View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
WEDNESDAY, MAY 22, 1985
10:15 A.M. EDT

OUR TWIN DEFICITS

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
ac the
National Conference of Petroleum Independents
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania
May 22, 1985

SUMMARY

1.

The U.S. economy is at the center of a tug of war between two

deficits -- the budget deficit, which expands demand, and the trade deficit,
which drains demand abroad.

2.

The trade deficit has been gaining on the budget deficit and has

slowed the economy.

3.

The outlook for the dollar is the major uncertainty overhanging

the American economy.

A strong dollar hurts American trade, but facilitates

the inflow of foreign capital,

4.

The best approach to reducing the trade problem is to reduce the

budget deficit, thereby reducing the need for importing foreign capital.

OUR TWIN DEFICITS

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
National Conference of Petroleum Independents
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania
May 22, 1985

The title of your session —

"Coping with Hard Times" —

shows

how in a large economy like ours different sectors can have very different
experience.

I can fairly say that the American economy in general is not

experiencing "hard times."

There are, however, some sectors that are not

doing well -- farmers, some heavy industries, exporters and import-competing
industries.

You are not alone.

A Tale of Two Deficits
Looking at the economy generally, it clearly today is being subjected
to a tug of war of two powerful forces —
deficit.

the budget deficit, and the trade

The budget deficit has enormously increased demand in the economy,

simply by giving the taxpayer more purchasing power.
propelling the economy for two-and-a-half years.

This force has been

Meanwhile, the trade deficit

has been building up slowly as our imports advanced while exports remained
feeble.

Draining away purchasing power from the domestic economy, the trade

deficit has been nibbling at the expansionary force of the budget deficit.

-2
At $120 billion projected for 1985, the trade deficit is still substantially
smaller than the unified budget deficit of $210 billion.
But aside from the fact that a simple dollar comparison is not
entirely valid, the trade deficit now has revealed itself as having a
leverage over the rest of the economy that the budget deficit does not seem
to have.

The trade deficit seems to affect adversely the inducement and

ability to invest in additional plant and equipment.

It does so by hitting

with particular force at the manufacturing sector, contributing to a virtual
stagnation of industrial production since the summer of 1984.

In good part

as a result, the rate of business investment, which in 1984 grew in real terms
at the spectacular rate of 20 percent, has slowed down to 3-1/2 percent during
the first quarter of this year.

The trade deficit slows investment not only

by holding down industrial production, but also by curbing business profits,
through intensified foreign competition.

The slow growth of corporate profits

makes the point.
The budget deficit does not have the same leverage over business
investment.

By stimulating consumer purchases, it does indirectly stimulate

investment.

Moreover, a moderate part of the budget deficit is the result,

not of consumer tax cuts and general increases in government expenditures,
but of the tax benefits made available to business through accelerated
depreciation and investment tax credits.

But the budget drives up interest

rates, although these have come down substantially from their peaks.

The net

result is before our eyes -- business investment has slowed substantially.
Recent surveys, to be sure, seem to indicate that other factors will tend to
raise investment again.

-3Other Factors in Good Balance
Apart from the shifting balance of these two deficits —

the

internal and the external -- the economy at the present time does not
exhibit the type of imbalances typical of late stages of an expansion.
We are now well into the third year of the present expansion, but the
typical imbalances in the housing, investment, and other sectors do not
yet seem to have developed.

In our private enterprise economy, business

cycles are entirely normal.

They can be ridden out if the imbalances have

not been allowed to become excessive as a result of government efforts to
keep the economy expanding when its natural expansive forces have temporarily
spent themselves.
The consumer is doing quite well and seems capable of carrying his
important share in a continued expansion.

Real income has been rising.

The

ratio of consumer debt to income, to be sure, has expanded considerably and
is roughly equal to its past peak.

But the consumer's assets are in good

shape, with the value of common stocks substantially higher than a year ago,
other financial assets advancing rapidly, and the value of homes growing
moderately although much less so than during the 1970's.

The consumer's

views of the state of the economy and of his own present and prospective
finances are good, although below their peak during the first half of 1984.
Business inventories are in reasonably good shape.

A slight

accumulation that occurred in the latter part of 1984 has been brought to
a halt, and the inventory position in most industries has been improved.
The housing sector has maintained a brisk pace with housing starts at 1.8
million in 1984 and at an annual rate of 1.9 million during April.

It has

-4turned in this performance despite a historically high level of interest
rates, particularly after adjustment for the much reduced rate of inflation.
This seeming ability to live with relatively high interest rates, however,
may to some extent reflect the benefit of the usually lower initial rates on
adjustable-rate mortgages, now accounting for about two-fifths of total loans
closed.

Moreover, the homeowner may be more sensitive than in the past to

any subsequent movement in interest rates.
The ability of the homeowner to live with historically high interest
rates raises a question whether business investment has suffered from these
rates, or whether the recent slowing has been the consequence of other
possibly quite temporary factors.

In examining the behavior of business

fixed investment, it needs to be recognized, for instance, that its character
has been somewhat unbalanced.

Increases have been most pronounced in office

equipment and in business-owned automobiles.

This is good enough to generate

purchasing power, but it does not contribute much to the productivity of the
industrial sector.

The big new investments that typically occur in the core

of manufacturing during the course of an expansion such as this one have not yet
materialized, even though output of heavy industrial machinery has been strong.
Moreover, while the rate of business fixed investment as a share of GNP has
beaten previous records, at least until its recent slowdown, it has done so only
if the depreciation factor is ignored.

Because so much of the investment has

been in relatively short-lived assets, depreciation will be considerably higher.
Even so, the increase in the capital stock after allowance for depreciation has
been equal to that of past recoveries.
Inflation has behaved relatively well, if one can speak of 4-5 percent
inflation in those terms.

For the longer run, that rate is, of course, still

much too high to avoid distortions and disincentives in the economy.

In any

-

5

-

event, inflation has not so far shown the kind of acceleration that has
been typical of late stages of the expansion.
most wages, at least until recently.
picking up over the last two quarters.

The same has been true of

In some sectors, wages have been
Meanwhile, unit labor costs, which

are a combination of wages (and fringes) and productivity gains, have
increased quite sharply as a result of the poor productivity performance
of the last three quarters.

The Wild Card
Looming in the background of all these trends in our economy is a
risk element that we have never experienced in the past -- the unpredictable
dollar.

The dollar has risen very high, in part at least because of the

interest-rate effects of the budget deficit.

In turn, the high dollar has

been responsible, although by no means exclusively, for our trade deficit.
The counterpart of that trade deficit, or more correctly the current-account
deficit (which includes services), has been an identical volume of capital
imports.

More goods and services have come in than have gone out.

In real

terms that means an increase in real resources, i.e., in real capital.

This

has been manifested by increased foreign holdings of American securities,
bank deposits, factories, and real estate.

The capital inflow, though it

reflects the painful fact of a large external deficit, has been beneficial
to the extent that it has helped to hold down interest rates.

The budget

deficit has in that sense been partly financed abroad.
The near-term future of the dollar is unpredictable.

In the long

run, the present level seems unsustainable because it would imply the accumula­
tion of an ever-mounting foreign debt by the United States.

It is useless to

-

6-

argue that the United States was a debtor country before World War I with
no adverse consequences.

In those days, the country borrowed abroad to

build railroads and factories.
i.e., in effect for consumption.

Today we borrow to finance a budget deficit,
But today, the current-account deficit of

a single year does not add dramatically to our net international liabilities,
because the world's holdings of dollar assets already are enormous (as are
our claims on the rest of the world).

The short-term impact of the current-

account deficit, therefore, is uncertain.

Nobody can tell when foreign

investors will begin to be concerned that they may have too large a stake
in the dollar and so become reluctant to keep financing us.

A decline of

the dollar would, with a lag, reduce the trade deficit which in one sense
would be a blessing.

But it would also reduce the capital inflow and that,

other things equal, would tend to raise interest rates.

Nobody can say when

this will happen, and, if it does, in what form.

It is a threat hanging over

our economy that we must do what we can to lift.

Reducing the budget deficit

is the most promising approach.

What Deficits Can We Sustain?
The amounts by which our internal and external deficits have to be
reduced may not be quite as large as the present levels of these deficits seem
to indicate.

In other words, some level of deficit, both in the budget and

in the current account, would probably be sustainable although far from
desirable.

The external deficit is in part the result of an excessively high

dollar, but in part also the consequence of sluggishness abroad.

Recovery

abroad can and should do part of the job of redressing our trade balance.
So long as that does not happen, the rest of the world is as dependent on

-

7-

the stimulus it gets from our imports of their goods as the United States
is on our imports of their capital.

If the rest of the world does recover,

the magnitude of the current-account adjustment that would have to come
through dollar depreciation would be much smaller.
The budget deficit, too, may not be in need of quite so dramatic
a fiscal effort as its present magnitude of $210 billion seems to imply.
In principle, it would, of course, be desirable for the government to make
no drains at all on our nation's savings flow, which is scanty enough as it
is.

Ideally, the government might even contribute to the savings flow by

running surpluses which the private sector would invest.

That is how the

American economy operated during the 1920's, when public debt was being
reduced steadily, and why the economy grew so fast during those years.
But that presupposes that the private sector is willing to absorb
savings into investment on a large scale.

It would imply a very favorable

investment climate, in which investors could take full advantage of low
interest rates, with confidence in price and exchange-rate stability, with
a moderate tax system, a moderate degree of regulation, and markets free
of rigidities imposed by government, labor, or uncompetitive business
practices.

One may doubt that such a blessed condition prevails today,

even after a great deal has been done through deregulation and better
business tax treatment.

If, by some stroke of a magical pen, the budget

deficit were eliminated, the economy would experience a deficiency of
aggregate demand of the order of 5 percent.

If a second stroke of that

pen also eliminated the external deficit, to be sure, the economy would
lose resources it now borrows abroad of the order of 3 percent of GNP.

-

8-

To make up for that, domestic production would have to rise by that
3 percent, leaving a deficiency of aggregate demand of 2 percent of GNP.
Could the economy increase its investment by so large an amount, assuming
that consumption simply stays at its old level in relation to GNP?

It

would mean raising investment by about 2 percentage points of GNP which
takes it well beyond its normal relationship to GNP.
be sure, would fall if the government stops borrowing.

Interest rates, to
But whether that

would stimulate investment sufficiently and how long it would take are big
ifs.

If these very rough numbers are even approximately meaningful, they

would seem to suggest that in the current context some government deficit
of one or two percent of GNP might be needed in order to lift purchasing
power to a level at which the economy would be operating close to potential.

Stabilizing the Ratio of Public Debt to GNP
A different approach to the question of an acceptable budget deficit
would look at the ratio of public debt to GNP.

Presumably a debt constantly

rising in relation to GNP would not be acceptable because ultimately it would
push us into inflation.
The current level of the public debt —
government accounts -- is $1.3 trillion.

excluding debt held by

Assuming nominal GNP growth of

7 percent, of which 3 percent is real growth and 4 percent is inflation, the
debt-to-GNP ratio would remain roughly constant even if the federal government
ran a budget deficit of $100 billion.

In real terms, 3 percent growth of

both GNP and debt would allow an inflation-adjusted deficit of about $45 bil­
lion.

-9To be sure, a constant debt/GNP ratio is not a very good guide
because it seems to say that the higher the debt already is in relation
to GNP, the more it can be increased each year without raising the debt/GNP
ratio.

A high ratio means simply that the point at which inflationary

pressures might begin, owing to the burden of interest payments in the budget,
is that much nearer.
These numbers suggest, nevertheless, that the United States could
tolerate a sizable budget deficit —

provided the government is prepared to

take that much saving away from the private sector and possibly from productive
investment.

If the private sector

in any event could not find productive use

for the money even if interest rates were lower and the functioning of markets
improved, no immediate damage would be done by even a high budget deficit.
Indeed, the deficit would be needed in order to keep the economy from sinking
into recession.

However, a continuously high budget deficit would also mean

that the United States had become resigned to low investment, low productivity
gains, and low growth.

It would be a sad day for the economy if that happened.

At the present time, the budget deficit obviously is too high in the
sense that it causes us to borrow heavily abroad as well as at home.

A

reduction of the budget deficit, as I have noted, would lower interest rates,
probably lower the dollar, and so reduce the trade deficit and capital imports.
Investment would also benefit from lower interest rates.
Nobody can evaluate the possible interaction of all these forces
and their ultimate effect on the American economy.

The magnitude of the

effects is uncertain, their timing very uncertain, even the direction in
which a given effect might go is not sure.

For instance, a reduction in the

budget deficit, while reducing interest rates, might so improve the international

-10image of the United States that the dollar might go up instead of down.
Various kinds of scenarios could be developed.
possible but by no means assured.

Soft landings seem entirely

The key variables always are the budget

deficit and the dollar.
Timing uncertainties are very marked.

Financial-market effects,

on interest rates and on the dollar, normally take place more rapidly than
goods-market effects, such as on trade balance and investment.
may play a role and further speed up financial developments.

Anticipations
Alternatively,

if government lacks credibility, the desired responses of interest rates and
exchange rates may be long delayed.
The main driving force of these possible interactions is the
assumption of a major cut in the budget deficit.

In an alternative and

less benign scenario, the deficit is not reduced significantly, interest
rates in consequence do not fall, but the dollar drops because foreign
investors change their attitude toward investment in a country that seemingly
cannot get its house in order.

In that case, the trade deficit and capital

imports would still go down, but interest rates would tend to rise.

The net

effect on GNP of an improved trade balance and deteriorating investment could
go either way.

The unpredictable dollar, therefore, plays the role of a wild

card in this game.
Movements in the dollar also change the rate of inflation.

A well-

known econometric estimate says that a 10 percent drop in the dollar raises
the price level by a little over 1-1/2 percent in three years, i.e., raises
the rate of inflation by slightly more than a half percent per year.

When

the dollar was going up, the United States benefitted by a lower rate of
inflation.

On the way down, it will lose.

-11The Role of the Price of Oil
Let me conclude with a word about the role of oil in this picture.
Foreign countries have often complained that a rise in the dollar and
consequent fall in their currencies has added to their own inflationary
pressures.
oil.

That case has been made particularly with respect to the price of

Because oil prices are quoted in dollars the case often has sounded

persuasive and indeed is by no means invalid.

Nevertheless, the argument

ignores that the demand for oil is a world demand and that the supply price,
to the extent that it is at all sensitive to demand, is also determined in
the world market rather than in the United States.

The tendency of the world

oil price to weaken as the dollar went up reflects, among other things, the
fact that the price of oil in other currencies rose, reducing the amount
demanded.

If the dollar declines, a constant dollar price for oil will mean

cheaper oil in other currencies and, accordingly, a greater demand.

Both on

the way up and on the way down, the movement in the dollar price of oil, other
things equal, is likely to be less than that of the dollar itself.
Finally, I would note that domestically in the ups and downs of
inflation, the great role played by the price of oil has often been overlooked.
Directly and indirectly, movements in the oil price that were inposed upon the
United States by forces from abroad have contributed strongly, first to the
acceleration of inflation, more recently to its slowing.

A near tenfold

increase in the price of perhaps the most important single commodity in the
world over less than a decade was bound to have major price effects, quite
aside from monetary policy, budget deficits, wage push, and occasional crop
failures.

Movements in this price have influenced the location of industry,

-12the pattern of production, the rate of productivity growth, and the solvency
of many enterprises and even banks.
Today it is customary to say that people made serious mistakes in
investing in oil, that they should have had better foresight, and that many
investors, producers, and bankers are now paying a penalty for these errors.
I would like to think back to the time when those decisions were made.

It

was not only a time of speculation, but a time of perceived national emergency,
characterized by deep concern about how the world economy would continue to
function in the face of what was widely seen as an oncoming oil crisis.
Mistakes have been made, and penalties are being paid, but I remember well
that many of those unfortunate decisions at the time were widely hailed as
serving to protect the national economy.

Perfect judgment is not possible,

either in the oil business, or in forecasting the dollar, GNP, and all the
rest.

All we can do is to try to do better next time.

#