View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Normalization:
A New Approach
James Bullard
President and CEO, FRB-St. Louis
Wealth and Asset Management Research Conference
Olin Business School
Washington University in St. Louis

Aug. 17, 2016
St. Louis, Mo.

1

Introduction

2

A new approach
The St. Louis Fed recently changed its approach to near-term
U.S. macroeconomic and monetary policy projections.
 Wharton Business Radio interview, Aug. 12, 2016.
 J. Bullard, “A Tale of Two Narratives,” remarks delivered at the
Gateway Chapter of NABE, St. Louis, July 12, 2016.
 J. Bullard, “A New Characterization of the U.S. Macroeconomic and
Monetary Policy Outlook,” remarks delivered at the Society of
Business Economists Annual Dinner, London, U.K., June 30, 2016.
 J. Bullard, “The St. Louis Fed’s New Characterization of the Outlook
for the U.S. Economy,” St. Louis Fed commentary, June 17, 2016.
 All available on my webpage under “Key Policy Papers.”

3

Two narratives
An older narrative used by the St. Louis Fed over the last five
years or so has likely outlived its usefulness.
A new narrative is replacing the old narrative.
In this talk, I will describe in more detail the differences
between the two narratives.

4

Overview of the Previous Narrative

5

Gaps tending to zero
The old narrative held that, as inflation and unemployment
gaps narrowed to zero, the policy rate would have to rise.

 For one example, see J. Bullard, “Fed Goals and the Policy Stance,” remarks
delivered at the Owensboro in 2065 Summit, Owensboro, Ky., July 17, 2014.

Today, inflation and unemployment gaps are indeed near
zero—business cycle dynamics have completely played out
seven years after the end of the recession.
This suggests that—since inflation and unemployment are at
normal levels—the policy rate should also be near its normal
level.
This is standard macroeconomics.

6

Nature of the old narrative
What is driving this conclusion?
In the old narrative, there is, axiomatically, a unique long-run
steady state which is essentially an average of the past.
The economy is viewed as converging—all values for key
macroeconomic variables are tending toward steady-state
values.
Implication: The policy rate would likely rise over the
forecast horizon to be consistent with its steady-state value.
Under the old narrative, the St. Louis Fed therefore projected
a rising policy rate over the forecast horizon.

7

Overview of the New Narrative

8

Nature of the new narrative
In the new narrative, the concept of a single, long-run steady
state is abandoned.
Instead, there is a set of possible “regimes” that the economy
may visit.
 J.D. Hamilton, “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary
Time Series and the Business Cycle,” Econometrica, March 1989, 57(2), 357384.
 C.-J. Kim and C.R. Nelson, State-Space Models with Regime Switching, MIT
Press, 1999.

The “regime” language comes from this and subsequent
nonlinear econometrics literature on this topic.

9

More on the nature of the new narrative
Regimes are viewed as persistent, and switches between
regimes are viewed as not forecastable.
Optimal monetary policy is regime-dependent.
The current regime appears to be characterized by slow growth
and low real rates of return on safe assets.
Implication: The policy rate will likely remain essentially flat
over the forecast horizon to remain consistent with the current
regime.
 This implication is very different from the previous narrative.

10

The forecast based on the new narrative
A simple forecast over the next two and a half years:





Real GDP growth
Unemployment
Trimmed-mean PCE inflation
Policy rate

2 percent
4.7 percent
2 percent
63 basis points

Risks associated with this projected policy rate are likely to the
upside.

11

The Previous Narrative and
the End of Its Usefulness

12

Forecasts under the St. Louis Fed’s previous narrative
The typical medium-term forecast during the past several
years under the old narrative:





Output growth above trend.
Unemployment declining.
Inflation (net of commodity-price effects) overshoots 2 percent.
Policy rate increases to be consistent with the unique steady
state.

13

The old narrative: Did it work?
Some aspects of the previous narrative worked well from
second half of 2013 through the first half of 2015:
 The average quarterly real GDP growth rate was about 2.7
percent versus a trend rate of about 2 percent.
• So, economic growth was arguably above trend as we predicted.

 Unemployment declined by 2 percentage points.
• We were relatively accurate on this.

 But, Dallas Fed trimmed-mean PCE inflation measured from
one year earlier was 1.50 percent in July 2013 and increased to
only 1.60 percent in July 2015.
• We did not see the overshooting of the 2 percent inflation target
we expected.

14

The end of the usefulness of the old narrative
The usefulness of our previous narrative may have now come
to an end:
 Output growth has arguably slowed to a rate below a 2 percent
trend.
 Unemployment may not fall much below its current values.
 Trimmed-mean inflation is close to target but not rising rapidly.

If there are no major shocks to the economy, this situation
could be sustained over a forecasting horizon of two and a
half years.
These facts suggest that it may be time to quit using the old
narrative.

15

Previous Narrative and
the End of Its Usefulness in Charts

16

Real output growth has slowed

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis and author’s calculations.
Last observation: 2016-Q2.

17

Unemployment has fallen to a low level

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics and author’s calculations.
Last observation: July 2016.

18

Inflation is closer to target

Source: FRB of Dallas and author’s calculations. Last observation: June 2016.

19

A New Narrative Based on Regimes

20

A new narrative based on regime-switching ideas
An unsatisfactory aspect of the old narrative:
 The policymaker is completely certain that the economy is
converging to a long-run steady state, which is itself an average
of past outcomes.
 How to fix this?

The new narrative: We want a manageable expression of the
uncertainty surrounding medium- and longer-term outcomes.
 One way to do this is to abandon the idea of a long-run steady
state and instead think in terms of regimes that the economy may
visit.
 What are these regimes?

21

The nature of the regimes
Fundamental factors determine the nature of the regimes:
1. Productivity growth—high or low.
2. Real interest rate on short-term government debt—high or low.
3. State of the business cycle—expansion or recession.

The “regime” can refer to any of these states or to the
combination of all three.
Optimal monetary policy is regime-dependent.
Regime switches are not forecastable—viewed as “risks.”
Forecast limited to a horizon of two and a half years—no longrun projections.

22

Productivity regimes
One important fundamental is productivity growth.
Average labor productivity growth has been low at least since
2011, which we view as a “low-productivity-growth regime.”
We assume that we will remain in the low-productivity (and
hence low-real-GDP growth) regime through the forecasting
horizon because regimes are persistent.
Higher productivity growth was observed in the recent past.
A switch back to a high-productivity-growth regime is an
upside risk.

23

The high- and low-productivity-growth regimes

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bureau of Economic Analysis and author’s calculations.
Last observation: 2016-Q1.

24

Real-interest-rate regimes
The real rate of return on short-term government debt, r†, has
been exceptionally low, which we view as a “low-real-rate
regime.”
 Appears to be highly persistent.
 For forecasting purposes, we assume that we will remain in the
low-real-rate regime through the forecasting horizon.

The alternative regime has a relatively high real rate.
 A switch to a high-real-rate regime is viewed as a risk.

25

Real-interest-rate regimes
Interpretation:
 We think of low real rates of return on government paper (safe
assets) as reflecting an unusually high liquidity premium on
government debt.
 Real returns on capital as calculated from GDP accounts are
not particularly low.*
 Therefore, not all real returns in the economy are unusually
low.
 Nevertheless, the real returns on safe assets are the ones most
closely linked to monetary policy.

* See P. Gomme, B. Ravikumar and P. Rupert, “Secular Stagnation and Returns on Capital,”
St. Louis Fed Economic Synopses, August 2015, No. 19.

26

Real rate of return on short-term government debt, r†

Source: Federal Reserve Board, FRB of Dallas and author’s calculations. Last observation: June 2016.

27

The state of the business cycle
Another important fundamental is the possibility of recession.
Currently we are in a “no-recession regime,” but it is possible
that we could switch to a recession state.
All variables would be affected, but most notably, the
unemployment rate would rise significantly.
We have no reason to forecast a recession given the current
state of the U.S. economy.
The possibility of a recession is a risk to the forecast.

28

Recession probability is low

Source: FRED, based on M. Chauvet and J. Piger, “A Comparison of the Real-Time Performance of Business Cycle Dating
Methods,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, January 2008, 26(1), 42-49. Last observation: May 2016.

29

Summary: The current regime
In summary, we think the current regime is characterized by:
 Relatively low probability of recession in the near term.
 Low real interest rate on short-term government debt.
 Low productivity growth.

In addition, business cycle dynamics have played out, and
current unemployment and inflation gaps are near zero.
Given the current regime, what is the optimal path for the
policy rate?

30

The Policy Rate Path Based on the New
Narrative

31

The policy rate path
The policy rate path (63 basis points) supporting our output,
unemployment and inflation forecasts is regime-dependent.
Unemployment and inflation gaps ≈ 0.
A Taylor-type rule collapses to a Fisher equation
i = r† + π e + ϕπ π GAP + ϕu u GAP = r† + π e
i = 0.63% and π e = 2% imply (i – π e) = –1.37%
Very close to r† = –1.35%, the one-year ex post real interest
rate on government debt.

32

The policy rate path

Source: Federal Reserve Board and author’s calculations. Last observation: July 2016.

33

Risks to the forecast
Fundamental factors could switch into new regimes, in which
case monetary policy would have to react.
Phillips curve effects:
 In our narrative, a strong labor market (low unemployment)
does not put significant upward pressure on inflation.
 A risk is that Phillips curve effects could reassert themselves
and drive inflation higher.

Inflation expectations:
 Low market-based measures are at odds with our forecast.

Asset price bubbles are not addressed in this framework.

34

Conclusion

St. Louis Fed’s characterization of the macro outlook
r† = real rate of return on short-term government debt
λ = productivity growth
High λ
High r †

Low λ

Upside risk to the
policy rate path

High λ
Start

No recession

Recession

Low r †

Low λ

Baseline forecast

36

Conclusion
The projected policy rate path is the main difference in the
new approach.
 For other variables, the St. Louis Fed’s forecast under the new
approach is similar to private-sector forecasts.

Old narrative:
 Relatively steep policy rate path, dictated by convergence to
the single, long-run steady state.

New narrative:
 Flat policy rate path, conditional on the current regime.
 If a regime switch does occur, the policy rate path would have
to change appropriately—it remains data-dependent.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
stlouisfed.org
Follow us on Twitter
twitter.com/stlouisfed
Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED)
fred.stlouisfed.org
James Bullard
research.stlouisfed.org/econ/bullard/