View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

O
- J *v
Address by

tuttmL

O
Irvine H. Sprague, Chairman
I1
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

before the
National Association of Mutual Savings Banks




Marriott Hotel
Ci New Orleans* Louisiana

May 14 , 1979

In recent weeks there have been four actions —

one

administrative, one legislative, one judicial and one regulatory
_ which vitally affect the regulatory environment of mutual
savings banks and other federally regulated depository^institu­
tions.

I refer, of course, to the FDIC's decision denying a

branch approval under the Community Reinvestment Act, the House
Banking Committee's decision to sidetrack the Federal Reserve
membership bill, the D.C. Court of Appeals decision invalidating
automatic transfer accounts, and the proposal out for comment by
the regulatory agencies on small saver instruments.

I would like

to share with you this morning the FDIC's current perspective on
these major developments in banking regulation.
COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT ACT
As you know, in enacting the Community Reinvestment Act
of 1977 Congress concluded that:
(1) regulated financial institutions are required
by law to demonstrate that their deposit
facilities serve the convenience and needs of
the communities in which they are chartered
to do business;
(2) the convenience and needs of communities include
the need for credit services as well as deposit
services; and
(3) regulated financial institutions have continuing
and affirmative obligations to help meet the credit
needs of the local communities in which they are
chartered.
Congress further declared that the purpose of the Act was
to require each Federal financial supervisory agency to use its
authority to encourage financial institutions to help meet the
credit needs of the local communities in which they are chartered,




2
consistent with the safe and sound operation of such institutions,
and to consider whether such needs are being met when the agency
is acting on a branch or merger application by the bank.
While some may view these congressional findings as truisms
and others may contest the need for this type of legislation, the
Community Reinvestment Act is, nonetheless, the law of the land.
Apart from the law, I believe that most banks will agree that in
the long run financial institutions are only as sound as the local
economic environment.

It is a matter of self interest and preser­

vation to promote economic activities and growth within one's
local community.
Section 804 states that in connection with the examination
of a financial institution, the appropriate Federal financial
supervisory agency shall assess the institution's record of
meeting the credit needs of its entire community, including lowand moderate-income neighborhoods, consistent with the safe and
sound operation of such institution, and take such record into
account in its evaluation of an application for a deposit facility.
There is an affirmative responsibility on the part of a
financial institution to serve the credit needs of its local
community.

Since enforcing compliance with this requirement may

appear to some extent inconsistent with the FDIC's traditional
function of assuring the soundness of insured banks, there may be
some misunderstanding as to the perception of CRA by the FDIC.
I would like to clear the record on that particular issue, and
it can be addressed in three specific points.




3
First.
banks.

The prime provider of the nation's credit is its

In the case of mutual savings banks, the credit need to

be served is mortgage credit.

The Congress, in allowing mutual

institutions to have some advantage in the acquisition of funds,
expects these institutions to make a greater effort to meet the
mortgage credit needs of their local communities.

The Community

Reinvestment Act reinforces this expectation and commissions the
regulatory agencies to encourage banks to meet their responsibili­
ties in this area.
Second.

Congress, while recognizing the need to make

credit available, very properly enjoined that such need be met
in a manner "consistent with the safe and sound operation of the
institution."

It was not the intent of Congress to require

regulatory agencies to encourage financial institutions to make
loans which are unsafe and unsound. Any perception of CRA that
leads to the conclusion that it forces bank regulators to require
banks to make any and all loans no matter what the borrower's
credit standing is clearly in error.
Act is

The Community Reinvestment

an attempt to encourage banks to intensify their search

within their own communities for good loans which were available
but which in some cases were not being made for a variety of
reasons, including location, occupations of the residents of the
community, the perceived lack of repayment programs, or any other
of myriad reasons.

The posture of the regulators in carrying

out the will of the Congress cannot be construed as advice to
make bad loans, but it should be construed as encouragement to
make good loans which have previously not been made.




4
Third.

CRA is not an allocation of credit law.

It has

been suggested by some that this is a prelude to allocation of
credit by government fiat.

This is not so.

The law, as I have

previously described, allows banks to remain independent in
making their credit judgments, but encourages them to do a better
job of developing available, credit-worthy loans in their local
communities.
The regulation implementing the law recognizes the
differences in the credit needs of different communities.

It

urges bankers, as the best perceivers of those needs, to set
their own guidelines on reinvestment within their respective
communities.

The bank CRA statement clearly is intended to give

you the opportunity to take the initiative in defining your
community's credit needs as you see them and to say what you will
do to meet them.
The FDIC will continue to consider CRA cases on their
individual merit, as we do in all cases involving applications.
If the record is unsatisfactory we will deny.
satisfactory we will approve.

If the record is

The bottom line will be the

institution's record of performance with regard to its continuing
and affirmative obligation to help meet the credit needs of its
local community, including low and moderate income neighborhoods,
consistent with safety and soundness.
FEDERAL RESERVE MEMBERSHIP LEGISLATION
While the Federal Reserve membership bill appears to be
at least temporarily bogged down in the House and Senate banking




5
committees, there is always the possibility of a compromise that
will see this proposal reemerge as a viable legislative initiative.
It may well surface again this week in House hearings on trans­
action accounts.
We feel that the Federal Reserve should have the tools
it needs for the successful conduct of the nation's monetary
policy.

That prime function of the nation's central bank is

critical to the nation's economy, to the well being of our people
here at home, and to the maintenance of the value of the dollar
in international exchange.

To the extent that the Federal

Reserve is handicapped in its exercise of monetary management,
the nation runs a greater risk of runaway inflation or devastating
depression.
Traditionally, the Federal Reserve has employed open
market operations and the adjustment of reserve requirements as
its two major levers in administering monetary policy.

Now the

Federal Reserve is concerned that the erosion in its membership
is seriously undermining one of its two principal controls of
monetary policy.
The Federal Reserve further contends that reserve levels
serve as a benchmark against which open market operations can be
gauged and that the effectiveness of such operations is impaired
as reserve coverage shrinks.
There is no question that the drop in membership has been
substantial.

The Federal Reserve has estimated that the propor­

tion of commercial bank demand deposits subject to reserve
requirements has declined from 86 percent in 1960 to 72 percent




6
in mid-1978.

If there is no legislative solution soon, the

departures from the Federal Reserve could reach deluge proportions.
Thus, unless the banking industry reaches a compromise
with the Federal Reserve on this issue, declining membership in
the Federal Reserve seems destined to be resolved by "crisis
legislation."

While bankers can certainly block legislation in

this area this year, and probably longer, I believe that when a
large number of banks drop out of the Federal Reserve System and
the media draw attention to the problem, a public backlash will
develop.

From my experience, I have found that the only way to

mold good legislation is to be careful on an issue over the long
term, to obtain all viewpoints, and to obtain necessary checks,
balances and compromises and not wait for a crisis to develop.
ATS DECISION
Restrictions on the interest rates that can be paid on
time deposits, and the prohibition against payment of interest
on demand deposits, have been part of the American banking system
since the major banking reform legislation of 1933 and 1935.

The

origin of these restrictions is somewhat more complex than
generally believed.
The conventional wisdom is simply that interest rate
restrictions were adopted in response to our bank failure experi­
ence of the 1920s and early 1930s.

In that view, banks were

competing excessively on a rate basis, bidding deposit interest
rates up to levels that forced banks to acquire riskier assets
in order to meet their interest obligations.




Further, it was

7
argued, high rates on demand deposits, particularly on correspondent
balances, were a means by which funds were attracted to the
financial center banks from the rural and agricultural areas of
the country.

According to this rationale, these funds_were then

lent out with stocks as collateral and fed the flames of stock
market speculation during the late 1920s.

The problem with this

interpretation of history is that over the last 10 to 20 years
there have been a number of scholarly studies which do not support
the view that banks engaged in widespread excessive competition
to attract deposits in the 1920s and early 1930s.

The evidence,

in fact, suggests that deposit interest rates tended to decline
during the 1920s.
Whatever may have been the reasons initially for enacting
the prohibition of payment of interest on demand deposits, the
imposition of artificial controls on this market mechanism qave
rise to the development of ways to circumvent those controls.
Banks have avoided the prohibition against paying
interest on demand deposits by providing services equal or even
higher in value than interest payments would be if such direct
payments and charges for services were permitted.

For demand

deposits, the indirect ways for paying interest may become more
costly than the direct.
In any event, we all know that in recent years the
prohibition against payment of interest on demand deposits has
been progressively less meaningful with the advent of EFTS, NOW




8
accounts in some states, telephone transfer accounts, overdraft
checking and similar new devices.

Primarily

to accommodate

these and other innovations in fund transfers, the Federal Reserve
and the FDIC authorized, as of November 1, 1978, the automatic
transfer of funds from a depositor's savings account to cover
checks drawn on his checking account.

In practical effect, this

seemed like a relatively small step from the already permissible
use of overdraft checking in combination with telephone transfers
from savings to checking accounts.
Nevertheless, as we

all know, the D.C. Court of Appeals,

just three weeks ago ruled that the automatic transfer of funds
from an interest-bearing savings account to a noninterest-bearing
checking account violated the statutory prohibition against payment
of interest on demand deposits.

In related cases the Court also

invalidated the withdrawal of funds from a savings and loan
account via a remote service unit and the offering of share draft
accounts by credit unions.




In its opinion the Court stated

that the methods of transfer authorized by the agency
regulations have outpaced the methods and technolo gy
of fund transfer authorized by the existing statutes.
We are neither empowered to rewrite the language of statutes
which may be antiquated in dealing with the most recent
technological advances, nor are we empowered to make a policy
judgment as to whether the utilization of these new methods of
fund transfer is in the overall public interest. Therefore, we
have no option but to set aside the regulations authorizing
such fund transfers as being in violation of statute. We do
so with the firm expectation that the Congress will speedily
review the overall situation and make such policy judgment
as in its wisdom it deems necessary by authorizing in whole
or in part the methods of fund transfer involved in this
case or any other methods it sees fit to legitimize, or
conversely, by declining to alter the language of existing
statutes, thus sustaining the meaning and policy expressed
in those statutes as now construed by this court.

9
We recognize that enormous investments have been made by
various financial institutions in the installation of new
technology, that methods of financial operation in the
nation have rapidly grown to rely on much of this, and that
a disruption of the offered services would necessarily have
a deleterious impact on the financial community as a whole,
in the absence of the certainty that new procedures are
authorized for the foreseeable future, which certainty, only
a Congressional enactment can give.
...
It is the responsibility of the Congress and not the
courts to determine such policy.

In order to give the Congress time to act, the Court stayed the
effective date of its ruling until January 1, 1980.
The agencies are working on a court review of the Court
of Appeals decision; we may decide to go to the Supreme Court.

At

the same time, we are working with the Congress to achieve a legis­
lative resolution of this issue.

Chairman St Germain of the House

Financial Institutions Subcommittee has scheduled hearings and I will
be testifying tomorrow on a bill he has introduced to repeal the stat­
utory prohibition against payment of interest on demand deposits.
In order to arrive at a legislative solution, of course,
it will be necessary to traverse a sea of collateral
could prove to be very sticky.

issues which

Such issues might include the

Federal Reserve membership problem, Regulation Q and the differ­
ential, nationwide NOW accounts, expanded assets powers for
thrifts, tax equality between thrifts and commercial banks,
maintenance of a continuing flow of funds to housing, the status
of EFT facilities as branches, interstate branching, and reorgani­
zation of the Federal regulatory structure —

to mention only a few.

While it is much too early to chart a course through such
a treacherous sea as this, one possible compromise solution would
be enactment of a bill limited to authorization of the three




10

devices struck down by the Court of Appeals; viz., automatic
transfer and share draft accounts and remote service unit with­
drawals from savings and loans.

Another intermediate course that

might be worth considering would be the extension of NOW account
authority to all 50 States.
Whatever the final outcome it would seem to be a gross
understatement to suggest that financial institutions and their
regulators are in for an interesting legislative free-for-all
in the coming months.
SMALL SAVER PROBLEM
On April 3, the Federal regulatory agencies issued for
comment four proposals for actions intended to help the small
saver while at the same time preserving the safety and soundness
of the institutions.
To my knowledge, no one takes the position that the small
savers are not discriminated against.

The question is how to

reduce the imbalance.
We have received 1,014 comments, by far the largest
response in FDIC history to a regulatory proposal.

We now are

reviewing the comments and at the same time seeking to make
judgments on the effect of the various proposals in terms of bene­
fits to the saver, the effect on viability of financial institutions,
the impact on housing, and other factors.

We will do something to

alleviate present conditions, probably in the very near future.




Briefly, the April 3 proposals are:
1.

a 5-year certificate of deposit with interest

tied to but below comparable U.S. Treasury securities,

11

2.

a bonus savings account paying a 1/2 percent

lump-sum bonus a year,
3.

a rising-rate certificate with a moderate

early withdrawal penalty and an interest rate that
increases the longer the money is on deposit, and
4.

a reduction to $500 in the minimum for

certificate accounts, except for the $10,000 6-month
money market certificate, and elimination of all
minimum deposit requirements on certificates of less
than 4 years (now required only at savings and loans).
We are dealing with a volatile situation, keeping in mind
the experience with the $10,000 6-month money market certificate.
The regulators authorized it beginning June 1, 1978, and in 11
months it has attracted almost $147 billion in deposits throughout
the

nation, including $23 billion in mutual savings banks.

No

one can predict with absolute certainty the effect of the proposals
we now have before us so we must move with caution.
When we put our series of interim proposals out for
public comment, we emphasized that none of them are untouchable,
that we welcome suggestions on ways to improve the terms and
conditions of the proposals while maintaining the balance with
institutional soundness.

We have made it plain, for example,

that such specifics as maturity, rate, penalty or other terms
are open to change on the basis of public comment.

The package

we approve, I predict, will differ from the proposals put out
for comment.
None of our proposals is in any way intended to be a
permanent or comprehensive solution.




What needs to be done in

12

terms of an overall solution, in our judgment, is to phase out
Regulation Q and other interest rate controls, an action that
would have to be taken by the Congress.

We need to set a date

now for some time in the future, say, 5 or more years,_ and to
work toward it.

The ceiling would have to be eliminated gradually,

either by eliminating its applicability to certain instruments or
by providing for market based ceilings at different deposit
maturities so that the ultimate elimination of the ceiling would
be a minor event.
Thrift institutions would have to be given more investment
powers to provide additional financial services to different kinds
of customers, say, consumer borrowers.

In the process, we should

also phase down the differential between banks and thrifts and
eventually eliminate it.

We need to do everything possible to

prepare the institutions for the transition to a market-rate
interest environment and to encourage them to take steps toward
that goal.

The Regulation Q Task Force, set up last year by the

Administration with representation from the bank supervisory
agencies, has been looking at these issues.

The recommendations

are expected to go to the President this week.
In our effort to help the small saver, we cannot act
recklessly without regard for the danger of disintermediation or
the financial health of the depository institutions to which we
look for a stable flow of funds to housing.

In addition to our

housing responsibilities, we have the duty of cooperating with




13
the conduct of monetary policy.

Obviously, it is not unusual

when these various, major, differing objectives conflict.

Before

the recent acceleration of inflation and the rapid increase of
interest rates of the past 12 months, returns on thrift assets
were approaching the point where thrifts might have been able to
pay market rates on deposits.

However, market interest rates

moved to new, high ground and left the interest ceilings on
deposits far behind.

Under such circumstances, the elimination

of interest ceilings could pose a serious threat to thrift
solvency.

Thus, the present dilemma can be explained to a large

extent by the inflation rate and the recent run-up in interest
rates.
Before we acted March 8 to trim the compounding and
differential costs on money market CDs, our projections showed
that under certain sets of assumptions about interest rates and
deposit flows mutual savings banks would end 1979 in worse
financial shape than at any time in this decade

and that in­

cludes the 1974-75 recession, which many feel was the worst since
the Great Depression.
We believe our recent action helped stabilize the condition
of mutual savings banks, but it is obvious to us that we must do
more to help thrifts improve revenues or reduce costs if we are to
look to them for substantially higher payments to small savers.
The financial situation today adds a new edge to the question of
expanding the asset powers of thrifts.
The economic circumstances which prompted us to issue
the proposals for comment a month ago still prevail.




These

14
conditions remain today a clear mandate for the regulators to act
to provide some relief to small savers caught in an inflationary
pinch that has driven up everything except the government-controlled
rates of interest they may receive on their savings.
I

This is not to say that we are unmindful of the cost and

administrative burden on financial institutions.

We are very much

aware that whatever final regulation we impose must be thoroughly
justifiable and bearable for the institutions.
We will consider all sides of the issue during our
deliberations on the small saver proposals.
our opinion that delay is not an answer.




We trust you will share