View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery




Statement by
J. Charles Partee
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs
U. S. Senate
June 6, 1977

I appreciate the opportunity to appear before this
distinguished committee to present the views of the Federal Reserve
Board on H.R. 5675.

The Board strongly recommends the enactment of

this bill, because by providing a means for earning a direct return
on the Treasury's liquid balances it will materially reduce certain
operational difficulties encountered by the Federal Reserve in its
day-to-day management of monetary policy.
Until recent years, Treasury cash management practices
were conducted with a view to keeping fluctuations in Treasury
balances from influencing the supply of bank reserves and short­
term interest rates.

This policy, in effect, recognized that the

level of the Treasury balance is quite volatile because cash flows
to the Treasury— from taxes and Federal borrowing— tend to be bunched
at particular times of the month and year, whereas cash outlays are
more evenly distributed.

It makes a difference whether the Treasury

maintains its cash balance with private depositories or with the
Federal Reserve.

By holding most of the balance in tax and loan

accounts at commercial banks the potential reserve effects of
fluctuations in the Treasury's cash position were minimized.

When

funds moved to or from the Treasury, they simply shifted between
private and public demand deposits at banks and exerted little net
impact on the total supply of reserves available to the banking
system.

The need for Federal Reserve open market operations to

offset the reserve effects of variation in the Treasury's balance
was reduced correspondingly.







-2-

The Treasury did maintain an operating balance at
Federal Reserve Banks as well, on which the bulk of its checks
were drawn.

But as checks for outlays were cashed, the operating

balance was quickly replenished by "calls" on the Treasury's tax
and loan accounts at private banks.

In this way the Treasury held

a roughly constant balance with the Federal Reserve System.
Of course, some deviation in the level of the operating
balance was inevitable.

An accurate current measure of the volume

of Treasury checks written was difficult to obtain, and it was hard
to forecast exactly when outstanding checks would clear through
the Federal Reserve.

Nevertheless, the procedure was highly

effective in reducing the degree of fluctuation in the Treasury's
account at the Federal Reserve Banks.

Thus, from the standpoint

of minimizing the impact of swings in the Treasury's cash position
on the supply of bank reserves, the former Treasury tax and loan
account system worked well, and the implementation of monetary
policy was insulated quite successfully.
In 1974, however, the Treasury reexamined the tax and
loan account system, especially with regard to the foregone potential
interest earnings on its cash balances.

An earlier study had

concluded that the Treasury was adequately compensated for this
revenue loss by services provided by the banks.

But with the

general rise in market interest rates that had occurred during
the late 1960's and early 1970's, and the need to maintain larger
balances consistent with growing Federal outlays, it appeared that

-3-

the foregone interest income on the Treasury's balance had come
to exceed substantially the value of services rendered to the
Treasury by the depository institutions maintaining tax and loan
accounts.
The Treasury did not have the authority to invest directly
in short-term earning assets, and thus to earn some income with its
idle cash.

But it was assured of an indirect return when it

reduced its non-interest bearing deposits at commercial banks and
transferred the bulk of its cash balance to the Federal Reserve
System.

When the Treasury's account with the Federal Reserve is

increased, the System makes corresponding additions to its holdings
of government securities.

And since virtually all of the earnings

on Federal Reserve assets are turned over to the Treasury, this
transfer of deposits provides a return to the Treasury that would
not be available if the balances remained with depository institutions.
Unfortunately, this change in procedure has complicated
the task of managing monetary policy.

This is so because virtually

all of the short-run volatility in Treasury deposits now occurs in
the accounts held with Federal Reserve Banks.

Since variation in

the level of such deposits has a dollar for dollar impact on the
supply of reserves available to the banking system, the current
concentration of the Treasury's cash position in these accounts
greatly increases the need for offsetting Federal Reserve open
market operations.







-4When most of the Treasury's cash balance is held at
Federal Reserve Banks— as has been the case since 1974— increases
in the Treasury's account reduce the overall reserve position of
the banking system, and decreases ease that position.

Erratic

swings in the Treasury balance are often large and concentrated,
so that the Federal Reserve must take action through open market
operations to offset the unwanted influence on bank reserves.

The

need for intervention in the Government securities market on this
scale has sometimes made the conduct of monetary policy in the
short run more difficult.
A few comparisons will help to illustrate the significance
for open market operations of this shift in Treasury policy.

In

1970— before the Treasury began to alter its cash management
techniques— the average weekly change in Treasury deposits at the
Federal Reserve was only $124 million.

In 1976— after the new

policy had been fully implemented— the average weekly change
jumped to $2.0 billion.

Principally due to this enormous increase

in volatility, the average weekly change in reserves provided or
absorbed by the Federal Reserve rose to nearly $2.5 billion in 1976
from less than $400 million in 1970.
The shift is even more striking when one focuses on the
weeks of peak need to offset technical factors affecting bank
reserves.

In 1970, the maximum week-to-week change in reserves

resulting from open market operations amounted to just under
$1.2 billion, and the movement in the Treasury balance necessitated
only $130 million of this change.

By 1976, however, open market

-5-

operations added or absorbed more than $4.0 billion of reserves
in twelve different statement weeks, and in each case fluctuation
in the Treasury balance was the dominant factor requiring action.
The largest of these week-to-week changes required Desk intervention
totalling $6.0 billion.
To date the Federal Reserve has generally been able to
execute the requisite volume of open market operations needed to
offset the unwanted reserve effect of these enlarged swings in the
Treasury balance.

However, there have been significant difficulties.

The Treasury balance has become harder to estimate, large day-to-day
variations in the balance make it more difficult to develop a
consistent short-term operating strategy and the sheer size of the
operations required has at times constrained the System's flexibility
in pursuing the more general objectives of monetary policy.
The Federal Reserve's success in offsetting the reserve
impact of sharp fluctuations in the Treasury balance has been aided
by the availability of a relatively large market supply of Govern­
ment securities, as is typical of periods with relatively low
interest rates and low inventory financing costs.

As the economy

continues to expand, however, the picture could change.

If

pressures on financial markets intensify, Government securities are
likely to be less readily available in the market and a large volume
of open market operations may become more difficult to accomplish.




-6Thus, from a monetary policy standpoint, the Board
urges action on the proposed legislation.

Passage of H.R. 5675

would permit the Treasury to receive at least the volume of
earnings it is obtaining now without the present complications
and operational costs to Federal Reserve open market policy.
Moreover, there should be distributional advantages if the
Treasury maintains its balance with depository institutions.
Then, when balances shift between the private sector and the
Treasury, the supply of funds in regional and local credit markets
can remain unaffected.

If these funds are moved instead to and

from the Federal Reserve, there can be unsettling transitory
effects on individual credit markets, since the impact of off­
setting open market operations tends to focus initially on major
money market center institutions.
I have left all comments on the technical implementa­
tion of H.R. 5675 to Mr. Mosso, since he has direct responsibility
for administration of Treasury balances.

However, I would like

briefly to comment on one provision of the bill.

Under present

law, commercial banks, mutual savings banks and federally chartered
credit unions may all hold Treasury deposits.

Savings and loan

associations are the only type of depository institution not author­
ized to participate in the tax and loan account system, and this
bill would add them to the list.

In this connection, I would like

to point out that savings and loans typically hold a very large
share of their earning assets in long-term mortgage loans.




Since

-7Treasury operating balances are by their very nature inherently
volatile, it seems particularly important that the regulatory
authorities insist that these institutions add to their short­
term liquid assets in amounts commensurate with any such balances
obtained.




##########