View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Demographics, Redistribution, and Optimal In‡ation
James Bullard

Carlos Garriga

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Christopher J. Waller
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

30 May 2012

Abstract
We study the interaction between population demographics, the desire for intergenerational redistribution in the economy, and the optimal in‡ation rate in a deterministic life-cycle economy with capital. Young cohorts do not initially have any assets
and wages are the main source of income; they prefer relatively low real interest rates,
relatively high wages, and relatively high rates of in‡ation. Older generations work
less and prefer higher rates of return from their savings, relatively low wages, and relatively low in‡ation. In the absence of intergenerational redistribution via lump-sum
taxes and transfers, the constrained e¢ cient competitive equilibrium entails optimal
distortions on relative prices. We allow the planner to use in‡ation to try to achieve
the optimal distortions. In the economy changes in the population structure are interpreted as the ability of a particular cohort to in‡uence the redistributive policy. When
the old have more in‡uence on the redistributive policy, the economy has a relatively
low steady state level of capital and a relatively low steady state rate of in‡ation. The
opposite happens as young cohorts have more control of policy. These results suggest
that aging population structures like those in Japan may contribute to observed low
rates of in‡ation or even de‡ation.
JEL codes: E4, E5, D7
Keywords: monetary policy, in‡ation bias, de‡ation, central bank design
This paper was prepared for the conference “Demographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance,”
sponsored by the Bank of Japan and the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, May 30th and 31st,
2012. The views presented here are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the
Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

1

1

Introduction

1.1

Overview

Can observed low in‡ation outcomes be related to demographic factors such as an aging
population? A calculation which we will label “back-of-the-envelop”(BOTE) based on some
basic economic theory might suggest that the answer is “no.” Suppose we think of the net
real interest rate r in a model with capital. We might guess that in steady state r = + n;
where is the net depreciation rate and n is the net population growth rate. Suppose we also
assume that money and capital pay either the same real rate of return or closely related real
rates of return,1 and that the real return on money is the negative of the net in‡ation rate
: Now suppose the rate of population growth increases to n0 ; creating a new steady state
with a more youthful population. By itself, this must mean that the real return to capital
increases to r0 and that the in‡ation rate decreases to

0

: This would seem to suggest that

countries with relatively young populations would have relatively low in‡ation rates, all else
equal, and conversely that countries with relatively old populations would have relatively
high in‡ation rates, all else equal.
However, the BOTE calculation does not seem to square with some of the facts. Figures
1 and 2 show two time series each for two countries, the U.S. and Japan.

15

42

11.25

40

7.5

38

3.75

36

0

34

percentage of population 15-40

y-on-y percent change, MA(6)

Figure 1: In‡ation and Demographics U.S.A 1960-2010

Youthful pop. share (right scale)
CPI inflation (left scale)
-3.75
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

32
2010

Moving average CPI in‡ation and the share of population
1

“Closely related” would apply to cases where the return on capital and the return on money were not
exactly equal but di¤er only by a constant, so that the two rates still move in tandem.

2

10

48

7.5

45

5

42

2.5

39

0

36

-2.5

percentage of population 15-40

y-on-y percent change, MA(6)

Figure 2: In‡ation and Demographics Japan 1960-2010

33
Youthful pop. share (right scale)
CPI inflation (left scale)

-5
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

30
2010

Moving average CPI in‡ation and the share of population
The years run from 1960 to 2011. A moving average of the consumer price in‡ation rate is
plotted using the left scale. A measure of the youthfulness of the population, the fraction
of the population aged 15 to 40 years, is plotted on the right scale. In each case, very
roughly speaking, the more youthful economies are associated with higher in‡ation, while
the more elderly economies are associated with lower in‡ation.2 This evidence, while far
from de…nitive, is at least suggestive and does run counter to the BOTE “standard theory”
calculation.
In this paper, we provide one reconciliation of the BOTE calculation with the suggestion
from the data shown in Figures 1 and 2 that aging populations are associated with lower
levels of in‡ation. The theory we study has all the elements of the BOTE calculation but
also considers the desire for redistribution within society. We model this desire as a social
planner’s problem in which the planner only has access to in‡ation or de‡ation as a tool
for redistribution. We show that the solution to the social planner’s problem associates
relatively elderly populations with relatively low in‡ation.

2

The mid-1970s moving average in‡ation rate in Japan is truncated at 10 percent in order to allow a
better view of the two data series.

3

1.2

Redistributional tension

In canonical macroeconomic models, the representative agent assumption is used to capture
the “average” behavior of key variables, including in‡ation. When using the representative
household approach, policy implicitly ignores the redistributive e¤ects of …scal and monetary
interventions. While it is possible to incorporate various forms of heterogeneity into canonical
models, attempting to understand redistribution policies for demographic reasons forces us
to abandon the representative agent framework and move to a general equilibrium life-cycle
framework.
Accordingly, in this paper we use an overlapping generations model with capital to study
the redistributional tensions associated with monetary and …scal policy. As in Bullard and
Waller (2004), in‡ation dictates the real rate of return on money and thus the portfolio
choices of each generation. Via a standard Tobin e¤ect, higher in‡ation can induce a substitution from money to capital. But why is there a tension across generations from this? The
tension can be understood by considering the decision-making of a given individual at time t.
A high wage rate at time t, which we can represent as fl (kt ), increases lifetime income of the
young cohort. In‡ation reduces the rate of return of money balances and individuals shift
portfolio decisions towards capital. The increasing capital accumulation increases wages of
young workers but reduces the rate of return on capital, fk (kt+1 ), for the older cohort of
savers. Consequently, young workers like in‡ation when they are young but dislike it when
they are old. Thus, if a single generation could choose the in‡ation rate at each point in
their lives, they would choose relatively high in‡ation when they were young and relatively
low in‡ation (or de‡ation) when old. Clearly, the generations existing side-by-side with this
one generation would not appreciate such a policy and would oppose it. Consequently, how
agents resolve this con‡ict between generations is important for understanding policy choices
and the institutional design of the central bank. Bullard and Waller (2004) considered three
institutional arrangements for resolving this con‡ict, among them a “policy committee”that
allows older and younger cohorts to solve a Nash bargaining problem.3 Their main …nding
is that the behavior of in‡ation hinges critically on key details of the institutional design.
The objective of this paper is to understand the determination of central bank objectives
when population aging shifts the social preferences for redistribution and its implications
for in‡ation. Our starting point builds on Bullard and Waller (2004), but unfortunately,
it is di¢ cult to follow their approach since it is not possible to specify the entire spectrum
3

Bullard and Waller did not focus directly on demographic e¤ects.

4

of institutional arrangements that could be implemented. We take a di¤erent approach in
this paper. Rather than specifying particular political decision-making rules, we use a direct
mechanism to decide the allocations. This means we will solve a social planner’s problem in
which the weights assigned to each generation are population weights. Thus, a baby boom
corresponds to putting more weight on the young of a particular generation relative to past
and future generations. This mechanism can replicate any steady state allocation arising
from a political economy model with population growth or decline.
For every level of social redistribution there exists an optimal level of capital. When the
young have more in‡uence in the planner’s optimization problem, wages are high and the
return from capital is low, and when the old have more in‡uence in the planner’s optimization
problem, wages are low and the return from capital is high. A critical feature of the planning
problem we study is whether or not the planner can redistribute resources via lump-sum taxes
or transfers. In the absence of lump-sum redistribution, we show that the planner might wish
to use in‡ation or de‡ation to change the relative price of capital to induce young households
to hold the right amount of capital. In general, the constrained redistributive solution is not
fully e¢ cient. That is, the implied level of savings is either too low or too high compared
with the unconstrained e¢ cient solution. In this sense, in‡ation or de‡ation will turn out to
be an imperfect substitute for a full system of lump-sum taxes and transfers.
We emphasize that in contrast with Bullard and Waller (2004), the unconstrained socially
e¢ cient level of savings is always dynamically e¢ cient. This is because in the unconstrained
case the social planner has access to a full system of lump-sum taxes and transfers. However,
the constraints on redistribution— the planner only has access to in‡ation or de‡ation as a
redistribution tool— behave as binding participation constraints that cause the e¢ cient level
of capital to deviate from the socially e¢ cient one. These deviations are due to the relative
importance of each group and the underlying distribution of resources.4
The mechanism presented in the paper follows the work of Garriga and Sánchez-Losada
(2009) , who considers the implementation of constrained e¢ cient solutions in economies with
warm-glow or joy-of-giving preferences. The rational for intergenerational redistribution is
always present in life cycle model that abstracts from lump-sum taxes and transfers. Garriga
(2001) shows depending on the relative importance of present versus future generations it
is optimal to tax/subsidize capital. Dávila (2012) uses a similar approach in a steady state
4

Judd (1985) considers a redistributional trade-o¤ between wage earners and capital earners. In that
economy the optimal redistribution is independent of the relative weight of each group in the social welfare
function. In terms of monetary policy, in that economy the central bank should set the nominal interest rate
to zero.

5

analysis to show that capital taxation can still be optimal even in the absence of government
expenditure. This mechanism is usually absent in economies with dynastic agents. Dávila,
Hong, Krusell, and Ríos-Rull (2012) also use a similar set up in an economy with incomplete
markets and uninsurable income risk.

2

Economy

2.1

Environment

Consider a standard two-period overlapping generations growth model with capital. Time
is discrete and double in…nity t = :::; 2; 1; 0; 1; 2; :::. Each period a number of identical
households are born, and population grows at an exogenous rate Nt = (1+n)Nt

1

where N0 =

1. Agents live for two periods and have perfect foresight. Young agents are endowed with one
unit of time that can be devoted to market work. These agents consume goods every period
and consumption bundles are compared using a standard utility function U (c1;t ; c2;t+1 ) =
u(c1;t ) + u(c2;t+1 ) where the utility function satis…es standard properties. There is an initial
old agent that consumes at t = 0:
This economy produces consumption and investment goods with a standard neoclassical
technology F (Kt ; Nt ). The production function has constant returns to scale and satis…es
standard properties. Capital depreciates at the rate . Output per worker can be written as
f (kt ) where kt = Kt =Nt . The economy aggregate resource constraint is given by
Nt c1;t + Nt 1 c1;t

+ Kt+1 = F (Kt ; Nt ) + (1

) Kt

(1)

+ (1 + n) kt+1 = f (kt ) + (1

) kt :

(2)

1

or, in per capita terms,
c1;t +

2.2

1
c1;t
1+n

1

The e¢ cient allocation of resources

Consider the allocation of resources determined by a social planner. The objective function
weights current and future generations according to
V =

1 u(c2;0 )

+

1
X

t

t=0

6

[u(c1;t ) + u(c2;t+1 )] :

(3)

The term

t

can be interpreted as the social discount rate and represents the relative weight

that the government places between present and future cohorts. Note that it is possible for
t

> 1 for some arbitrary generation t but for exposition it is convenient to assume that

discounting is geometric; that is,

t

1. The socially e¢ cient allocation of resources is

=

then the solution to a standard optimization problem
V (k0 ) = max

1
X

t

1

u(c1;t ) +

u(c2;t )

(4)

t=0

subject to
c1;t +

c2;t
+ (1 + n)kt+1 = f (kt ) + (1
1+n

)kt :

(5)

The objective function has been rewritten to illustrate the redistributive trade-o¤s between
existing old cohorts and the new young. A higher value of

places more weight on the new-

born and future generations, and less in the current individuals. The …rst-order conditions
of the optimization program imply
u0 (c1;t ) = (1 + n)u0 (c2;t )

(6)

and
(1 + n)u0 (c1;t ) = u0 (c1;t+1 ) [1

+ f 0 (kt+1 )] :

(7)

Both conditions are standard. The …rst expression equates the marginal rate of substitution
of the young and the old at a given point in time. When

= ; both individuals receive

the same amount of per capital consumption. When the weight on the young cohort is
larger, c1;t > c2;t : The second expression is the standard Euler equation but comparing the
marginal rate of substitution between a newborn in period t and t + 1 to the marginal rate of
transformation. Combining both expressions, the model implies the standard Euler equation
from the two-period overlapping generations model:
u0 (c1t ) = u0 (c2t+1 ) [1

+ f 0 (kt+1 )] :

(8)

In steady state, the allocation of resources perfectly separates the production process
(determination of the capital stock and employment) since the steady state stock of capital
k s is determined solely from (7),
f 0 (k s ) = (1 + n)
7

1

+

1;

(9)

while steady state consumption cs1 and cs2 solve
u0 (cs1 ) =
cs1 +
Since

cs2
1+n

(1 + n)u0 (cs2 )

+ ( + n)k s = f (k s ):

(10)
(11)

< 1, the economy always satis…es the condition for dynamic e¢ ciency. Note that for

the extreme case of

= 1; the economy satis…es the golden rule f 0 (k ) = n+ . Many analyses

of this model ignore the role of social discounting, implicitly setting

= 1; and maximize the

savings rate subject to the steady state resource constraint. However, this particular case of
the Pareto frontier is not useful for the study of intergenerational redistribution when the
relative importance of one group increases.
If one restrains the analysis to only steady state allocations, then (9)-(11) yield a unique
solution for any value of . It is clear from (9) that for

> 1, k s > k and the economy

has more capital than prescribed by the golden rule. This is the case studied by Bullard
and Waller (2004) who looked only at political economy allocations rather than a planner
allocation. It is in this sense that any political economy allocation occurring in steady state
of their model can be replicated by an appropriate choice of

confronting a social planner.

However, since we want to study the dynamic behavior of in‡ation following a baby boom and
bust, we cannot constrain our analysis to steady states. This forces us to study allocations
for which

2.3

1.

Implementation of the e¢ cient problem: Lump sum transfers

Markets can achieve the same allocation as the social planner. However, that requires a
transfer resources across cohorts using lump-sum taxation. The optimization problem of the
representative newborn is given by
max u(c1;t ) + u(c2;t+1 )

(12)

c1;t + st = wt lt + T1;t ;

(13)

subject to

and
c2;t+1 = (1

+ rt+1 )st + T2;t+1 :

8

(14)

The optimality conditions imply
u0 (wt lt

st + T1t ) = u0 [(1

+ rt+1 )st + T2;t+1 ] (1 + rt+1 ):

The optimal interest rate determined by the intergenerational discount rate can be implemented by shifting resources across cohorts at a given period t. That ensures that the young
cohort saves the right amount, implementing the fully e¢ cient solution. The market clearing
condition for capital implies (1 + n)kt+1 = st : The government budget constraint implies
T1;t +

T2;t
= 0:
1+n

(15)

This economy is not particularly useful, because neither …scal or monetary policy is used
to implement the e¢ cient solution. In the absence of redistributional policy this is no longer
true. In this case, the direct mechanism needs to respect the distributional restrictions
implied by the market. However, a constrained planner can internalize the impact of the
decisions on factor prices. This solution should be superior to the one in which the direct mechanism does not take into account the e¤ect of aggregates on factor prices. The
constrained e¢ cient solution implies a wedge in market decisions (for instance, in‡ation or
capital taxation). The optimal wedge (positive or negative) is determined by the social
desirability to redistribute resources across cohorts.

2.4

Constrained e¢ cient allocations: Ramsey

In the e¢ cient allocation, the social planner has access to lump-sum taxes and transfers.
Since the use of lump-sum taxes and transfers are rarely used in practice, we follow the
traditional Ramsey approach and assume that the social planner: (1) does not have access
to lump-sum taxes and transfers and (2) faces the same market prices as agents. This
assumption implies that the only way to increase consumption for a given cohort is to
manipulate the incentives to save and the implied relative prices. By taking into account
the e¤ects on relative prices the planner does not need to manipulate the allocations that
much. Consider
V (k0 ) = max

1
X

t

1

u(c1;t ) +

u(c2;t )

(16)

t=0

subject to
c1;t = fl

st 1
1+n
9

l

st ;

(17)

and
c2;t = 1

st 1
1+n

+ fk

(18)

st 1 ;

where (1 + n)kt+1 = st . This optimization problem is equivalent to the Ramsey problems
described in Garriga (2001) when the government expenditure is set equal to zero, or to the
steady state analysis when the planner faces no intergenerational con‡ict,

= 1, as in Davila

(2012).
Let

1;t

and

2;t

represent the Lagrange multipliers of the distributional constraints (17)

and (18) respectively. It is important to stress that each resource constraint e¤ectively
provides an entitlement for each individual and thus

1;t

and

2;t

are endogenous weights

a¤ecting the distribution of resources. The …rst-order conditions of this problem for every
period t yield

u0 (c1;t )
(1 + n)
=
0
u (c2;t )

The endogenous weights are the same

1;t

=

2;t

1;t

(19)

:

2;t

only if the planner does not have redistri-

butional con‡icts. When a particular cohort controls more resources, its endogenous weight
is lower making it easier to transfer resources from that cohort to the other. In short, intergenerational redistribution trades o¤ the relative importance of each cohort, , with the
cohort’s ownership of resources, .
The intergenerational decision of savings (capital) is more complicated:

1;t

=

1;t+1 fl;k

st 1
1+n

l
+
1+n

2;t+1

1

+ fk

st 1
1+n

+ fk;k

st 1
1+n

st
: (20)
1+n

An increase in savings reduces consumption of the current generation c1;t . The additional
savings (1) increases future consumption of the generation that saves the resources by the
marginal product of capital, (2) increases the wages of future newborn cohorts at t + 1, and
(3) reduces the future rate return of all savings. Replacing the multipliers implies
u0 (c1;t ) = u0 (c1;t+1 )fl;k

st 1
1+n

l
1+n

+ u0 (c2;t+1 ) 1
As

+ fk

st 1
1+n

+ fk;k

st 1
1+n

st
: (21)
1+n

increases, the relative importance of the young cohort increases, the e¤ect of saving on

future wages is more important, and the economy accumulates more capital. In the absence
of intergenerational redistribution, the only way to induce additional savings is to subsidize
10

capital.
This expression can be rewritten in wedges form
st
t 1
t 1
+ fk;k s1+n
1
+ fk s1+n
u0 (c1;t )
1+n
=
;
0
)
st 1
l
u0 (c2;t+1 )
1 + uu(c0 (c1;t+1
f
k;k
)
1+n
1+n
1;t

where fk;k k =

(22)

fl;k l: The constrained e¢ cient solution is fully e¢ cient only when fk;k = 0.

Otherwise, the e¢ cient solution implies an optimal wedge (positive or negative) in savings
decisions. The magnitude of the wedge depends on the relative in‡uence of each generation
in the planner’s objective function. Let
k

k
<1
fk (k)

= fk;k (k)

(23)

be the elasticity of marginal product to changes in the capital stock. If the production
function is linear or has constant marginal product the social planner cannot manipulate
prices. The other wedge is determined by

t+1

=

u0 (c1;t+1 )
fk;k
u0 (c1;t )

st 1
1+n

l
<1
1+n

(24)

Replacing the de…nition of the wedges in the optimality condition implies
1
u0 (c1;t )
=
0
u (c2;t+1 )

(1 +

To simplify, assume that the depreciation rate
u0 (c1;t )
= fk
u0 (c2;t+1 )

st 1
1+n

+ fk

(1 +

k
t+1 )

t+1 )

:

(25)

=1:

st 1
1+n

(1 +
(1 +

k
t+1 )
t+1 )

:

(26)

In this case it is clear that the relative strength of each wedge determines the magnitude of the
k

wedge (larger or smaller than one). The wedge
in the constraints in the economy whereas

is determined by the income distribution

is also determined by relative importance of

young cohorts versus the older ones.

11

2.5

Implementation via optimal wedges

The implementation of the constrained problem requires wedges and transfers within a given
cohort. The optimization problem of the representative newborn is given by
max u(c1;t ) + u(c2;t+1 )

(27)

c1;t + st = wt lt ;

(28)

subject to

and
c2;t+1 =

1

k
t+1 )

+ rt+1 (1 +
1 + t+1

(29)

st + Tt+1 :

This formulation does not allow for intergenerational redistribution— all the resources are
transferred within the same cohort. The optimality condition of the consumer problem
implies
u0

h

u0 (wt lt
1

+rt+1 (1+
1+ t+1

st )
i

k
t+1 )

=

1

+ rt+1 (1 +
1 + t+1

st + Tt+1

k
t+1 )

:

(30)

This formulation is silent about the tax instrument used to implement these wedges. Several
instruments can manipulate the relative rate of return of savings (for example, in‡ation or
capital taxation). To illustrate the importance of these wedges, we compute some numerical
examples that show comparable …ndings to Bullard and Waller (2004).

3
3.1

Money and capital
Pricing an additional asset

Since the optimal intergenerational redistribution determines the equilibrium interest rate,
we can also think about these parameters as the determining factors in an economy where
capital and money are perfect substitutes. Thus, the equilibrium return on capital pins
down the real rate of return on money and thus the in‡ation rate. In this economy, one can
imagine the per capita money growth rate evolving according to Mt+1 (1 + n) = (1 + zt )Mt .
The real rate of return on money is given by (1 +

t)

1

where

t

is the net in‡ation rate in

period t. Arbitrage then implies that
fk (kt ) =

1
1+
12

=
t

1+n
:
1 + zt

(31)

We do not explicitly model the reason agents hold money in this economy. Rather we think
of this exercise as being able to price an asset that is held in zero net supply. This is similar
in spirit to Woodford’s (2003) “cashless”economy.
Since the rate of return from capital is the same as money, it is possible to write the
consumer’s budget constraint as
c2;t+1 =

vt+1
st+1 ;
vt

(32)

where vt+1 =vt = 1 + n=(1 + z) = 1 + . Replacing the expression in the budget constraint
implies
(1 + )c2t+1 = st+1 :

(33)

The optimal wedge takes a di¤erent form, but it a¤ects the relative price of consumption.
Arbitrage between money and capital ensures that the economy implements the constrained
e¢ cient stock of capital. This model ties the constrained e¢ cient level of capital to the
implied in‡ation rate that would have to prevail to equate rates of return on assets.
It is important to emphasize that the optimal rate of in‡ation is derived from the primitives of redistribution and not the other way around. If we impose the arbitrage condition
into the planner’s problem, the optimal capital stock would be determined by z. In this
case, the e¤ects of savings in the stock of capital become irrelevant because the exogenous
arbitrage condition would determine the e¢ cient stock of capital, and the level would not
necessarily be consistent with the intergenerational discount factor :

3.2
3.2.1

Numerical example
Functional forms and optimality

The numerical example compares the solution of the unconstrained e¢ cient problem with the
constrained one. The objective is to illustrate the di¤erences in capital stocks achieved by
these economies and the implied redistributional policies. We consider individual preferences
of the form

c11;t
U (c1;t ; c2;t+1 ) =
1

c12;t+1
+
;
1

(34)

and the technology is Cobb-Douglas such that f (k) = Ak : For this functional form, the
unconstrained e¢ cient problem has a closed form solution. The optimal level of capital
depends on the intergenerational parameter . A larger weight on future generations implies

13

a higher capital stock and higher wages for the young cohort:
k ( )=

1

A
1+n

1

(1

)

.

(35)

Given the level of capital, the distribution of consumption depends on

whereby higher values of

1

(1 + n)

c2 =

as well
(36)

c1 ;

imply lower relative consumption for the current old. Finally,

the level of consumption for each cohort is determined by net output
c1 +

c2
= y( ) = Ak ( )
1+n

(37)

( + n)k ( ):

The constrained e¢ cient problem does not have closed form solutions and requires solving
a nonlinear equation for the capital stock, k, given by
[fl (k)l (1 + n)k]
f[1
+ fk (k)] (1 + n)kg

1
+ 2 Ak
=
1 + (1
) Ak

1
1

:

(38)

The parameters used in the steady state simulations are chosen to be fairly consistent with
standard macroeconomic aggregates, but the selection of the two-period economy is mainly
for illustrative purposes. Table 1 summarizes the parameter values used in the numerical
experiments.
Table 1: Summary Parameter Values
Parameter

Value
0:35

A

10

l=

1
2
0:99630

n

0:97930
3.2.2

Steady state comparisons

Given this parameterization, Figure 3 summarizes the optimal capital stock for both constrainted and unconstrained economies as a function of the parameter : The capital stock

14

is plotted as deviations from the e¢ cient level. There exists a parameter

for which the

constrained e¢ cient solution is optimal.
Figure 3: Capital Stock
2.4

Efficient
Constrained

2.2
2

Capital Stock

1.8
1.6
1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.6

Higher values of

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting(
λ)

1.3

1.4

1.5

imply that the constrained solution has an insu¢ cient level of capital

when compared to the e¢ cient solution. The reason is that as more weight is placed on the
future young, the current cohort must save more and reduce its consumption. This increases
the endogenous component
For low values of

2

and prevents the economy from achieving the e¢ cient solution.

the model predicts the opposite e¤ect. The economy is not dynamically

ine¢ cient in the classical sense, r < n + , but the market solution can have too much or
too little capital relative to the e¢ cient (dynamically e¢ cient) level.
The redistributional constraints have important implications for the cross section of consumption. Figure 4 compares the share of consumption of the young cohorts as a fraction of

15

total consumption.
Figure 4: Consumption Share Young Cohort
0.65
Efficient
Constrained

Consumption Young(%)

0.6

0.55

0.5

0.45

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting (
λ)

1.3

In the presence of lump-sum transfers, a larger value of

1.4

1.5

implies a greater share of

consumption for the young. However, in the constrained e¢ cient steady state, the relative
weight of old cohorts,

2;t ,

increases. As a result, the young cohorts’share of consumption

decreases. The reason is that the only way to achieve a higher capital stock is to decrease
consumption of the young. The absence of intergenerational transfers prevents increasing
both consumption and capital simultaneously.

16

Figure 5 shows the implied wedge consistent with the high savings rate
Figure 5: Optimal Wedge

Wedge (<1= tax | >1= Subsidy)

2

Efficient
Constrained

1.8

1.6

1.4

1.2

1

0.8
0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting (
λ)

1.3

1.4

1.5

In the market economy, young cohorts can only be induced to save more and reduce the
current consumption when the return from capital is higher than the marginal product of
capital. When the economy has too much capital relative to the e¢ cient level, the optimal
strategy is to reduce the return of savings of the old cohorts.
The notion of in‡ation or de‡ation should be viewed relative to the e¢ cient magnitude,
. It is possible to construct examples where the constrained e¢ cient in‡ation rate is
negative
of

< 0 or

we have (

> 0. The role of redistributional policy implies that for di¤erent ranges
<

) <

( ) <

(

). When population growth is positive the

>

equilibrium interest rate is always positive r = n, and the redistribution is accomplished
by changing the optimal rate of de‡ation z < 0. When the size of the population shrinks
(i.e., after a baby boom), then r = n < 1 and the e¢ cient rate of in‡ation can be positive
or negative depending on the distributional factor . Figure 6 summarizes the annualized

17

in‡ation rate implied by the model.
Figure 6: Annualized In‡ation (n<0)
x 10

-3

Efficient
Constrained
20

Inflation

15

10

5

0

-5
0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting(
λ)

1.3

1.4

1.5

In this economy, the monetary equilibrium implies r < 1; and as a result the crossing
line between e¢ cient and constraint implies

> 0: The relevant result is not the level of

in‡ation but the relative preference for di¤erent individuals in the population. This economy
illustrates the basic trade-o¤ between the young and old. The young prefer higher in‡ation
(or less de‡ation) and the old cohorts prefer the opposite. This trade-o¤ is clear in the
e¢ cient economy and the constrained e¢ cient economy, but the relative di¤erence in both
economies is due to the absence of intergenerational transfers. When the old cohorts are
relatively more important, the optimal in‡ation rate is determined by the size of the capital
stock. Ideally, it would be optimal to have more capital, but the young are the ones that
need to give up consumption to achieve the needed level of savings. Since this would violate
their budget constraint, the resulting policy implies de‡ation (redistribution towards the
old), but the magnitude is not as large as in the e¢ cient case because of the binding role of
the redistributional constraints.
The level of in‡ation depends on the growth rate of population. With stationary population, n = 0, the interest rate is always above one and the optimal in‡ation is always negative
as can be seen in Figure 7.

18

Figure 7: Annualized In‡ation (n=0)
Efficient
Constrained
0.01

0.005

Inflation

0

-0.005

-0.01

-0.015
0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting( λ)

1.3

1.4

1.5

The model also predicts that the young cohorts have a preference for a lower negative
growth of money, whereas the old cohorts prefer a higher rate of de‡ation. The quantitative
magnitudes depend on the parameterization, but the qualitative tension between young and
old cohorts is consistent with the political economy equilibrium of Bullard and Waller (2004).
The revenue/loss raised by the optimal wedge is rebated to the old cohort. Figure 8
compares the tax/transfers paid by the old generation for both economies.
Figure 8: Taxes and Transfers
1

Efficient
Constrained

0
-1

Taxation

-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
-7
0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Intergenerational Discounting (
λ)

19

1.3

1.4

1.5

For a given value of ; the e¢ cient economy always has more redistribution than the
constrained e¢ cient one. When both economies achieve similar capital stock levels, the role
of redistribution becomes less important, and the consumption shares of each cohort are
nearly the same.

4

Transitional dynamics

The steady state calculations are only useful to illustrate the static trade-o¤. By de…nition,
the young and the old cohort have to face the same prices. The current young might earn
a high wage today, but will be an old cohort tomorrow earning a low rate of return. In the
transition path the stock of capital changes, therefore, the prices faces by a given generation
at time t will be di¤erent to those face by the next generation at t + 1:
The intuition is clear from the Euler equation of the constrained e¢ cient problem
c1;t =

t+1
t

) Akt+11 ] + c2;t+1 1

c1;t+1 [(1

+

2

Akt+11 :

(39)

An increase in savings reduces the consumption of the current young c1;t ; increases the
compensation of the future young cohort, c1;t+1 ; via wages and decreases the return from
savings of the young cohort next period, c2;t+1 : Because the current young and the future
old are the same individuals, the relative weight

t

cancels.

The Euler equation of the e¢ cient solution is very di¤erent, but has the same economic
interpretation. The intergenerational redistribution is done directly, and as a result market
prices are not distorted:
c1;t =

t+1
t

c1;t+1 1

+ Akt+11 :

(40)

It is clear from the expression that an increase of the relative weight of future cohorts,
t+1 = t

> 1; will reduce consumption of the current generation (increase in savings) relative

to future generations. The increasing savings are sustained by intergenerational transfers.
A simple way to capture the e¤ects of demographic changes is to adjust the relative
importance of a given cohort in the social welfare function. When current generations become
relatively more important than future generations, the capital stock will increase. A higher
capital stock reduces the return of savings and it increases workers’compensation.
In the experiment we adjust the initial discount rate

so both economies start with the

same stock of capital. Therefore, the constrained economy is e¢ cient with an optimal wedge
20

equal to zero. The implied in‡ation is determined by the arbitrage condition between capital
and money. We consider two di¤erent sequences of intergenerational weights f t g: In case

1 the relative importance of young cohorts increases during a short number of periods. In
case 2, the high

is maintained during a larger number of periods. The di¤erence sequences

illustrated in Figure 9 summarize the behavior of the model in these two cases.

Figure 9: Intergenerational Discount Rate
Case 2: Persistent
1.6

1.4

1.4

Intergenerational Discounting
λ) (

Intergenerational Discounting
λ) (

Case 1: Transitory
1.6

1.2

1

0.8

0.6

0.4

1.2

1

0.8

0.6

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

0.4

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

The interpretation we wish to use is that the young cohorts become temporarily more
important in the determination of the optimal policy. The change is transitory and eventually
reverts back the initial level. The change in the social discount rate has implications for
savings and consumption. The initial steady state is no longer optimal at the new discount
rates f t g: The implicit baby boom generates a change in policy. To incentivize the savings

the rate of return of money has to decrease (this is the standard Tobin e¤ect in this model).
The implied policy generates a hump-shaped response from in‡ation.

21

80

90

Figure 10: Annualized In‡ation
Case 1: Transitory

Case 2: Persistent

0.015

x 10

-3

Efficient
Constrained

14
12
Efficient
Constrained

Inflation (Annualized)

Inflation (Annualized)

0.01

0.005

0

-0.005

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6

-0.01
10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

Figure 10 summarizes the evolution of annualized in‡ation along the transition path. Both
economies increase the in‡ation rate relative to the initial steady state. The persistence
of in‡ation is entirely determined by :5 Along the transition path the increase in savings
increases the compensation of working generations and reduces the return from savings
for the existing old. In the e¢ cient economy, the optimal in‡ation rate can be sustained
via intergenerational policy. The constrained economy has more limitations regarding the
transfer resources across generations. Market prices are the only mechanism for the young
individuals to save the right amount. As a result, the constrained in‡ation rate is lower
during the boom, but higher during the bust. The underlying income distribution between
wage earners and the asset-holding generation places bounds on the optimal policy.
The increase in the savings rate reduces the return from capital and increases the workers
compensation. Figure 11 summarizes the evolution of real interest rates as a percentage

5

The nature of the two-period problem requires an assumption of a high depreciation rate, and we used
= 1: Given that all the capital depreciates from one period to the next one, the dynamics in terms of
quantities per period are very fast. We think the same dynamics would hold in more elaborate general
equilibrium life cycle settings, but the computational cost would be higher.

22

80

90

change of the initial steady state.
Figure 11: Interest Rates
Case 2: Persistent
0.2

0.1

0.1
Interest Rates (% Change)

Interest Rates (% Change)

Case 1: Transitory
0.2

0

-0.1
Efficient
Constrained

-0.2

-0.3

-0.4

-0.5

Efficient
Constrained

0

-0.1

-0.2

-0.3

-0.4

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

-0.5

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

The path of interest rates is entirely driven by the sequence of f t g: In the constrained

e¢ cient economy, the optimal in‡ation rate is not su¢ ciently high to encourage a higher
savings rate. As a result, the interest rate does not fall as much during the boom and
workers compensation cannot increase to the e¢ cient levels.

5

Conclusions

We study the interaction between population demographics, the desire for redistribution in
the economy, and the optimal in‡ation rate in a deterministic economy with capital. In
the economy we study changes in the population structure are interpreted as the ability of
a particular cohort to in‡uence redistributive policy. The intergenerational redistribution
tension is intrinsic in life-cycle models. Young cohorts have few assets, and wages are the
main source of income. Old generations work less and prefer a high rate of return from their
savings. When the government has access to lump-sum taxes and transfers, redistributive
policy does not have to resort to distortionary measures (such as capital taxes, or in‡ation).
When lump-sum transfers are not possible but we allow the planner to use in‡ation or
de‡ation to achieve as much of the redistribution as possible, there exists a competitive
equilibrium with a constrained-optimal redistributive policy. The equilibrium entails optimal
distortions on relative prices that are necessary to achieve the constrained e¢ cient allocation.
When the old have more in‡uence over this redistributive policy, the economy has a lower
23

90

100

steady state level of capital, a higher steady state real rate of return, and a lower or negative
rate of in‡ation. By contrast, when the young have more in‡uence the economy has more
capital than the e¢ cient level, wages are relatively high and the market solution requires a
low rate of return from money holdings, that is, a relatively high in‡ation rate.
When demographics are changing, the constrained e¢ cient solution will entail an entire
transition path that will alter capital stocks, in‡ation, real wages, consumption, and other
key macroeconomic variables. In particular, a “baby boom”can generate temporarily higher
in‡ation, and aging population dynamics will put downward pressure on in‡ation or even
lead to de‡ation. This seems to be broadly consistent with the very rough evidence presented
in Figures 1 and 2.
In this paper, we have allowed a planning problem to “stand in”for the political processes
that society uses to make decisions concerning redistributional policy. Some more concrete
examples of political processes are studied in Bullard and Waller (2004), including a “policy
committee” that uses Nash bargaining to come to a social decision. In this paper, by contrast, the planner optimally chooses in‡ation or de‡ation to do as much of the desirable
redistribution as possible given that in‡ation or de‡ation only provides a partial substitute
for a fully operational lump-sum tax and transfer scheme. The society could use other types
of distortionary taxes to achieve similar goals, so we interpret the …ndings here as providing
an assessment of the marginal contribution of in‡ation or de‡ation in this process taking the
existing distortionary tax system as …xed and immutable.
Taken at face value, the results in this paper contribute to the debate concerning the
observation of mild de‡ation in Japan along with an aging population structure. The results
suggest that the aging population may be optimally associated with lower in‡ation as part of
the constrained e¢ cient equilibrium. We think it will be interesting to study this hypothesis
further in models that can more realistically quantify these e¤ects.

References
Bullard, J. and Waller, CJ (2004) Central bank design in general equilibrium. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 36(1): 95-113, February.
Dávila J (2012) The taxation of capital returns in overlapping generations models. Journal
of Macroeconomics, forthcoming.
Dávila J, Hong JH, Krusell P, Ríos-Rull JV (2012) Constrained e¢ ciency in the neoclassical
24

growth model with uninsurable idiosyncratic shocks. Econometrica, forthcoming.
Garriga C (2001) Optimal …scal policy in overlapping generations models. Working Paper
N. 0105, Centre de Recerca en Economia del Benestar (CREB).
Garriga C, Sánchez-Losada F (2009) Estate taxation with warm-glow altruism. Portuguese
Economic Journal, Volume 8, Issue 2, pp 99-118, August.
Judd, KL (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of
Public Economics 28(1): 59-83.
Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices. Princeton University Press.

25