View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

GOLD, THE DOLLAR AND OUR BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Remarks by
Hugh D. Galusha, Jr.
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

before the
University Club of Milwaukee

February 19, 1968

GOLD, THE DOLLAR AND OUR BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Hugh D. Galusha, Jr.
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Tonight, at Mr. Swanson’s suggestion, I am to talk about international
monetary developments.

This is almost impossible to square with our first con­

versation, when he warned me to stay away from serious subjects.

Not even Mark

Twain could extract much humor from the current situation, even though his
reference to a gold mine as a hole in the ground owned by a liar might have some
relevance to certain of the proposals advanced by proponents of an increase in
the price of gold.

But perhaps it is too harsh to characterize these proponents

as "liars'1 -- it may be simply an excess of "deGaulle" that causes them to be so
strident in their advocacy.

And they are correct, at least in concentrating

their attention on the barbarous metal, for it is the loss of gold from our
monetary stocks that has enlarged the area of our anxiety over monetary policy
and the U. S. dollar.

Why this loss has occurred and what alternatives are being

considered to alter the role of gold I will attempt to sketch for you this evening.
To give the appearance of logic to this talk, I should, I suppose, start
with a rational explanation of why gold is so highly prized in monetary systems.
I'm not sure I can.
analysis.

Attitudes toward gold are not susceptible of rational

Sufficient perhaps to acknowledge its entrenchment in all our in­

stinctive yearnings for a well-ordered and disciplined world -- coupled with
not unreasonable distrust of government motives.

G. B. Shaw summed it up

succinctly when he said:




"You have to choose (as a voter) between trusting to the
natural stability of gold and the natural stability of the
honesty and intelligence of the members of the government.
And

a.

with respect for these gentlemen, I advise you, as long as
the capitalist system lasts, to vote for gold."
I suspect, though, we no longer have the choice.
For example, consider our domestic situation.

We are projecting a

GNP of substantially more than $800 billion this year, none of which will be
paid for in the accursed metal.

We are on the verge of a checkless society,

when even paper symbols of the transfer of wealth will diminish in importance.
To cap it all, the citizens of this country, who are the wealthiest in the world
and logically would be the best customers for gold, are forbidden by law to own
gold bullion.

Finally, with the removal of the gold cover on Federal Reserve

notes, there will be no domestic link left in our monetary system.

Under these

circumstances, it seems unimportant whether the holes in the ground are full or
empty.
It is in the world monetary systems that gold still holds its ancient:
tyranny; but even for nationals of the developed countries of the West, the logic
of private purchase of gold as an investment is hardly a clear case.
is pegged at a fixed price.

Its value

Gold not only earns no income, but it costs somewhat

more than 6 per cent per year to hold.

True, there will be a speculative gain

if the price is raised, but the speculative values are hardly as measurable as
those inherent in the stock of a major U.S. corporation.

And the odds against

an increase in the price of gold are not diminished by the firmly reiterated
declaration of most of the major industrial nations of the free world that there
will be no change in the price of gold.

How credible are these declarations?

That cannot be answered without a close look at our monetary uses of gold; our
present monetary stocks of gold, the rate of consumption, and the alternatives
being discussed in different countries.




What monetary uses has our gold?

It has provided an inaccessible

cover for Federal Reserve notes; through the limited convertibility of foreign
dollar claims it has furnished what some argue is the major reason the U. S.
dollar has maintained its status as a reserve currency; and it has been the
means of settling part of our continued deficits in the balance of payments.
Because it is so much in our minds, let's start this analysis with a look at
our balance of payments position.
Table 1
The Balance of Payments of the U.S., 1958-67
(Billions of U.S. Dollars)

Exports of goods
and services
Imports of goods
and services

1958

1959

1960

1961

1962

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967**

23.0

23.5

27.0

28.6

30.3

32.3

36.9

39.0

43.0

45.6

-20.8 -23.3 -23.2 -22.9 -25.1 -26.4 -28.5 -32.0 -37.9 -40.2

Balance on goods
and services

2.2

.2

3.8

5.7

5.2

5.9

8.5

7.0

5.1

5.4

Remittances and
pensions abroad

-.7

-.8

-.7

-.7

-.7

-.9

-.9

-1.0

-1.0

-1.4

Balance on goods &
services, remit­
tances & pensions

1.5

-.6

3.1

5.0

4.5

5.0

7.6

6.0

4.1

4.0

-2.6

-2.4

-2.8

-2.7

-3.0

-3.6

-3.6

-3.4

-3.4

-4.2

U.S. private net in­
vestment abroad
-2.9

-2.3

-3.9

-4.4

-3.5

-4.5

-6.5

-3.7

-4.2

-5.1

.9

.3

.7

1.0

.7

.7

.2

2.5

3.9

.5

.4

-.8

-1.0

-1.2

-.4

-1.0

-.4

-.3

-.9

-3.5

-4.2

-3.9

-2.4

-2.2

-2.7

-2.8

-1.3

-1.3

-2.3

U.S. Govt, grants &
capital flows, net

Foreign net invest­
ment in the U.S.
Errors & omissions*
Balance on inter­
national accounts
*

Reflects mainly "hot flows" of funds.

**

Annual rate based on first nine months.

Source:




U.S. Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business.

- 3 -

The fourth quarter of 1967 saw a catastrophic turn in our balance
of trade.

It now looks as though the liquidity deficit for 1967 will exceed

$3.5 bi11 ion.
So much for our position:

what are we doing about it?

Because

of the continued drains caused by Vietnam, direct investment, and the limited
prospects of quick improvement in our current account, the President on the
first of January announced a program which is supposed to improve the balance
by about $3 billion in these ways:

by curbing direct investment, $1 billion;

by tightening the restrictions on lending by financial institutions, $.5 billion
by curtailing travel, $.5 billion; by cutting back government expenditures over­
seas, $.5 billion; by stepping up the encouragement of U.S. exports, $.5 billion
And the surtax, of course, is thrown in to curb final demand.
While I do not intend to enter into a discussion of the merits of the
program, its chances of total success are certainly questionable.

Not only are

parts of it dependent upon legislation, but it also assumes that there will be
no retaliatory measures by other countries, malicious or forced by circumstances
As to legislation, your appraisal of the news is as good as mine.
is hardly encouraging.

What about retaliation?

It

One of the few bright spots of

the last two years has been the extraordinary cooperation that has developed
among central bankers.

At least for them, the ancient wisdom of hang together

or hang separately has been heeded.

There is reason to believe they are sympa­

thetic to our attempts to remedy our deficit position, and are not contemplating
immediate retaliatory efforts, even though the areas of their anxiety will be
considerably enlarged.

Less certain is any assurance that central governments

will be all that cooperative to accept a trade-off of short-term losses for
long-term gains.




Cries for protection of "our" industry from "theirs11 have

always been a part of every country’s political heritage -- although muted for a
few years, these ancient tunes are coming back in style, and it's an unusual
politician who fails to respond when they are played loud enough.

Protectionism

is mutually reinforcing -- once the commitment to retaliate has been made, there
is no problem in finding countries or industries to retaliate against.

The

effect on world trade can only be disastrous.
A requirement that the U.S. eliminate its balance of payments deficit
as a condition precedent to a serious inquiry into international liquidity and the
roles of gold has the same immediate appeal to a belief in a world of rational
discipline as an argument for a return to the gold standard.

It assumes that

governments will confine themselves to an area of response determined by tra­
ditional monetary goals.

If you are in deficit, you contract your economy, in­

crease interest rates, and accept a higher level of unemployment; in response,
capital flows in, imports fall as the domestic market shrinks, and exports in­
crease as price adjustments make your products more competitive.

It seems to me

there are two very large reasons why this orthodoxy will no longer work If applied
by this country.
doxy.

First, we have officially and emotionally embraced another ortho­

Expressed in the statement of national economic policy of the Full Employ­

ment Act of 1946, we have pledged ourselves to a full employment economy.
Secondly, there is a response of scale among nations.

Because of our enormous

position in the economy of the world, changes in our domestic policies are
quickly reflected officially and privately in the economies of other countries.
It was one thing to urge upon France, in the early 1950’s, or upon England in
the 6 0 !s, that they should deflate their economies by whatever means to expiate
their financial sins, for the effect on other major industrial countries could be
compensated through conventional mechanisms without reproducing the same con­
ditions in their countries.

But it is quite something else for the U. S.

The

economies of the rest of the free world are immediately responsive to changes in




5

ours.

As has been pointed out a number of times by our foreign critics, we do

export inflation -- but it must also be remembered we export recessions as well.
And recessions have more political impact than inflation.

Our trading partners,

forced by their national interest to protect their balance of payments, respond
with changes in their monetary and economic policies that usually reinforce the
deflationary pressures set in motion in the U.S.

And some of these changes, like

devaluation, may be more or less involuntary reactions without alternatives.
It is at least arguable that our balance of payments deficit has been
less an international problem than a solution to easing the liquidity pressures
of our trading partners and the beneficiaries of our aid and military assistance
programs.

Of the increase in free world reserves ($20 billion), about 65% was in

foreign exchange.

Of this, 90% was composed of U.S. dollars, which reflected

that part of our deficit our creditors were willing to hold in dollars, which
has been no small contribution to world liquidity.
there is always a "balance11 of payments.
bookkeeping.

For the world as a whole,

It is simply a matter of double entry

For every deficit there must be a surplus.

If the President’s

aggressive attack on our balance of payments deficit is successful, then obviously
some of those nations in strong surplus positions will have to adjust their sights
downward, and some others will have deficits of their own to settle.

There is no

way of predicting how the adjustment will be distributed with any degree of pre­
cision, but if it corresponds roughly to our trading partners, the burden will
fall on Canada, Japan, the United Kingdom and West Germany, in that order.
Nations that have benefited from capital flows from this country will also bear
their share.
and Australia.

The principal ones have been Canada, West Germany, the United Kingdom
It might be speculated that like so many broad programs, the impact

will be most severe on countries least able to sustain it.
Nothing I have said should be taken as approval of continued and deepening
deficits in our balance of payments.




I have a fundamental distaste for financial

- 6 -

irresponsibility, and the word "deficit11 has unpleasant connotations for me in
any context.

What I am saying is that because of our role in the world, correct­

ing our balance of payments is not going to do much to solve the broader problems
of world liquidity.

A program to eliminate our deficit will force a readjustment

of reserves in the world, but it won't add any except as it may make dollars a
little more acceptable.

To start with, I am not all that sure the dollar is Ln

all that danger professed by some of the gnomes, who are not all in Zurich.

Until

some other alternative emerges for reserve expansion, it is still as good as gold
in most countries, for want of any other options.

Further, the number of dollars

a country will hold is regulated in substantial measure by that country's national
interest in financing world trade of its people.

An all-out effort by the U.S. to

alter its economic policies to redress the U.S. deficit may, in fact, alter foreign
attitudes about the dollar, and may indeed have a moderating effect on world
liquidity pressures; but fundamentally, I suspect, by reducing the level of world
trade and the need for expanding reserves however constituted.

In support of this

conclusion, which I must admit is contrary to an article of faith of many of my
betters,

let me explain.
As was pointed out by Messrs. Butler and Deaver of the Chase Bank in

an article on "Gold and the Dollar", which appeared in "Foreign Affairs" a few
months ago, "nearly one-quarter of world trade crosses our frontiers; we provide
nearly half the world's private foreign investments; probably more than half of
all international money transactions are denominated in U.S. dollars."
Given this position, it is less noblesse oblige than self preservation
to be concerned about the impact of our short-range economic objectives on the
rest of the world and the possible responses of other countries.

The possibility

of a return to a world of controls is not a pleasant one to contemplate.
Next let's take a look at gold stocks.
imperishability of gold.

And it is.

Much has been made of the

A substantial part of the gold mined

in the history of the world is still in existence; one authority has estimated
that all the gold ever mined could be put into a cube 90 feet square, or
about 100,000 tons.

Although the mining of gold has expanded enormously

since 1900, it has not kept pace with the liquidity needs and industrial




- 7 -

needs of the world.
sign of abatement.

Nor has the speculative desire to hold gold shown any
The two principal sources of gold for the free world

have been mines and Communist sales*-both of these sources showed a decline
last year.

Even more significantly, monetary stocks in the non-communist

world showed a net loss in both 1966 and 1967.

In short, all the gold

produced from traditional sources in the last two years has either gone into
industrial uses or has been reburied by hoarders.

Table 2
Supply and Use of Gold, 1953-67
(Millions of U.S. Dollars)

Year

New
Production

Russian Sales
to West

Net Official
Purchases*

Private
Demand*-

1953

845

75

455

465

1954

895

75

670

300

1955

940

75

665

350

1956

975

150

490

635

1957

1015

260

690

585

1958

1050

220

680

590

1959

1125

300

750

675

1960

1175

200

345

1030

1961

1215

300

600

915

1962

1290

200

330

1160

1963

1350

550

840

1060

1964

1395

450

725

1120

1965

1435

550

400

1585

1966

1440

--

-95

1535

1967***

1069

---------

-225

— —

*

Addition to monetary reserves of the non-Communist countries.

**

For industrial use and speculation purposes in non-Communits countries.

*** First nine months.




Our gold supply has been the principal sufferer.

From a high

point of $24.6 billion in 1949, our supply has dropped to $11.8 billion as
of a few weeks ago.

There are two channels of escape -- through central bank

demands from other countries, or through the London gold pool.
Let us start with the first of these.

Generally, the number of

dollars a foreign central bank is willing to hold depends partly upon the
quantity needed to finance the trade of its economy in dollar areas, partly
upon its assessment of the continuing value of dollars, and partly upon its
political interests as they relate to the U.S.

Because the U.S. dollar is

regarded as a reserve currency -- i.e., to be counted as a gold equivalent
in official reserves -- central banks have been willing to hold substantial
numbers.
For example, out of the approximately $64 billion of official
reserves in the free world at the end of 1966, $23 billion was in reserve
currencies -- either dollars or pounds.

And if from the $64 billion you

exclude the United Kingdom and the U.S., because their reserves have been
largely in gold, 45% of the remainder has been in dollars and pounds, but
mostly dollars.

These dollars got into reserves, as I said earlier, because

of our continued U.S. deficits -- deficits paid for only partially in gold,
the balance in dollars.

The reason most frequently ascribed to the willing­

ness of foreign central banks to hold dollars has been their convertibility
into gold at a fixed exchange rate; but certainly as important a reason is
the industrial productivity of the United States.

The capacity to pay debts

is at least as important as collateral, as every banker knows.
But it is not only the dollars lodged in the reserve accounts of
foreign central banks that represent a threat to our gold supply, but the
dollars that are in economic pipelines, such as in foreign bank accounts




- 9 -

denominated in dollars.

These totaled

17.6 billion

at

December 31, 1967 .

These dollars are held because they are truly the world currency, and are
essential to the process of trade.

Short of a total world-wide economic

disaster, there is no more reason to expect these dollars to be presented
as claims against our gold stock than for all of a bankfs depositors to
demand specie at the same time.

But their presence does pose a continued

threat simply because of their sheer size.
It might be useful to give you an idea of how these dollar claims
are converted into gold.

As you know, our Treasury will pay out gold only

to the Bank of England to restore the gold pool, or to a foreign central
bank.

A Frenchman who no longer wishes to hold dollars can do two things

with them:

he can exchange these dollars for francs or other currencies

through the French banking system, with the dollars eventually finding their
way to the French central bank.

The Bank of France periodically appraises

its stock of dollars against the demands of the French banking system for
dollars, and their own national interest.

If their stock of dollars is too

high--and unfortunately, they nearly always think so--they present these
dollars to the U.S. for gold.
For the non-official holder of dollars who wants gold, there is
the gold pool.

Here he can join the oil sheiks and others who prefer gold

to a currency--provided their own country permits them to own gold, which
may or may not be a deterrent.

The London gold pool is a consortium of the

larger industrial nations, now excluding France, who have agreed to use the
Bank of England as their agent to buy or sell gold in any quantity at roughly
$35 an ounce.

Periodically the Bank of England requests the countries making

up the pool to reimburse its gold stocks.

Our share now is 59 per cent.

Our gold loss last year through the pool and through claims presented by




-10-

foreign central banks amounted to $1,175 billion.
The pool is extraordinarily responsive to world conditions.

The

British devaluation and the war in the Middle East have produced the most
severe buying sprees; but in addition to these, like any other volatile
commodity market, the gold market quickly reflects the hopes and fears in­
herent in any infinite range of rumors.
happens to have a monetary role.

Unfortunately, this commodity also

For better or for worse (and occasionally

there is a better; although the pool has been a net seller, there are days
when gold can be bought by the pool), the monetary stocks of the major in­
dustrial, non-Communist countries, except France, are linked to the pool.
As I said earlier, central banks have developed remarkable patterns
of mutual assistance.

Official gold transfers from this country generally have

been less of a danger than the unpredictable surges in the gold pool.

Still,

though, the twin questions of price and access to our gold stocks remain.
How do we free ourselves from the inflexibility of the present
arrangements?

Of all the many proposals ranging from a return to the gold

standard to flexible exchange rates, one of the most intriguing is the one ad­
vanced by Butler and Deaver, those two economists at the Chase I quoted earlier.
I am not endorsing it, but let me describe it to you for its merits as one of the
more imaginative proposals.

Briefly stated, their proposal is to "clearly indi­

cate that we will never support a price higher than $35.00 an ounce even if other
central banks should use their dollars to buy all the gold in the U.S. Treasury."
To buttress this statement, the U.S. Treasury would make sales and purchases
only at that price, and at its discretion.

What would be the consequences?

It would be the end of the gold pool.

It would also mean loss of

control over the foreign exchange value of the dollar.




11

Instead of linking

these two commodities via the pool and the unlimited convertibility privilege,
they would be separated.

And separate they certainly would, especially at

first, for they would now be priced on their individual merits.

The contem­

plation of the confusion and dismay among gold hoarders is almost enough in
itself to recommend the proposal.
Dollar markets would be the immediate concern of central bankers.
If they were unwilling to accept the dollar standard, the rate might well sag
for a time.

But a sure limit would be the trade advantage given the U.S.

To offset this, there might be retaliatory measures of trade and exchange
restrictions, but as the authors pointed out, the resulting chaos would be
to no one’s advantage, and would be contrary to the responsible behavior the
European central bankers have consistently demonstrated in the post-war
period--behavior not always consistent with published statements.
The criticism that acceptance would be endorsement of permanent
U.S. balance of payments deficits does not follow either.

Instead of

requiring the U.S. to take unilateral steps to redress its position--steps
which are certain to cause them to wince--there can be a bilateral effort to
assist us by assuming a larger share of aid to under-developed countries,
encouraging expansion of their own capital markets, and by reducing some of
their tariff barriers.
I am sure there are holes in this argument--if they donft exist,
the argument will be changed by the critics to produce them.

As Paul

Samuelson once said, "Gold is to economists what sex is to biologists-except sex has far more real importance.11
The fact is, I suspect, the U.S. has to take the initiative in
freeing a complex and expanding industrial world society from the preoccupa­
tions with the price of gold, if we are to get on with the real problem of




-12-

making the present system of international finance capable of supporting
world economic growth.
So we come to the world monetary dilemma--the growth of monetary
reserves in the free world must keep pace with the expansion of world trade;
but with no substantial increase in traditional gold sources in sight, an
understandable reluctance to hold sterling, and a general unhappiness with
U.S. economic policy, which has made foreign central bankers uneasy about
dollars, the principal post-war sources are no longer adequate.
The fear that preoccupation with the balance of payments may
distract us from the larger considerations of world liquidity and gold is a
real one, I think.

In the crisis climate that now seems a permanent part of

our world, the relief that follows discovery of an expedient seldom has much
relevancy either to the enormity of the problem involved or to its long-range
solution.

The price for time gets progressively higher.
Any analysis of long-range solutions has to start with some history.

The Bretton Woods Agreement was the "great step forward1’ for the free world
in its attempts to move away from the rigidities of the pre-World War II
international monetary systems.

Out of it came the International Monetary

Fund, which was designed to accomplish these things:

1) to provide a source

of emergency credit for participating nations, and 2) to provide a mechanism
for the stabilization of exchange rates.

In its first objective it has

succeeded rather well, but the second objective succeeded too well.

Although

it is explicit in the framework of the Agreement that nations can make
periodic small adjustments in their exchange rates to meet shifts in their
currency relationships to other currencies, the prejudices of several thousand
years against changes in currency values were impossible to overcome.




A number of expedients were added during the next 20-odd years to

-13-

cushion surges in exchange markets.

Credit facilities were added through

the B.I.S.; swaps or guaranteed currency loans were contributed by Bob Roosa
along with special bonds for foreign central banks denominated Roosa bonds in
his honor; significantly, central banks of the major industrial nations of
the non-Communist world moved closer together for their mutual protection--but
until last summer nothing was done to enlarge the owned reserves of the free
world.

Then came S .D .R. 1s- - special drawing rights.

Although the label

carries a connotation of a credit instrument, this was only to placate certain
intransigent members of the I.M.F. who wanted to preserve the appearances.
They are much closer in a philosophic sense to an original proposal advanced
by Keynes during the Bretton Woods discussion for a new monetary unit than
they are to the credit portion.

Subject to a number of restrictions to

protect the I.M.F. community from abuse of the new units, the proposal
contemplates the addition in an orderly way of a new monetary unit to the
members* reserves--a unit to circulate on a parity with gold and dollars
among signatory nations for severely limited purposes.

The present timetable

requires ratification by the legislative bodies of the governments involved,
which may take another year.
of the membership is required.

Before any are issued, a vote of 85 per cent
This was one of the compromises to please

the French, and will assure a veto right to the Common Market countries.
How quickly they will come into existence, how receptive central banks will
be to them, are questions yet to be answered.
There are those who still feel the central uncertainty in inter­
national exchange markets will continue to be the role of gold--and generally
this means its price.

Again, doubling its price has the virtue of simplicity.

As the owner of the largest single gold stock, the U.S. would be the principal
beneficiary.




We could pay off our principal debtors and still have as much

-14-

as we have now.

Adjustments could be made to salvage our reputation for

financial probity on an ad hoc basis by supplemental payments to our special
friends.

World gold production would be stimulated.

So goes the argument.

In rebuttal, there are these points to be made:

1) Having maintained

repeatedly there would be no change in the price, the U.S. would have at
least as difficult a time reestablishing its credibility as the British
Government following devaluation.

2) While it would benefit us in the short

run, the benefit to France, the speculators, South Africa, and Russia would
be disproportionate.

3) It would certainly bring about a reallocation of

resources directed to the mining of gold, which in the present state of things
in the world should be of low priority.

4) It would be a one-shot expedient

when what the world really needs is a mechanism which will permit the contin­
uing adjustments of reserve needs.

We have the framework of this mechanism

in the I.M.F. and the ancillary institutions.

We encourage manufacturers

of things to continuously refine and adapt them to our changing uses; we
should be equally willing to accept the necessity of adaption of political
and economic institutions, instead of seeking always for the dramatically
new once-and-for-all solution.




-15-