View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Search Site
Home > James Bullard, President and CEO > James Bullard - Speeches, Presentations and Commentary >

Dial "M" for Monetary Policy
From the President
Key Policy Papers
Speeches, Presentations
and Commentary

February 17, 2009
New York Association for Business Economics, Harvard
Club of New York, New York

Research Papers
Media Interviews

*I appreciate assistance and comments provided by my
colleagues at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Robert
H. Rasche, senior vice president and director of research,
and Marcela M. Williams, special research assistant to the
president, provided assistance. I take full responsibility for
errors. The views expressed are mine and do not
necessarily re ect o cial positions of the Federal Reserve
System.

Four aspects of the current situation

James Bullard
President and Chief
Executive O cer

According to the National Bureau of Economic Research,
the U.S. economy has been in recession since December
2007. Real national income held up remarkably well
through the rst three quarters of this recession—
especially given the ongoing nancial turmoil. But real

Bio

output contracted rapidly in the last quarter of 2008,
declining 3.8 percent at an annual rate according to
preliminary estimates. Payroll employment shrank
continually throughout last year, and the decline in jobs
accelerated rapidly in the fourth quarter and into January
of this year. At this point it seems likely that output and
employment will continue to shrink in the rst half of 2009.

Photos

There are several important aspects to this contraction.
First, the ongoing nancial turmoil has affected a broad
spectrum of nancial markets and institutions around the
world. The initial turmoil was associated with the downturn
in the U.S. housing market and the attendant increase in
defaults on a variety of mortgage products. But the onset
of a sharp recession has added to di culties in nancial
markets well beyond those experienced during the rst
year of the crisis. In the U.S., the U.K. and the euro area,
signi cant nancial institutions have failed, been
nationalized or received substantial injections of capital
from the public sector. Credit markets far removed from

Curriculum Vitae
Staff Contacts
IDEAS/RePEc Pro le

Videos
Subscribe:
Email alerts
RSS
"Rationally, let it be said in a
whisper, experience is certainly
worth more than theory."
Amerigo Vespucci

mortgage nance, such as those for commercial paper,
junk bonds, auction rate securities and credit default
swaps, have faltered or collapsed.
Second, during the fall of 2008 and into early 2009, the Fed
has injected an astonishing amount of liquidity into the
economy. As a result, the U.S. monetary base has grown
from $871 billion in August of last year to $1.73 trillion in
January 2009.(1) This undertaking has supported
domestic nancial markets as well as domestic and
international nancial institutions. Support for dollar
funding markets has been provided through swap
operations with foreign central banks(2)—an increase of
more than $400 billion from the end of September 2007 to
the end of January 2009.
Third, the current recession is a global phenomenon.
Growth has slowed appreciably or turned negative in many
industrial countries, including the euro area, the U.K. and
Japan. Even Chinese growth has been signi cantly
affected as export demand from major world economies
has declined. In part, this is because all economies have
been impacted by the dramatic run-up of commodity and
particularly energy prices in late 2007 and the rst half of
2008 and by the subsequent decline in the second half of
2008.
The fourth aspect is the zero bound on nominal interest
rates. Central bankers around the world have responded
aggressively to the ongoing nancial turmoil and the
associated contraction in economic activity. The FOMC
acted preemptively with a 50-basis-point reduction in the
intended federal funds rate in September 2007 followed by
an additional 75-basis-point reduction in January 2008. In
December the Committee set a range for the federal funds
rate target of zero to 25 basis points, effectively reaching
the zero lower bound. Central banks of other major
industrial countries started reducing their targets for policy
rates later than the FOMC did and most have not yet
reached the zero lower bound. Still, policy rates have been
moving lower worldwide. I believe it is fair to conclude that
we are entering an extended period of exceptionally low
policy rates globally. In the United States, the setting of
nominal interest rate targets as a monetary policy tool will
be off the table for some time. In this environment the
implementation of monetary policy has to be refocused.
The new focus should be on quantitative measures of
policy.
In my remarks today, I will lay out a three-part thesis that
takes these facts as a starting point.
In the rst component, I will argue that a key near-term risk
for 2009 is further disin ation and possibly de ation.
Expectations of de ation for the next ve years may feed
into real interest rates, driving real rates higher just at the
time monetary policy would like to move them lower. The

zero bound is constraining ordinary policy responses to
this situation, making things worse.
In the second component, I will argue that because of the
special circumstances in which we nd ourselves,
monetary policy should focus more squarely on
quantitative measures, beginning with the monetary base,
to get some idea of the thrust of policy with respect to
in ation. I stress that I would not recommend this
approach in normal circumstances, as I think nominal
interest rate targeting works well in more ordinary times. It
is just that today's economy is operating far from its
normal routine.
In the third component, I will consider the Fed's balance
sheet. There I will stress that while the monetary base has
expanded at an extraordinarily fast pace during the fall and
winter, much of that expansion has been closely related to
the Fed's lender-of-last-resort function, and cannot be
counted on to keep expectations of disin ation and
de ation at bay. Because of this, the Fed needs a more
systematic method of keeping the persistent component of
monetary base growth rates elevated in order to combat
the risk of a de ationary trap. Two aggressive programs
have been put in place that may help to meet this objective:
outright open market purchases of agency debt and
agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and an
expanded Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility
(TALF). But the strategies behind these programs have
often been described in terms of the possible impact on
speci c markets. While the programs may help, we remain
far from the systematic approach I would like to see.
The risk of further disin ation and a possible de ationary
trap
Let me turn now to the rst part of the thesis: that the
primary near-term risk for monetary policy is continued
disin ation and a possible de ationary trap. Core personal
consumption expenditures (PCE) in ation has been
negative during each of the last three months of 2008—in
December, the rate was about minus three-tenths of one
percent. The readings for the core consumer price index
(CPI) in ation during these three months were similar, near
zero to slightly negative. It is true that measured from one
year ago, core PCE and core CPI in ation have not yet
turned negative, but given the sharp drop-off in real activity
at the end of 2008, it may be unwise to focus solely on the
measures from one year ago at this juncture. I think it is
reasonable to say that core in ation is running at zero to
slightly negative rates at this time.
Further, the global recession promises to carry on at least
through the rst half of 2009. This suggests that there is a
risk that core prices may continue to stagnate or decline
slightly for some time to come. Should lingering nancial
turmoil continue to weigh on the economy and stretch the
recession out still longer, the zero or negative in ation

could continue through 2009. Over that time frame,
de ationary expectations could become entrenched. For
this reason I think we face some risk—at this point only a
risk—of sustained de ation. One important near-term goal
for monetary policy is to guide the economy away from this
outcome.
In some ways, our current environment parallels the
Japanese experience after 1990. The Japanese banking
system encountered di culties with "troubled assets" and
the intermediation system broke down. Eventually,
persistent year-over-year de ation was observed in core
measures of in ation, and average economic growth
stagnated. In Japan, policy rates have been below 1
percent for 14 years, and de ation was observed for more
than a decade. The ultra-low nominal interest rate,
de ationary outcome is sometimes referred to as a
de ationary trap. That is an experience that neither we, nor
the rest of the world's economies, want to repeat.
Ongoing de ation in the United States might be particularly
pernicious. Household mortgages are long-term nominal
contracts. Sustained de ation increases the real debt
burden of leveraged homeowners and can erode their
equity. With sustained de ation, the foreclosure experience
that we have seen in the subprime market could generalize
to a wider spectrum of homeownership. This is a
signi cant downside risk to macroeconomic performance.
In more ordinary times, central banks would have a
standard policy response to in ation rates falling
substantially below desired levels: namely, lower the policy
rate. However, the zero bound is constraining that response
in the current environment. To the extent that the recent
disin ation is re ected in the expectations of market
participants, it is therefore putting upward pressure on real
interest rates, right at the moment when monetary policy
would prefer to drive real interest rates lower. This is
counterproductive for stabilization policy. The question is:
What can be done to move in ation closer to desired
levels, given the zero bound?
Why monetary policy should dial "M"
Let me now turn to the second part of the thesis: that
monetary policy in the current situation should put
increased emphasis on quantitative measures, starting
with the monetary base. Conventional monetary policy has
come to be de ned as a central bank establishing an
effective target for a short-term nominal interest rate. This
has been incorporated in the recent practice of central
bankers and in textbook and academic discussions of
monetary policy. In textbooks, the nominal interest rate
target is derived from a relationship, or policy rule, involving
the long-term in ation objective of the central bank,
deviations of actual in ation—either observed or forecast—
from that in ation objective, and deviations of actual
economic activity from some measure of "potential

output." In actual practice the FOMC has been shown to
follow such rule-like behavior at least since the beginning
of the Greenspan period, though notable deviations from
the predicted target have occurred on occasion. After a
decade and a half, the private sector has become fully
conditioned to think of monetary policy in terms of a target
funds rate and predictable adjustments of the target rate in
a strategic or rule-like fashion.(3)
Under ordinary macroeconomic conditions, nominal
interest rate targeting can work quite well. But under
conditions where in ation expectations become highly
unstable, or change rapidly, this approach to monetary
policy is less feasible. Di culties in controlling in ation
expectations while using a federal funds rate target
provoked the October 1979 Volcker monetary policy
reform.(4) Under exceptional circumstances like the
present, with policy rates at or near zero, low rates of
actual and expected in ation, and a sharp contraction in
economic activity, central bankers lose their ability to use
nominal interest rate movements to signal to the private
sector. This has surely created substantial uncertainty in
the economy.
One danger of the current situation is that, because the
interest rate signal mechanism has been turned off,
medium-term in ation expectations of the private sector
can begin to drift, possibly toward a de ationary trap. In
particular, once the zero lower bound is encountered, there
is no conventional Fed policy tool—no nominal interest rate
move—that will head off in ation that is "too low."
To avoid the risk of de ation, it is important that the Fed
provide a credible nominal anchor for the economy. One
way to do so is to set quantitative targets for monetary
policy, beginning with the growth rate of the monetary
base. This has several advantages. First and foremost, the
monetary base is relatively easy to understand, fostering
better communication about the thrust of monetary policy.
Second, we can be fairly certain that rapid expansion of the
monetary base will be su cient to head off any incipient
de ationary threat. Rapid base growth has been
associated with in ation in a wide variety of times and
places in economic history.
One important disadvantage is that the linkages between
the growth rate of the monetary base and key
macroeconomic variables are not statistically tight. It is
di cult to be as precise as we would like about the impact
on the economy from a given increase in the base. We
know this from wide-ranging earlier debates on monetary
targeting during the 1980s and 1990s. One reason the
linkages are not tight is that the monetary base has been
left to be determined as a residual to the interest rate
policy. In part as a result, the world's central banks focused
almost exclusively on nominal interest rate targeting more
or less en masse beginning in the 1990s. And, to be sure, I

recognize this, and I would not recommend a base
targeting approach in normal times. The move toward
quantitative measures of monetary policy is a
consequence of the zero lower bound and the
exceptionally weak state of the economy.
While the statistical relationships may be less precise than
in the case of nominal interest rate targeting, the effects
are unmistakable and every bit as powerful. The fact that
short-term nominal interest rates are at zero in no way
inhibits money creation and its in ationary consequences.
This channel can be used to support the Committee's
medium-term in ation objective and head off a possible
global de ation trap and the counterproductive rise in real
interest rates that would accompany that outcome.
Examining the balance sheet
Let me now turn to a discussion of the Fed's balance sheet.
Astute listeners will note that I said earlier that the amount
of liquidity injected into the economy since September
2008 has been astonishing, and that, in fact, the monetary
base has more than doubled during this period. However, I
now want to divide the increase in the size of the balance
sheet into two components, one temporary and one
persistent. The temporary component is presently very
large and is associated with the lender-of-last-resort
function of monetary policy. This component is unlikely to
have important in ationary effects as currently
implemented. The persistent component is presently
smaller and is associated with outright open market
purchases of agency debt and agency MBS. This program
may have greater in ationary consequences going forward,
and; so, may help the FOMC achieve medium-term in ation
objectives and avoid further disin ation or outright
de ation.
First let me talk about the temporary component.
An element of conventional monetary policy that is rarely
addressed in textbook and academic discussions is the
lender-of-last-resort function in a time of crisis. Historically
central banks have ooded the banking system with
liquidity by providing massive reserves in nancial crises or
panics.(5) Once the crisis is past, the liquidity injection can
be reversed. There are few if any in ationary
consequences of this type of liquidity injection. The Federal
Reserve response to the 9/11 attacks and disruption of
normal nancial market function is a great example of this
process.(6) Total reserves in the banking system nearly
doubled in the weeks following the attacks, but were
removed in short order. Something like the 9/11 response
is going on now, but on a grand scale and for an
undetermined length of time.
The current nancial crisis began in earnest in early August
2007. For more than a year into the crisis, the FOMC
continued to target the nominal federal funds rate in the

conventional fashion. The Fed also encouraged depository
institutions to use its lending facilities as appropriate. In
December 2007, the Term Auction Facility (TAF) was
created with the intent of encouraging bank borrowing by
circumventing any "stigma" associated with the primary
credit facility. Simultaneously, the Fed established
temporary swap lines with some foreign central banks to
help ease conditions in dollar funding markets globally.
The effective federal funds rate was maintained close to
the intended target rate by sterilization of the effect of
increased Fed lending on the monetary base. Initially the
sterilization was accomplished by open market sales from
the System Open Market Account (SOMA) portfolio and,
subsequently, by substantial increases in Treasury
balances at the Fed in the Supplementary Financing
Account. Monetary policy proceeded in the conventional
fashion—targeting a nominal interest rate—despite
substantial liquidity injections.
When nancial market turmoil intensi ed in September
2008, the Fed response—hardly unconventional—was to
ood the banking system with reserves. In fact, as I have
stressed, this is the normal central bank response to
severe nancial market distress such as that experienced
in 1998 or 2001. However, the scale of the response this
past fall dwarfed that of these earlier events, and the crisis
has persisted much longer than in earlier episodes.
These events have left the Fed with an expanded balance
sheet. The question is, how much of the balance sheet
expansion is temporary, being merely associated with the
lender-of-last-resort function in this time of extraordinary
crisis?
To keep the discussion simple, let us consider just three
programs that are currently some of the largest
contributors to the increased size of the balance sheet.
These are the CPFF at $251 billion, the TAF at $413 billion
and the swap lines at $391 billion, a total of more than $1
trillion.(7)
A critical element to the current liquidity injections is
reversibility: How quickly and easily can programs be
reversed or phased out, as is normal in the lender-of-lastresort function of monetary policy? The CPFF and TAF
programs score high marks on this criterion. Outstanding
TAF lending is under direct Fed control: The maturity of the
outstanding loans is 84 days at a maximum, and the size
and timing of future auctions are policy parameters. This
facility can be phased out quickly at any time it is deemed
appropriate. The Commercial Paper Funding Facility deals
in short-term money market instruments and can also be
phased out, if desired, in a short period of time. Indeed, as
elevated risk aversion recedes and market functioning
improves, the use of this facility may atrophy naturally. The
duration of swap-line programs is somewhat more
problematic. While all temporary swap lines have sunset

dates, phasing them out cannot realistically be done
unilaterally by the Fed, but will require discussion with the
foreign central banks involved. Still, the swap lines are
clearly intended for temporary use.
Now suppose that the especially severe market stress of
the past several months was to recede in such a way that
the size of these three programs falls to zero, without any
other effects on the remainder of the balance sheet. That
would actually leave the size of the Fed balance sheet
below the level of July 2007, before the crisis began in
earnest, and before any special programs were introduced.
It would be as if the FOMC had reacted to the nancial
crisis by shrinking the monetary base. From the
perspective of maintaining an expansion of the monetary
base to ward off a de ationary risk, these programs seem
to be a thin reed on which to balance medium-term
in ation objectives.
Now let me turn to the persistent components of the
balance sheet. To keep the discussion simple, I will discuss
just three items: The Fed's holdings of Treasury securities,
the agency MBS purchase program and the TALF program.
Fed holdings of Treasury securities in July 2007 were
about $800 billion. As liquidity programs were introduced
during the crisis, this portfolio was sold off, and it now
stands at $475 billion. This creates some room on the
balance sheet.
In November 2008 the Federal Reserve announced a
program to purchase direct obligations of housing-related
government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and MBS
backed by those GSEs. The ultimate goal of the program is
to purchase up to $100 billion in GSE direct obligations and
$500 billion in MBS. The purchase of agency debt is not
unprecedented: Historically the SOMA portfolio contained
agency debt, though these assets were allowed to mature
and were not replaced.(8) These outright purchases could
be viewed as, in part, a replacement for the Treasury
securities that were sold off earlier. Still, the targets for
these purchases indicate that the total purchases are
expected to exceed the earlier decline in Treasuries. Thus,
once these purchases are carried out, the balance sheet
would have expanded relative to the $800 billion, July 2007
level. The future liquidity of secondary markets for longerterm agency debt and agency MBS has yet to be
determined, and it is not completely clear that large
holdings of these securities could be readily sold back to
the market before maturity.
The remaining program is the Term Asset-Backed
Securities Loan Facility (TALF). Maturities of assets that
will be purchased under the TALF will extend up to several
years, and the current sunset date for new purchases under
this program is the end of 2009. This program is not
operational yet. The intent is to provide support to the
securitization process, which has broken down, and the

sunset clause indicates the temporary nature of the
program. The multi-year maturities of the loans and the
potential size of the program—up to $1 trillion—make the
impact on the monetary base more persistent than for
some of the other liquidity programs.
In general, if we are willing to think of the TALF as a
temporary liquidity program, then we are left with the
outright purchases of agency debt and MBS as the
persistent components of the increase in the monetary
base. These purchases are occurring on a su cient scale
to replace the previous sell-off of Treasuries and to also
add about $275 billion to the size of the balance sheet.
Unlike other items, this seems like a credible, persistent
increase in the monetary base, likely to feed into in ation.
Whether this increase in the persistent component of the
monetary base is of a proper size to mitigate de ation risk
is an open question. But one bottom line is that much
depends on how the various pieces of the balance sheet
are viewed.
Let me turn now to some brief conclusions.
Conclusions
Presently, macroeconomic expectations are very uid and
volatile. We know that expectations in uence
macroeconomic performance to a great degree, and that
providing a solid anchor for expectations is an essential
ingredient for any policy that will help resolve the current
stress. The fact that the target federal funds rate has hit
the zero bound has taken away the Fed's ability to signal its
intentions for monetary policy at a critical time. And in
particular, the Fed cannot lower interest rates further in
response to incoming information that suggests in ation
may be uncomfortably low. This makes the "M" part of
monetary policy more important at this juncture. By
expanding the monetary base at an appropriate rate, the
FOMC can signal that it intends to avoid the risk of further
de ation and the possibility of a de ation trap.
As I have discussed, the Fed's balance sheet has grown at
an astounding rate since September of last year, and the
monetary base has more than doubled. But the new,
temporary, lender-of-last-resort programs are blurring the
meaning of this picture. A temporary increase in the
monetary base, by itself, would not normally be considered
in ationary. The increase would have to be expected to be
sustained in the future in order to have an impact. Much,
but not all, of the recent increase in the balance sheet can
reasonably be viewed as temporary. The outright
purchases of agency debt and MBS are likely to be more
persistent, however, and it is these purchases that may
provide enough expansion in the monetary base to offset
the risk of further disin ation and possible de ation. The
quantitative effects of policy actions in this new
environment are more uncertain than normal, but
nevertheless these less-conventional policies can have

every bit as powerful an impact on the economy as
changes in the intended federal funds rate.
Footnotes
1. These gures are for the FRB-St. Louis adjusted
monetary base monthly series.
2. See Chairman Bernanke's testimony before the
Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of
Representatives, Washington, D.C. "Federal Reserve
programs to strengthen credit markets and the
economy." Feb. 10, 2009.
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090210a.htm
3. Various studies have shown that after 1999 nancial
market participants were rarely surprised by changes
in the funds rate target that occurred at regularly
scheduled FOMC meetings. See Poole and Rasche
(2003) "The Impact of Changes in FOMC Disclosure
Practices on the Transparency of Monetary Policy:
Are the Markets and the FOMC Better ‘Synched'?"
FRB-St. Louis Review 85(1): 1-10.
http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/03/01/PooleRasche.pdf
Intermeeting changes in the funds rate target
frequently caught nancial market participants by
surprise.
4. See Lindsey, Orphanides, and Rasche (2005) "The
Reform of 1979: How it Happened and Why," Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(2, part 2)
March/April, pp. 187-236.
http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/05/03/part2/Lindsey.pdf
5. See for example Richard G. Anderson, "Bagehot on
the Financial Crises of 1825…and 2008," Economic
Synopsis, 2009(7).
research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/09/ES0907.pdf.
6. Jeffrey M. Lacker (2004), "Payment system
disruptions and the federal reserve following
September 11, 2001," Journal of Monetary Economics,
51(5), July, pp. 935-65.
7. As of Feb. 12, 2009.
8. On Dec. 31, 1970, the SOMA portfolio contained no
GSE debt. By Dec. 31, 1979, it had built up to $8,709
million. It gradually ran down in the 1980s and 1990s.
On Dec. 31, 2000, it was down to $130 million and by
Dec. 31, 2003, it was zero.

GENERAL
Home
About Us
Bank Supervision
Careers
Community Development
Economic Education
Events

Inside the Economy Museum
Newsroom
On the Economy Blog
Open Vault Blog
OUR DISTRICT
Little Rock Branch
Louisville Branch
Memphis Branch
Agricultural Finance Monitor
Housing Market Conditions
SELECTED PUBLICATIONS
Bridges
Economic Synopses
Housing Market Perspectives
In the Balance
Page One Economics
The Quarterly Debt Monitor
Review
Regional Economist
ST. LOUIS FED PRESIDENT
James Bullard's Website
INITIATIVES
Center for Household Financial Stability
Dialogue with the Fed
Federal Banking Regulations
FOMC Speak
In Plain English - Making Sense of the Federal Reserve
Timely Topics Podcasts and Videos
DATA AND INFORMATION SERVICES
CASSIDI®
FRASER®
FRED®
FRED® Blog
GeoFRED®
IDEAS
FOLLOW THE FED
Twitter
Facebook
YouTube
Google Plus
Email Subscriptions

RSS

CONTACT US

|

LEGAL INFORMATION

|

PRIVACY NOTICE & POLICY

|

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM ONLINE