View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE (»1 DELIVERY
SATURDAY, MARCH 1, 1980
12:00 Noon, CST (1:00 p.m. EST)




TECHNIQUES OF MONETARY POLICY
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a meeting of the
Missouri Valley Economic Association
Memphis, Tennessee
March 1» 1960

TECHNIQUES OF MONETARY POLICY
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a meeting of the
Missouri Valley Economic Association
Memphis, Tennessee
March 1, 1980

Recent changes in monetary policy techniques adopted by the
Federal Reserve direct attention once more to a variety of issues in
the monetary field that have been debated from tin*r to time over the
years.

I am glad to have this opportunity to give you a quick review

of the new procedures and of their relation to lagged reserve accounting
and the role of the monetary base.

To begin with, I shall sketch briefly

the nature of the old procedures.

Money Supply Control Based on the Funds Rate
In 1970, the Federal Reserve for the first time instituted a
money-supply target, using the federal funds rate to achieve that target.
Essentially, the procedure was to set the funds rate at a level at which
the desired growth of the money supply would be forthcoming.

Estimates of

the demand for money at different interest rates, given the level of income,
were derived from quarterly and monthly models and judgmental estimates and
were, of cccsrse, always subject to correction.

This procedure was adopted

in preference to one that would seek to control the money supply by




-

2-

controlling reserves because, among other things, it promised less
disturbance to financial markets from sharp fluctuations in the funds
rate.
This procedure seemed to offer several advantages.

It avoided

sharp fluctuations in the federal funds rate that would result from deposit
shifts and associated changes in the multiplier.

More broadly, any short-

run shocks originating from the money-supply side would be kept from
influencing the volume of money.

Holding the funds rate more or less

constant and, given a stable demand function, the amount of money demanded,
meant accommodating such shocks by reducing or increasing the supply of
reserves consistent with funds-rate stability.

Since the multiplier link

from reserves to deposits was not relied upon, the procedure also did not
rely on any particular structure of reserve requirements.
The procedure also had significant disadvantages, however.

For

instance, a shock to the money stock from the demand side, causing the
amount of money demanded temporarily to deviate from the targeted level,
would be accommodated and thus deprived of its self-correcting side effects.
Concretely, a drop in the amount of money demanded below target, under a
funds-rate approach, would not be allowed to produce the reduction in
interest rates that would help to restore at least partly the targeted
money supply.

Neither would a rise in the demand for money be allowed to

generate a partly self-correcting increase in interest rates.

In either

case, the open market desk would alter the volume of reserves sufficiently
to neutralize any self-correcting interest-rate change.

This would be an

undesirable effect if the shock to the demand for money turned out to be
only temporary and if the objective of policy was to keep money constant.



3If, on the other hand, the shock implied a permanent change in the relation
of money to income, making a change in money desirable, the desk's action
tending to adjust the money supply to this changed demand would turn out
to have been appropriate.

However, if the change in money demanded

arose from an undesired change in nominal income, the funds rate
targeting procedure tending to accoranodate such changes, at least in the
short run, would represent an undesirable accommodation.
These technical problems of the funds rate procedure were over­
shadowed by even more serious implications at the policy level.

Even though

the funds rate was being controlled for the purpose of controlling the money
supply, a widespread public perception developed, or perhaps persisted, that
the Federal Reserve was seeking to influence primarily interest rates.
This misconception became apparent from the comments following the Federal
Reserve's change to a reserves procedure on October

6

, 1979.

But even a

correct perception of the funds rate as being merely an operating instrument
did not discourage the market from closely watching that rate, ready to make
portfolio changes and thereby transmit the impulse to other rates whenever
the funds rate moved.

The link thus established between the daily funds rate

and a wide range of short-term market rates made it more troublesome for
the Federal Reserve to move the funds rate in pursuit of its money-supply
target.

This created a danger that the Federal Reserve might move too late

and too little, and that meanwhile the money supply might run away in a pro­
cyclical direction.

Interest rates would then not move enough in the course

of an expansion or contraction to maintain the equilibrium between the market
rate and the marginal efficiency of investment or, as Wicksell would have
put it, between the market rate and the natural interest rate.



-4Advantages of the Reserves-Based Procedure
I shall briefly summarize the advantages of the new procedure
before describing its technical detail, because these advantages are the
mirror image of the disadvantages of the old.
At the technical level, the procedure of supplying a given volume
of reserves and thereby aiming via the multiplier at a given money-supply
target has the advantage of partly insulating the money stock against shocks
from the demand side.

Such demand-side shocks, in the face of a constant

money supply, will move interest rates in a self-correcting direction causing
at least part of the demand-shock effect to be reversed.

On the other hand,

if the demand-shock reflects a lasting change in the relationship of money
stock to income, an adjustment of the money stock is desirable and failure
to adjust would be destabilizing.

Finally, if the shift represents an

unwanted change in nominal spending itself, the automatic restraint would
be desirable.
At the policy level, the reserve-based procedure has the advantage
of minimizing the need for Federal Reserve decisions concerning the funds
rate.

Interest rates become a byproduct, as it were, of the money-supply

process.

To be sure, the public and the Congress will remain aware that

the Federal Reserve has something to do with interest rates.

But there is

widespread public and political support for a policy of holding down the
money supply which probably cannot be said of the mirror image of such a
policy in terms of interest rates.

The new procedure, therefore, has a

better chance of avoiding a pro-cyclical bias.




-5-

Among the technical disadvantages of the reserve-based procedure
must be rated the greater variability of interest rates, which tends to
result when the volume of reserves demanded does not match the amount
supplied.

Market factors such as float, Treasury balance, and currency

in circulation, all of which cannot be precisely predicted, virtually ensure
that such discrepancies will occur from time to time.

There is, however,

■:io reason why the daily funds rate should be as closely linked to rates
such as those on Treasury bills, commercial paper, and CDs as it was under
the old procedures.

These rates for the most part arc for periods beyond

one month rather than one day.
Another technical drawback is the dependence of the new technique
on reserve requirements.
increasingly troublesome.

The growth of nonmember bank deposits becomes
So does the difference among reserve requirements

for different types of deposits and different sizes of banks.

The two-week

lag in reserve requirements represents another source of multiplier instability.
These problems are avoided under the funds-rate procedure.

In terms of the

effectiveness of achieving a given money-supply target, past studies suggest
1/
that the two approaches are approximately equal.
However, inertia in the
adjustment of the funds rate to needed levels under the old procedure would
in practice tip the balance in favor of reserves.

1/

I examined the pros and cons of the two alternative procedures in
"Innovations in Monetary Policy," presented to the Southern Economic
Association at its meeting in Atlanta, Georgia, on November 18, 1976,
printed in Readings in Money. National Income, and Stabilization Policy,
edited by Ronald L. Teigen, University of Michigan, pp. 219-225.




-6-

A more fundamental potential disadvantage of a reserves strategy
is its possible impact on the foreign exchange market in times of recession.
If a recession depresses the demand for money, a reserve strategy will allow
interest rates to decline whereas a funds rate strategy automatically would
keep interest rates up unless the funds rate objective were lowered.

Many

observers have commented on the possibility that such a decline in interest
rates might adversely affect the dollar.
attach to this line of reasoning.

Several qualifications, nevertheless,

In the first place, the FOMC does not

allow the funds rate to move without limit but maintains a range, albeit
one considerably wider than under the funds rate procedure.

Second, the

demand for money is dominated by the movements of nominal GNP which recently
have reflected more the rate of inflation than the growth of real GNP.
Third, as long as inflation expectations are high, they will probably tend
to keep interest rates high at the long end and to some extent probably
also at the short end.

Of course, if inflation expectations are declining

under these conditions, interest rates will come down and should come down
and can probably do so without adversely affecting the exchange rate.

Details of the New Procedures
The Federal Reserve's new procedures, based as they are on reserves,
are sometimes described as relying on the money multiplier.

The multiplier

links the totality of reserves to deposits and the money supply.

Strictly

speaking the Federal Reserve's derivation of the appropriate reserve paths
does not rely on direct estimates of the multiplier.

Instead, the public's

projected demand for currency is subtracted from the targeted path for money,




-7-

giving an implied target for deposits.

Then, the volume of required reserves

is estimated separately for various reserve categories and type and size of bank.
In arriving at total reserves allowance must be made for some amount of
reserves to be absorbed by excess reserves.

In the past, excess reserves

have been rather insensitive to interest rates and have remained fairly
constant at what seems to be a frictional level.

Allowance must be made

also for the absorption of reserves by bank liabilities that do not enter
into the money supply, such as interbank deposits, Treasury balance, and,
under the new definitions of the monetary aggregates, deposits of foreign
commercial banks and monetary authorities.

Aggregation causes an aggregate

multiplier to fall out, but this multiplier is an implicit one only.

To

estimate the open market operations needed to achieve the path of total
reserves, account must be taken of the impact on reserves of market factors
such as currency in circulation, Treasury balances with the Federal Reserve,
and float.
These calculations lead to a level of total reserves, which on
February

6

, 1980, consisted of $42.7 billion required and $556 million

excess reserves.

Given expected total reserves, a decision must be made

as to what part of these total reserves is to be supplied through open market
operations and what part through the discount window.
reserves into nonborrowed and borrowed reserves.
reserves, of course, sustain deposits.

That divides total

Both borrowed and nonborrowed

The level of borrowing from the

Federal Reserve, given the discount rate, is related to the funds rate.
Banks are willing to pay a premium for federal funds purchased in the market
over funds borrowed from the Federal Reserve because they know that they
cannot borrow from the Federal Reserve without restrictions.



Therefore,

-

8“

the volume of borrowing from the Federal Reserve tends to rise as the
funds rate rises relative to the discount rate.

At the higher funds

rate, with other market rates moving in the same direction, banks and
nonbanks have reason to restrain their demand for funds.
Thus, it is not a matter of indifference whether a given volume
of total reserves is derived almost entirely from nonborrowed reserves or
whether it contains a significant component of borrowed reserves.

The

larger the borrowed component, the higher, other things equal, the funds
rate relative to the discount rate, and the stronger the tendency toward
restraint.
Technically, tighter control would be obtainable if the discount
window were more severely constrained, but prediction of reserves is difficult,
and noisy short-run shocks are common.

This suggests the need for a temporary

shock absorber at the discount window.
Under the new Federal Reserve procedures some level of borrowing
needs to be assumed in order to arrive at an estimate of the need for non­
borrowed reserves.

Typically, an amount in line with the existing volume of

borrowed reserves is plugged into the calculation.

However, the FOMC can

modify this, within a given estimate for total reserves, making allowance
in that case also for an appropriate change in the funds rate relative to
the discount rate.

Alternatively, the FOMC can change the discount rate

and thereby change the amount to which banks will want to borrow at a given
funds rate.




-9-

The new procedure thus focuses upon a family of reserve concepts.
Total reserves are most closely related to the monetary aggregates, given
reasonably stable excess reserves.

Nonborrowed reserves are less closely

related to the aggregates, because borrowed reserves can change.

For that

reason, however, total reserves are less easily controlled by the Federal
Reserve in the short run, whereas nonborrowed reserves are under its
immediate control.
Borrowed reserves can be controlled by the discount rate and by
the supply of nonborrowed reserves, except to the extent that lagged reserve
accounting makes the borrowed reserves interest-inelastic.

In practice

this means that, under lagged reserve requirements the level of nonborrowed
reserves determines the weekly need for member bank borrowing, given their
predetermined level of required reserves and minimal excess reserves.
Consequently, a rise in the discount rate will push the funds rate up by
an approximately equal margin since, in the very short run, the banks must
borrow whatever fix°d volume of required reserves they need given the
nonborrowed'reserves supplied to them.

I shall turn to the issue of lagged

reserve requirements later in ay talk.

At that time I shall also deal with

the monetary base, which is the last in the family of reserve variables
considered under the new procedures, although at a lower level of importance.

Misconceptions Concerning the New Procedures
The new procedures of the Federal Reserve have given rise to some
understandable misconceptions that suggest that the Federal Reserve has not
been fully effective in making itself understood.
these now.




I shall examine some of

-

10-

"Tightness should be measured by interest rates."

Under the old

procedures, watching the funds rate was the proper way to watch what the
Federal Reserve was doing.

Under the new procedures, it is the money supply

that needs to be watched for such signals.

The funds rate is a byproduct,

within the wide limits set by the Federal Reserve.

This is hard for Fed

watchers to accept, not only because it is new, but more particularly
because it is interest rates that most Fed watchers earn their money by,
not the money supply.

Moreover, interest rates are visible in the newspapers

and on screens continuously, while the money supply figures appear once a week
and are subject to revision.

Nevertheless, in terms of the new procedures,

it is wrong to say that the Fed has eased when interest rates go down.
The proper test is whether the money supply strengthened more than very
temporarily without the Fed acting to offset it by lessening reserve growth.

"Reserves are an indicator of monetary policy.

11

Some who argue

this do so because they are aware that the Fed is operating on reserves now,
others because they believe that a move of reserves —
nonborrowed —

total, required, or

foreshadows future movements in the aggregates.

part, this view, too, is misleading.

For the most

Movements of reserves relate not only

to the monetary aggregates, but also to shifts of funds among baiks, among
reserve categories, and among reservable liabilities included or excluded
in the monetary aggregates.

It is quite possible, for instance, to see

reserves go down while the aggregates increase, or vice versa.

"Nonborrowed reserves do not control the money supply.”

It is

sometimes alleged that the Federal Reserve focuses exclusively on nonborrowed
reserves, allowing borrowed reserves to go where they will, because it believes



-

11-

that borrowed reserves cause contraction instead of expansion.

Obviously,

borrowed reserves, which the bank receiving them through settlement cannot
distinguish from nonborrowed, support expansion just as well as nonborrowed
reserves do.
reserves.

The Federal Reserve, therefore, looks primarily at total

It is aware, however, that an increase in the proportion of total

reserves derived from borrowing, associated with a widening spread between
discount rate and funds rate, has effects on other interest rates and on bank
and nonbank behavior that are more conducive to restraint than if the same
reserves had been supplied through open market operations.

"The funds rate at the time the Fed enters the market is a tip-off
to where the Fed wants the funds rate."

This was undoubtedly the case under

the old procedures, and constituted one of the most important signals given
by the desk to the market.

The Fed usually did not enter the market unless

the funds rate was moving in one direction or the other.

The level at which

it entered told the market something about whether the Fed wanted the funds
rate to stop there, or at least wanted to slow down its movement*

Under

the new procedures, the Fed enters the market when its estimates of reserve
availability tell it that there is a need to supply or drain reserves.
funds rate level at which this happens is largely fortuitous.

The

It is only

if the Manager lacks confidence in his estimates of reserve availability that
he may take the movement of the funds rate as an indicator of whether the
market, at the going rate, has a reserve deficiency or a reserve surplus.
Since reserve estimates are being made continuously both at the Federal
Reserve Board and at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, with an input
from Treasury on the important Treasury balance factor, the danger that the




Manager may fall back Into manipulating the funds rate as a proxy for
estimates of reserve needs is small.

"The Federal Reserve's role when on a money-supply target is
essentially passive."

It has been, argued that adoption of a money-supply

target is virtually synonymous with a money-supply rule which in turn means
passivity of monetary policy.

In response, it needs first to be noted that

the short-run money-supply target, set monthly by the FOMC for overlapping
three-month periods, is not invariant even if the long-term (one-year or
possibly more) target is invariant.

Short-term deviations from the long­

term target are almost unavoidable.

Some may be predictable in advance

and those of a temporary nature could be accommodated without harm.
Conditions in the financial markets and in the economy may make it more
advisable or less advisable to get back on track immediately.

Short-term

monetary policy therefore needs to be mobile rather than passive.
More importantly, however, even a constant money-growth rule is by
no means a prescription for central bank passivity.

The consequence of a

firmly adhered to monetary target under conditions of cyclical fluctuations
implies wide fluctuations in interest rates.

The natural tendency of the

money supply and of a central bank concerned primarily about interest rates,
is to be inadvertently pro-cyclical.

The central banks will tend to move

interest rates less than needed to preserve the Keynesian or WickseIlian
equilibrium between the market rate and marginal efficiency of investment.
A money-supply target will push the central bank in the direction of
allowing or generating wider interest-rate swings.

Conceivably even the

larger swings induced by a constant rate of money growth will not be
sufficient to maintain the required equilibrium since demand for money



-13

varies with the interest rate.

To maintain that equilibrium, the money

supply, or at least its growth, might have to be altered, countcrcyclically.
In any event, a money-supply target implies wide interest-rste swings and
in that sense a highly activist monetary policy.

The Monetary Base
The monetary base, consisting of currency and member bank reserves,
is often proposed as the best target for monetary policy.

Under the new

Federal Reserve procedures, this use of the base has been advocated in the
context of a reserve aggregate for the Federal Reserve to aim at.

More

generally, however, the base has been proposed as a target in addition to,
or in place of, monetary aggregates such as the M-ls and M-2.

In support

of the base, it is argued that it can be shown to be closely related to
income, that it has not been as much exposed to demand shifts as have M-1A
or B and M-2, and that its growth rate, on average somewhat higher than M-1A
or B, has been a more reliable indicator of excessive money creation than
M-1A or B.
Personally I believe that the entire money supply approach would
have to be in even greater disarray than it is today before we should have
recourse to the monetary base.

The monetary base today consists of about

$105 billion of currency in the hands of the nonbank public, $15 billion of
vault cash held by banks, and $30 billion of member bank deposits with the
Federal Reserve a total of about $150 billion.
consists very predominantly of currency.

In other words, the base

There is something peculiar about

the volume of currency outstanding in the United States, which amounts to
approximately $500 per capita, because there is no evidence that a substantial




-14-

part of the total Is held by businesses.
representative households either.

Obviously it Is not held by

Nobody knows how much American currency

is held abroad, has been destroyed, or perhaps is used in some underground
economy, but one guesses that the sum of such elements may be substantial.
An aggregate containing such components does not inspire a great deal of
intuitive confidence.
As a proxy for the M-ls and M-2, the base clearly is defective.
In terms of reserves absorbed, it gives a weight of one to the currency
component but a weight of only about one-eighth to demand deposits and onetwenty-fifth to the deposit component of M-2.
Whether the base tracks income better than do the M-ls or M-2 is
partly a matter of one's econometrics.

But in any event the direction of

causation in the past was predominantly inverse.
supposed to be mainly a function of retail sales.

Currency holdings must be
The base, therefore, was

likely to have been determined by income more than the other way about.
The endogenous character of currency is troublesome in still
another respect.

When the public's demand for currency increases, the

Federal Reserve automatically offsets it, under a reserves operating
target, by providing the banks with reserves sufficient to cover the
shortfall of reserves on the unwithdrawn balance of their deposits.
Using the base as a policy guide would require a massive contraction or
expansion of deposits with any temporary or permanent change in the ratio
of currency to deposits.
not be feasible.

Such variations in deposits would in practice

For these reasons the base is not even assuredly

controllable, as is sometimes argued, let alone a dependable policy guide.




-15Lapjfled Reserves
The shift to a reserves-bascd procedure has injected new life
into the old controversy about lagged reserve requirements.

Since

September 1968, member banks' required reserves are based, not on the
reservable liabilities of the period during which reserves must be held,
but on the liabilities of two weeks earlier.

The advantage of this arrange­

ment is that banks find it easier to establish their reserve liabilities
and can avoid the extra costs, errors, and corrections implicit in
contemporaneous reserve accounting.

A second advantage, at least in the

eyes of some, is that required reserves cannot be reduced by anything the
banks can do during the reserve settlement period, such as selling off
securities or cutting back on loans, even if system-wide deposits have
meanwhile changed.

The past is fixed, and the banks must scramble to find

reserves or to dispose of excess reserves, allowing for a two-week carryover,
if they want to avoid reserve excesses or deficiencies.

Other things equal,

therefore, interest rate swings will tend to be somewhat wider and pressure
for adjustment stronger under lagged accounting as banks seek to obtain or
dispose of funds before they go to the discount window.

Given nonborrowed

reserves, the discount window remains the sole source of adjustment.
Under contemporaneous reserve accounting, the scramble of the banks
to acquire or dispose of reserves influences the volume of reservable
liabilities and therefore required reserves to the extent that sales or
purchases of securities or restraint or ease in lending alter deposits.
This reduces'the swings in interest rates that need to occur before banks
are driven into or out of the discount window.




The difference, however,

16-

is slight because it takes an average of

$ 8

of demand deposits and $25 of

time and savings deposits to change required reserves by $1 .
A significant advantage of contemporaneous reserves, however, can
flow from the timing of efforts to adjust reservable liabilities at least
under a reserves strategy.
advantage.

Under a funds-rate strategy, there is no such

The distinction is a subtle one.

Under a funds-rate strategy,

the timing of the banks' efforts to adjust reservable liabilities is
determined by the movement of the funds rate.

That movement, in turn, is

determined by the action of the FCMC and, between FOMC meetings, by the action
of the desk which is guided by incoming information on the monetary aggregates.
Lagged or contemporaneous accounting makes no difference under these circum­
stances.
Under the new procedures, however, the desk supplies reserves, and
the banks, in turn feel their need for reserves, with a lag of two weeks.
That is to say, they do not need to put up reserves until two weeks after
reserve liabilities may have increased.

Thus, pressure on the funds rate,

as banks bid for reserves, comes only with a two-week lag.

The process

of adjusting deposits by adjusting loans and security holdings begins two
weeks later, unless the Federal Reserve were to move interest rates so as
to start the adjustment process earlier.

Under the reserve strategy,

therefore, lagged reserve accounting is likely to slow down adjustment.




*