View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

for Release on Delivery
(Approximately 1 1 : H a.m.
Thursday, October 7, 1965)

DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL POLICY
Remarks by Governor J . Dewey Daane
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the meeting of the
National Industrial Conference Board
The Waldorf-Astoria - New York City
on Thursday, October 7, 1965

DOMESTIC AND INTEP^ATIONAL_ DET_EmNANTS_ OF FINANCIAL POLICY

When I was first approached by Conference Director Worssam to
a

U

Ppear on this forum, he asked me to speak on the subject of "Reconciling

- S. Domestic and International Dollar Policy."

l

Somewhere along the

*ne this got translated by the Conference Board's machinery into the

title of your program, "Domestic and International Determinants of
Financial Policy."
tc)

But the program title and its subtitles referring

'credit policy and stable growth at home , "dollar responsibilities

abroad", and "alternative means for achieving policy goals" carry the
Sa

m e implication of a possible clash, perhaps even an irreconcilabilicy,

between domestic and international policy determinants.
In fact, in the field of dollar policy domestic and international
considerations are inextricably intertwined.

In my judgment it would

quite wrong to take the simple, mechanical view that improvement
the balance of payments and healthy expansion at home are alternative
£°als between which we must choose.

This view is no more justified

than the setting up of a rigid choice or trade-off between price
stability and reasonably full use of domestic resources.
im

Those who

a g i n e such unalterable trade-offs fail, it seems to me, to take

account of the fact that policies--both public and p r i v a t e — c a n be
adapted in new and imaginative ways to alter the terms of the apparent
ttade-off--or, to put it differently, to reconcile the apparently
^ r e c o n c i l a b l e , although I would concede that the task is easier
at some times than at others.

It is not my task to be a spokesman

the wage-price guideposts, but I have no doubt that this

- 2 a p p r o a c h — c a l l e d "incomes policy" in other countries — can, when adequately
reinforced by appropriate general monetary and fiscal policies, significantly alter what has at times in the past seemed to be an inevitable
relationship between rising employment and the generation of price
advances.

The mix of monetary and fiscal policies and the specific

instruments appertaining to each can b e — a n d I believe have b e e n —
flexibly adapted to be mutually supportive of our national economic
objectives.
The interdependence rather than inevitable conflict among domestic
and international economic goals and policies, and the results from
successful pursuit of mutually reinforcing policies, may be seen in the
current U. S. economic situation and outlook.

Today the position and

prospect of the U.S. e c o n o m y — i n both its domestic and international
aspects--are more favorable than they have been in a number of years.
On the domestic side, as you know, we have in 1965 achieved a rate of
resource u t i l i z a t i o n — o f both labor and capital — h i g h e r than at any
other time in the 1960's, and within striking distance of levels regarded
as optimum.

This achievement is the more significant by virtue of

having been, at least until recently, unblemished by any general rise
in prices.
On the international side I would also characterize our situation
as favorable for *easons well known to .this audience-. The fact that
we had a small surplus for three months is less significant than the
fact that we have demonstrated our determination, in line with President
Johnson's balance of payments program, to put an end to the long string
of deficits.

As Secretary Fowler pointed out this week the three month

surplus does not mean we have solved our problem.

- 3 -

Thus our challenges today--to maintain a healthy, growing, and
inflation-free economy and to maintain a viable balance of payments —
are both closely related and in many respects interdependent.

Whether

our price record can be maintained is one of the major challenges facing
the e c o n o m y — i m p o r t a n t both for its domestic and international aspects.
A

n d whether the actions we take to solve the balance of payments

Problem will continue to be compatible

with the continued healthy ex-

pansion of our own economy and of others around the w o r l d — i s a second
^ajor challenge.
In responding to these challenges, it seems to me that the financial
Policy link between domestic and international determinants may be found
in what I have termed the "Roosa categorical imperative", deriving from
last Friday's Per Jacobsson lecture by M r . Roosa; namely, that, on the
one hand, monetary policy has to be formulated with full regard for all
other elements of public policies and o b j e c t i v e s — a n d clearly this includes
balance of payments considerations and even international reserve asset
c r e a t i o n — w h i l e , on the other h a n d , other appropriate public policies
cannot ignore the elements of monetary discipline essential to the system.
Credit policy and growth at home cannot be divorced from our dollar responsibilities abroad, and both m u s t be considered together in achieving our
overall policy goals.
The rationale of interdependence between a healthy domestic economy
and a viable balance of payments is not difficult to find.

There are a

number of facets which I might mention but I would like to aingle out two.

_ 4 -

(1)

A vigorous domestic economy is essential for lasting

strength in the balance of payments.

The incentives created

by a strong home economy with stable prices stimulate the
installation of new equipment and the adoption of new techniques.

This means higher profit returns, increasing the

attractiveness of investment at home as against investment
abroad.

It also means keeping ahead in the competitive

drive to sell our exports.

Both on current account and

capital account, therefore, the vigor of the domestic
economy can affect favorably the balance of payments.

Of

that there has been ample evidence in recent years in
Western Europe.

(2)

But the compatibility--and over the longer run, inter-

d e p e n d e n c e — o f vigorous domestic expansion and a healthy
payments balance is based on the assumption that the price
level will remain reasonably stable as vigorous expansion
proceeds.

A reasonably stable price level, in my

judgment,

is crucial to both sustainable growth and balance of payments equilibrium.

It avoids a speculative scramble in

the allocation of resources with the distortions and
uncertainties that lower the rate of productivity advance,
and lead to the kind of deterioration in competitive position
such as the United States experienced after the mid-50's inflationary
surge.

It follows, then, that economic growth and relatively

- 5 -

stable prices are desirable from both the domestic and
balance of payments standpoints.

The balance of payments

cannot remain long in equilibrium if the domestic economy
is plagued either by chronic underutilization of its resources
or by chronic

inflation.

While domestic and international considerations are of necessity
interrelated they are not necessarily always related in quite the way
th

a t i s sometimes assumed.

b e

re

One misconception is that somehow there can

a n international liquidity escape route for the domestic liquidity

quirements appropriate to the maintenance of sustainable economic

^owth.
Set

In fact, as we look at our domestic policies in the current

t i n g there are two quite distinct and separate international problems

E l a t i n g to them.

The first is the problem of the adjustment process,

r

° the way in which we manage our affairs so as to eliminate the deficit
in

our balance of payments.

Parenthetically, I would state categorically

^ a t the adjustment process cannot be confined to deficit countries.
Su

r p l u s countries have to act too and perhaps seme should be reminded

0f

U . S. policies back in the days of dollar shortage.

The other prob-

lem we confront, along with other countries, is that of contingency
Planning to meet possible future international liquidity n e e d s .
Since Pierre-Paul Schweitzer will be discussing the international
m

°netary reform question with you this n o o n , I shall at this point simply

St

th

r e s s that these are separate problems.

I have been struck, however, by

e fact that much of the continental yearning for international monetary

^ f o r m , and new forms of liquidity, basically reflects a desire to

constrict the present degree of liquidity and in a way that w o u l d , as
they see it, enforce monetary discipline upon the reserve currency
countries.

To be b l u n t , it is no secret that some European observers

feel that our monetary policies in recent years have not been sufficiently
restrictive--that our ability to finance external deficits with the
dollar in its role as a reserve currency has exempted us from monetary
discipline.

Here at h o m e , on the other hand, much of the academic

and other clamor for greater international liquidity and for altering
the international monetary system reflects the idea that this would
enable much more expansionary domestic policies, monetary and other.
In fact, both notions are in my judgment misconceptions.

The answer

to the first charge lies in the continuous and increasingly comprehensive
efforts made to contain the United States balance of payments deficit,
beginning in 1960, broadened greatly in F e b r u a r y , 1961, accelerated in
r

nid-1963, and widened further in February of 1965--efforts which have

n

°t neglected actions in the monetary a r e a .

In fact, the latest

measures have h a d , and are having, a very direct and conclusive impact
bank lending abroad.
The United S t a t e s ' current willingness to explore new methods of
reserve asset creation does n o t , and cannot, reflect any lessened determination to achieve equilibrium in our balance of payments.

President

Johnson made this crystal clear in his remarks at the Bank-Fund meetings
this past w e e k .
v

Liquidity cannot replace dollar viability and dollar

i a b i l i t y rests squarely on the continuance of appropriate domestic

Policies.

But, as alx^ays, one must beware of the simple solution to the
complex problem.

There are some observers who state, with a kind of

evangelical certainty, that our balance of payments deficits of recent
years could have been cured overnight simply by tightening monetary
policy at home.

To these observers, the Federal Reserve overfilled

the cup and it inevitably overflowed into other countries.

All we

had to do was to turn off the credit faucet and the problem would
solve itself.

My own view is that our balance of payments problem is

m

°re complex than that simple diagnosis and, accordingly, calls for a

more complex p r e s c r i p t i o n — a prescription that attempts to recognize
both the needs of the domestic economy and the far-from-simple explanation of our balance of payments problem.
If deficits were experienced only by countries suffering from
excess demands and inflation, while surpluses accrued only to countries
w

w

i t h inadequate demand and unemployed resources, the policy problem
ould be relatively simple.

Fiscal and monetary policies would be used

to stimulate aggregate demand in the latter countries and to restrict
demand in the former (deficit-cum-inflation) countries.
As has been evident in recent years, however, the combinations of
domestic situation and balance of payments position may pose more difficult policy problems.

If a country in balance of payments surplus

tightens its monetary policy in order to deal with an inflation problem
a t

l t s

home, it tends to attract capital from abroad, thereby increasing
surplus and, in the process, increasing the deficits of other

Countries.
disease.

Thus the simple prescription does not always cure the
One response to this realization is an increasing recognition

that it is sometimes appropriate to try to alter the "mix" of fiscal

- 8 and monetary policies in order to cope with the existing combination
of domestic and external problems.

In fact, the existing mix of

policies may itself at times be one of the causes of imbalance in
international payments.

Two countries which are alike in all other

respects but use a different combination of fiscal and monetary
policies to influence the domestic economy will tend to have different
levels of interest rates, and capital will tend to flow from one to
the other for this if for no other reason.
The fact that balance of payments deficits do not always accompany
excess demand at home and surpluses are not always found in countries
suffering from deficient demand is simply another way of saying that
imbalances in international payments are not exclusively a reflection
of the degree of demand pressure in domestic economies.

Imbalances--

surpluses or deficits--often have more deep-seated or structural
causes.

I have just indicated that differing mixes of fiscal and

monetary policies may be one such cause.

An example of such a structural

problem is the tendency toward a very large capital outflow from the
United States to the rest of the world.

There are many reasons for

the strong tendency for U.S. capital to move abroad, and for foreign
borrowers to seek funds here, in large volume.

The United States has

the largest capital market in the world and the highest level of savings.
Equally important, our capital market and our banks are readily accessible
to foreign borrowers.

They are highly efficient and, until recently,

unimpeded by governmental restrictions.

Participating in these markets

are well-developed financial institutions searching for high-yielding
loans and zealously competing for customers.

These characteristics

-9differentiate our financial markets from those in other developed
countries.
For these and other reasons, borrowing costs have been relatively
low here and the availability of funds to foreign borrowers has been
great.

The result is understandable.

Demands for funds abroad tend

to converge on U.S. capital markets and on U.S. banks.

And the U.S.

institutions have, again quite naturally, had every reason to respond
to these demands.
To some degree, the lower cost and greater availability of funds
in the United States in the 1960's has reflected the differences in
fundamental economic circumstances between the United States and
Europe.
w

While Europe experienced excess demand, our domestic problem

a s to stimulate the use of idle resources.

But only a part of the

difference in credit conditions is attributable to this f a c t o r — a n d
it has diminished as our economy has moved closer to its potential.
There remains a significant part of the difference in credit conditions which must be ascribed to the structural factors that I have
c

3lled your attention to.

It has been both structural factors and

differences in the phase of the business cycle between Europe and
the United States, that have provided the motivation and the justification for the adoption in recent years of selective measures
to supplement general fiscal and monetary policies.
Those selective measures need little elaboration to this audience,
-hey have included, first, the meshing of Federal Reserve-Treasury
Polic ies to help maintain short-term money market rates in line

lb «
ihternationally; second, the investment tax credit and depreciation
allowances designed to encourage domestic investment in a way that
would avoid the adverse effect on international capital flows associated
with declining interest rates; third, a turn to the interest equalization
tax to narrow the differential in borrowing costs; and fourth, the
voluntary program, both bank and nonbank, to deter massive capital outflow.
Meanwhile, as these special selective measures play their role,
fiscal and monetary policies continue to be used actively to promote
a growing, inflation-free economy, the achievement of which is, as I
said earlier, highly interdependent with the maintenance of equilibrium
in the balance of payments.
Fiscal policy last year, and again in 1965, demonstrated its
power.

The heightened rate of expansion of our economy since late

1963 can be ascribed in no small part to the tax reductions of these
two years.

Meanwhile monetary policy has gradually moved away from

the more stimulating posture that was appropriate to an economy operating
well below its capacity.

This change in the mixture of monetary and

fiscal policies is quite in keeping with our balance of payments position.
X am not so sure that the mixes of monetary and fiscal policies
in Europe have been quite so appropriate.

In those European countries

needing to curb demand pressures, the tendency has been to rely heavily
on monetary policy--in some cases combined with an easing of fiscal
p o l i c y — a n d thus to increase the tendency for capital to move to Europe
and for Europeans to borrow abroad.

- 11 But I would not want to imply by any means that we have fully
unraveled the complex and difficult relationship between differentials
in interest rates, reflecting differing domestic requirements, and
undesired and disequilibrating capital flows.

Instead I would stress

fc

hat some of the solutions that may seem most obvious in terms of

changes in internal policy mixes are not necessarily consistent with
the complexities of the problem in terms of factors actually affecting
the supplies and demands for funds here and abroad, and the various
differing stages of capital markets.

Classical remedies have, in fact,

not been adequate to cope with this unclassical problem or "stubborn
dilemma" as M r . Roosa has put it of "the tendency for capital to flow
out of an economy which has relatively stable prices and high savings
toward those economies which block or impede the outflow of their own
capital, which have in any event a greater need for capital in relation
to their own savings, which are also often undergoing some internal
inflation and which thus offer significantly higher rates of interest."
In conclusion, then, I have been calling your attention to two
types of development in the continuing effort to adapt policies toward
Meeting the interdependent needs of our domestic economy and our external position.

One development is a greater flexibility in altering

the mix of fiscal and monetary policies.

The other is the use, clearly

as a supplement to more general policies, of selective instruments to

k/

R. V. Roosa, Thp PIarp of Monetary Policy in the Economic Policy
of the United States, Per Jacobsson Foundation Lectures, Washington,
D. C., October 1, 1965.

- 12 d

eal with struetural-type problems that affect the balance of payments.

Some of these selective approaches, clearly of a temporary nature,
r

ely on voluntary action.

affect market prices.

Others, like the interest equalization tax,

All such approaches, as well as general fiscal,

monetary, and debt management policies, need continuous examination,
innovation and adaptation so as to minimize their interference with
free markets while maximizing their contribution to a vigorous economy
and a sound currency, domestically and internationally.