent

of B banks, 51.3 percent of C banks, and

71.9 percent of D banks.

We applied the same sets of limits to banks in various depositsize categories.

For the set of ratio limits ranging from 8.5 to

6 .5 , 12.2 percent of the national banks with deposits under $100
million would require a capital injection.
deposits between

Of National banks with

$100 and $500 million, 1^.8 percent would need to

augment their capital, while for the banks above
comparable percentage would be

$500 million, the

26.6 .

A similar pattern occurs with the application of the set of ratio
limits ranging from 9-0 to 7-0.

For the smailest-size category, 7.8

percent of the hanks would need capital.
the percentage would he
above category,

For the middle size category,

9-1 percent, and for the $500 million and

18.3 percent.

To add some perspective to these figures, it is usexul to
note that most of our National hanks




85*5 percent, in fact

are

-

12-

A banks, and that a far lower percentage of A banks would require
additional capital under the limits discussed than is the case for
the other classifications.

Secondly, for many banks showing a need

for capital under the procedures outlined, a comparatively small
injection would suffice.

This is shown by the fact that altering

limits by small amounts drastically reduces the number of banks fail­
ing to meet the limit test.
It is obvious that similar exercises can be pursued for each
of a number of capital ratios.

We have already made, for example,

a preliminary examination of the effects of various cutoffs applied
to the capital-to-total assets ratio.

5We have not made any deter­

mination to date as to whether different limits would be appropriate
for different-size banks.
I must re-emphasize that whatever the continuing results of
these exercises may be, we will never replace our judgement with any
strict formulation.

We do believe, however, that the more relevant

data that can be brought to bear on the question, the better our
judgement is likely to be.

However, I am reasonably certain that

annual reports of the Comptroller of the Currency well into the
future will continue to provide evidence that no final resolution of
this question has been achieved.