View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY, APRIL 14, 1983
9:30 A.M. LOCAL TIME (3:30 A.M. EST)




STRUCTURAL CHANGES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES IN THE 1970'S
AND THEIR IMPLICATIONS FOR THE 1980'S

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a conference on
"Financial Markets and Economic Activity"
sponsored by the First Austrian Bank
Vienna, Austria
Thursday, April 14, 1983

STRUCTURAL CHANGES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES IN THE 1970's
AND THEIR IMPLICATIONS FOR THE 1980'S

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a conference on
"Financial Markets and Economic Activity"
sponsored by the First Austrian Bank
Vienna, Austria
Thursday, April 14, 1983

With admirable foresight, the sponsors of this meeting, to whom
I extend thanks, have issued their invitations at a point in time when it
can be said with some assurance that, in the United States at least, an
expansion seems to be in progress.

This is an important development.

Nevertheless, even though most of the world's economies are likely to
move up hereafter, we are still experiencing the consequences, often
painful, of events and policies that now lie in the past, but that for
better or for worse will continue to shape our affairs for a good while
longer.

That is the reason for examining the legacy of the 1970's.

I

am grateful to our hosts for giving me an opportunity to survey such a
broad panorama of economic history and outlook.
The 1970's was a period of disillusionment, of loss of faith in
seemingly established truths.
prices and exchange rates.




Confidence was lost in the stability of

More than that, we lost faith in the willingness

2

-

o£ governments to make serious efforts to preserve or restore stability.
As governments lost credibility, so did some of the established doctrines
about the functioning of the economy.

New doctrines, themselves often of

questionable plausibility, began to take their place.

It has been difficult

to keep one's bearing under these conditions.
Nevertheless, not all our experience of the 1970's was adverse.
And it must be remembered that in the face of very considerable difficulties,
the world economy continued to make progress, raising average living standards
particularly in the developing world.
very perceptibly.

Progress, however, has slowed down

In many countries it has come to a total halt.

If we

can learn from our experience, we ought to do better hereafter.

Inflation
Virtually all industrial countries experienced serious inflation
during the 1970's, although in different degree.

Determination to resist

inflation and return to price stability has often been interpreted in terms
of each country's earlier inflation experience.

Austria and Germany both

suffered inflations so severe that the money supply was totally destroyed
and so were most financial savings.

The good performance of these two

countries in combatting the inflation of the 1970's probably reflects that
earlier experience.
The United States and Great Britain, as well as the Scandinavian
countries, have been spared similar experiences.

As a result, they seem to

have been more susceptible to the recent assault of the inflation virus.
For a long time, inflation in these countries was regarded as a minor evil,




and as a price well worth paying for fuller employment.

It took time to

learn that inflation is not only costly and painful, but that in the long
run it undermines rather than supports the full-employment objective.

It

took high rates of inflation, although far from the hyperinflations experienced
by Austria and Germany, to drive home that lesson.

One may hope that the

lesson has been learned, but it would be premature to be sure.
Other countries, such as France and Italy, years ago experienced
rates of inflation that fell short of totally destroying the money supply but
nevertheless sufficed to destroy financial savings.

It is not at all evident

that that lesson has dominated attitudes and policies.

Finally, there is the

example of Switzerland, which has had no historical experience of high inflation
and nevertheless has resisted inflation more vigorously and successfully than
any other country.

Thus, historical experience of inflation, while important,

does not seem to be a reliable indicator of a country's present day determina­
tion to achieve price stability.
The causes of inflation have, of course, been many, and often quite
different in different countries.

But making all possible allowance for oil

shocks, imported inflation and other circumstances difficult to control,
the principal cause almost everywhere seems to have been an effort to drive
the economy harder than it could safely be driven.

Economists, particularly

those of the Keynesian persuasion, must accept a great deal of responsibility
for these policies.

To be sure, more mundane political pressures might have

done a similar job without benefit of economic theory.

Whatever the causes

and circumstances, one effect of inflation has been a loss of faith in price
stability as a normal condition.




This has greatly increased the cost of

-4economic activity.

Buyers and sellers, employers and employees, lenders

and borrowers must charge some kind of a premium to cover the risk that an
unexpected movement of prices, to their disadvantage, would falsify their
calculations.

Both sides suffer as it becomes harder to interpret the

movements of individual prices and the general price level.

The most

damaging aspect of the uncertainties posed by inflation probably is the
great difficulty it creates for people who want to provide for their future.
Remarkably, people continue to save and did so even when real interest rates
were negative.

Indeed, some people seem to save more than they might if

price stability were assured because they need to guard against this
insecurity.

But predominantly the effect seems to have been to drive

people to rely on government protection for their retirement, as the only
seemingly sure way of guarding against destitution in old age.

It is hard to

imagine a more serious defect in civilized society than inability to provide
for the future.
It is not unreasonable to hope, given past experience, that the
lessons have been learned and that inflation in the future will be much more
moderate or entirely quiescent.

But the generation that has lived through

the 1970's, with their rapid shrinkage in the value of money, probably has
been scarred for life.

In the United States, a survey of financial managers

suggests that most of them do not expect a high rate of inflation over the
next 10 years.

Nevertheless, on average, they give a probability of about

one-third to the possibility of hyperinflation.

It will take long years of

reasonable price stability before these memories of the 1970's will fade.




-

5

-

Meanwhile, better techniques of preventing inflation and of bringing
it down once it has taken hold .~eem to have been developed.

Most countries

have shown enough wisdom to avoid wage and price controls, which usually are
effective for at most a short period, do much damage while they last, and have
no permanent impact on the rate of inflation.

Most countries have found that

the ordinary techniques of central banks in manipulating interest rates are
not adequate against inflation.

Moreover, many have found that the ability

of central banks to influence interest rates is very much diminished in an
inflationary environment.

Money-supply targets have proved to be more

visibly related to the rate of inflation and less susceptible to gross error.
They have also helped to shield the central bank against the criticism that
would be associated with a policy of setting interest rates high enough to
curb inflation.

By and large, money-supply targets have proved effective in

reducing inflation, although they have sometimes had unexpected and costly side
effects.
A central bank need not subscribe to the tenets of monetarism in
order to follow a money-supply policy.

Indeed, monetarism, while it has

acquired great merit by promoting money-supply targeting, has not served
the cause of anti-inflationary policy well by claiming that monetary over­
expansion is the sole cause of inflation and that no other instrument but
monetary restraint needs to be employed to bring inflation down.

This has

contributed to the prevailing lack of concern over large budget deficits.
For governments, of course, news that budget deficits are not inflationary
is welcome.

The ensuing higher real interest rates can readily be blamed

on the central bank.




-6 Excessive reliance on monetary policy as an anti-inflation weapon
has also contributed to discouraging the development of incomes policies.
To be sure, even in the not many cases where they seem to have worked,
incomes policies have been in no way a substitute for monetary restraint.
Nevertheless, they could reduce the costs associated with monetary restraint.
If fiscal policy and incomes policy had been employed more effectively, both
unemployment and interest rates probably would have been lower.

The develop­

ment of viable incomes policies has to be carried over to the agenda for the
1980’s.

It should be clear that they should in no way rest on wage and price

controls, but, on the contrary, require a heightened degree of cooperation
between business and labor.

Interest Rates
One of the legacies of the 1970's —
level of interest rates.
were far from high.

and early 1980's —

is a high

During most of the 1970's, however, interest rates

As the rate of inflation, with some ups and downs, moved

up during the decade, most interest rates became negative in real terms.
Short-term rates frequently were below the current rate of inflation, long­
term rates below what might reasonably be regarded as expected inflation.
This condition contributed to excessive borrowing, monetary expansion, and
further inflation.
During the early 1970*s, the tendency of interest rates to move
closely with the rate of inflation was far less pronounced than it is today.
This relationship was even looser during the inflationary periods of the
1940's and 1950's.




Interest rates were believed, on historical evidence

-7going back to the 19th century, to follow Inflation only with a lag of
many years.

Gradually, as both borrowers and lenders began to understand

better the effects of inflation on the cost of money, a much closer
relationship developed.

By 1980 or 1981, with the help of hardening

monetary policies in the United States and elsewhere, positive real interest
rates had become the rule, i.e., interest rates tended to exceed the rate of
inflation.
One may view this development, within limits, as an improvement in
the allocative function of interest.

One may view it also as a victory, for

the time being, of the saver over the borrower.
effect been expropriated by borrowers.

Previously, savers had in

And one may view it as a victory of

the old, who in part live on savings, over the young, who tend to be borrowers.
In that sense, it could reflect the beginning of an ominous shift in the
balance of numbers and the associated balance of political influence away
from the young who work and toward the old who in some form must be supported
by them.

That balance can be expected to change further during the 1980's

and indeed as far ahead as demographers can see.
The combination of inflation with a tax system that did not recognize
it seriously distorted the economic effect of interest rates.

The saver did

not get the full benefit of the inflation premium in the interest rate,
because both real interest and the inflation premium were taxable.

Borrowers

generally were able to deduct, for tax purposes, the full nominal interest
premium.

This introduced a further upward bias into nominal interest rates.

It also conveyed a false picture of seeming enrichment of interest recipients
through high rates, when in fact these rates in part constituted amortization
of a depreciating principal.




-8 The financial structure of business was distorted during the
1970's by the interaction of interest rates, inflation, and tax deductibility.
Debt financing increasingly predominated over equity financing.

Short-term

and floating-interest-rate debt gained at the expense of long-term and fixedrate debt.

Businesses, as well as home buyers and developing countries

that borrowed heavily, became increasingly vulnerable to interest-rate
fluctuations.

The share of capital in national income shifted toward

interest and away from profit.

All this depressed the willingness to

invest, despite negative real rates, as well as the rate of economic growth.
The rise in interest rates was further exacerbated, as already
noted, by mounting government deficits.

At times during the 1970*s, this

tendency was counteracted by the large supply of saving that entered world
capital markets from OPEC. But OPEC surpluses disappeared quite soon after
each of the two great jumps in oil prices.

It is worth noting that the

deficit in the U.S. budget now is approximately twice as large as the OPEC
surplus was at its peak.
The ability of central banks to influence interest rates diminished
as interest rates became increasingly responsive to inflation and inflation
expectations.

This consequence was enhanced by the variability of exchange

rates under the floating-rate system, to which I shall presently refer.
For the 1980's there are good prospects that interest rates will
decline, both nominal and real.

Nominal interest rates should decline as

inflation and inflation expectations diminish.

Real interest rates would

decline if the balance of saving and borrowing were to move in a favorable
direction.




Some contribution to that end may come from a resurgence of

-9 saving, as confidence in price stability rises.

The principal contribution

to lower interest rates, however, which quantitatively can far outweigh any
likely increase in private saving, would have to come from a reduction in
government deficits.

Exchange Rates
Floating exchange rates are another legacy of the 1970's.

When

they were imposed on the world by the collapse of the fixed-rate system, it
was widely argued that from now on individual countries would be able to
conduct the monetary and fiscal policies they preferred.

Each country

simply would accept the resulting rate of inflation, and so free itself
from the policy constraints that flow from the need to preserve fixed rates.
This turned out to be an error.
even minor variations in policy.

Exchange rates proved very sensitive to
The cost of rate movements in terms of

inflation if currencies went down and in loss of competitiveness when they
went up proved severe.

Many countries found that they were better off

voluntarily limiting their policy freedom and preserving more or less stable
exchange relationships with their main trade partners.
Floating exchange rates performed another service for which they
may not have received enough credit.

When the Bretton Woods system broke

down, there was indeed a policy alternative to floating.

It was to follow

the pattern of the 1930's and maintain fixed rates by means of exchange
controls.

During the 1930's, after the gold standard had broken down, this

alternative was chosen by many European countries in preference to floating.
Flexible rates, it was then thought, might lead to inflation and disorder.




-10-

In the event, exchange control during the 1930's led to a drastic shrinkage
of trade, widespread cessation of free capital movements, and default on
international debts.

Avoiding such consequences in the 1970's probably was

well worth the cost that floating rates have exacted in other respects.
Exchange-rate fluctuations, it turned out, were a great deal wider
than had been expected.

These ups and downs were far more also than could

readily be explained by differential movements in rates of inflation.

Thus,

competitive relationships and current-account balances varied alarmingly.
Nor were bankers, economists, and other experts seemingly at all successful
in predicting future rate movements.

The important role played by interest-

rate differentials, current-account balances, and rates of inflation in
determining exchange rates was generally agreed.

But their relative weight

and quantitative effect seemed to change unpredictably.
Nor did it seem possible to ameliorate exchange-rate fluctuations
substantially by means of intervention.
take place on occasion.
rates responded.

Very heavy intervention did indeed

When it was supported by monetary-policy action,

Most intervention indeed has monetary effects, through

its influence on bank reserves.

But if that influence is sterilized by

central-bank open-market operations, as is routinely the case in the United
States, the remaining effect on the exchange rate is modest.
Wide rate fluctuations have proved troublesome because of their
impact on competitiveness.

When a country's currency is high, protectionist

pressures are likely to develop.

In the end, this might lead to the same

kinds of controls that an attempt to maintain inappropriate fixed rates also
could provoke.




-11-

The volatility of exchange rates has been further enhanced by the
unintended consequences of money-supply targeting.

Under money-supply

targeting, interest rates and, therefore, exchange rates are likely to be
more volatile.

To reduce volatility, money-supply targeting would have to

be given up, or at least modified.

Then it might be possible to coordinate

interest rates internationally and so make exchange rates more stable.
But giving up money-supply targets might mean giving up the prospect of
controlling inflation.

Not only would that be a very high price to pay for

diminished exchange-rate fluctuations.

It would also introduce a new

destabilizing factor into exchange rates.
Nevertheless, it is evident that, among the countries of the
European Monetary System (EMS), wide swings in exchange rates have been
avoided.

Changes in EMS rates have been frequent.

But they have generally

been in the direction likely to produce more balanced current accounts.
There have been very few rate changes in one direction that soon were reversed
by a contrary movement, as has happened where rates have been floating freely.
Given the volatility of rates outside the EMS, this must be adjudged a
considerable advantage.

Moreover, the Bundesbank, for instance, has been

able to reconcile the pursuit of its money-supply target with such degree
of stability as currencies in the EMS have had.

This may be a special

situation attributable to the unique role of the D-mark in the EMS.

But

it may also hold broader lessons for money-supply targeting in general.
As inflation diminishes all around, the volatility of exchange rates
should also diminish.

At this time, a common effort to move toward domestic

stability seems to be the most promising form of international cooperation




12

that Is feasible.

Each country, by putting its own house in better order,

can contribute to the stability of exchange rates generally.

Unemployment
The unhappiest legacy of the 1970's is the high level of unemploy­
ment.

Though differing in degree, unemployment is pervasive around the

::rorld.

Even countries that, by international standards, might be regarded

as having little unemployment, by their own standards perceive their
unemployment to be high.

But while unemployment is troublesome every­

where, the circumstances and processes by which it reached present levels
have differed among countries.

In the United States, for instance, the

1970's saw very little increase in real wages.

There was an increase in

the number of jobs, however, of about 20 million, or almost 25 percent of
the 1970 total labor force, which in turn increased 28 percent.

U.S. employ­

ment, therefore, was associated with a very large increase both in employment
and in the labor force.

Only a minor part of the labor-force increase was

not fully absorbed into employment.
from demographic factors —

This labor-force increase resulted both

the baby boom of the 1950's —

increases in the number of working women.

and from massive

The flood of untrained new workers

may also have had something to do with the low level of productivity gains.
Because real wage increases were about commensurate with productivity gains,
both being very low, the shares of capital and labor in national income did
not change much.




In Europe, on average, unemployment developed under different
circumstances.
moderately.

Real wages grew substantially.

The labor force grew only

New job creation was relatively low.

Productivity gains,

however, fell well below the rate of increase in real wages.

As a result,

the distribution of national income between capital and labor shifted in
favor of labor.

These facis may contain some hints a-' tc at least one of

the causes of high European unemployment —

the size of real wage settle­

ments.

Ordinarily, settlements are in large measure determined by productivity

gains.

But when real wage gains depart substantially from productivity gains,

other factors evidently also have an influence.

One of tnerc is the forceful­

ness with which labor pursues its demands for higher wages.

When real wages

move significantly ahead of productivity, it is bard to avoid the conclusion
that there has been strong pressure on the part of labor and that this has
been a reason, perhaps only one of several, for rising unemployment. This
seems to have been the case of many European countries.
In the United States, the simultaneous stagnation of real wages and
productivity suggests that pressure for higher real wages was more moderate.
This probably helped to absorb the large increase in the labor force and to
keep that increase from pushing unemployment even higher.

In comparing

unemployment levels in Europe and in the United States, it needs to be
remembered that the U.S. unemployment count rests on household surveys rather
than, as in Europe, a count of registered unemployed, and so typically yields
higher numbers.
The most pressing economic and social issue facing the 1980's is
the reduction of unemployment.

Its level almost everywhere is so high that

there is no immediate need to focus on how far it should and can be reduced.




-14-

In the United States it has come to be realized that the noninflationary
level of unemployment unfortunately is higher today than it was in the past.
It is also considerably higher than was thought in the mid-1960's before
the outbreak of inflation indicated that unemployment levels of 4 percent
or less even then were not sustainable without important structural changes
in labor markets.

In any case, however, today's U.S. unemployment level of

about 10-1/2 percent is far above the noninflationary level, which often
now is placed in the range of 6 to 7 percent.

That leaves a very substantial

amount of unemployment to be remedied.
What is the best method of doing this?

The question confronts both

Europe and the United States, but I seem to hear somewhat different answers.
In the United States, it is generally expected that the economy will expand
sufficiently to provide the needed jobs.

During the 1980's, the United

States faces a much more favorable labor-force situation than in the 1970's.
The bulge of the baby boom is largely behind us, and the labor force there­
fore will grow less rapidly.

The many new entrants of the 1970's will have

acquired some experience, will be more easily placeable, and will contribute
more to productivity.

There is little talk in the United States, therefore,

of sharing the work by reducing hours worked.

Indeed, recent social security

legislation raises the retirement age, thus tending to increase the labor
force.

We are aware, of course, that to "share the work" would limit output

and growth, and almost certainly would reignite inflation.

It seems unlikely

that a reduction in hours could be accomplished without some increase in
hourly pay and benefits in order to give the appearance of compensating at
least in part for the individual income loss.




-15In Europe, I hear somewhat different views.

There seems to be a

good deal of discussion of shorter hours, matched by not very clearly defined
changes in hourly pay and weekly take-home pay.

Of course, I cannot judge

the reasons for taking this different approach, but I see many advantages
in the American approach.

Conclusion
In conclusion, as I look at the legacy of the 1970's and what it
means for the 1980's, I find myself moderately hopeful.
many advantages over the 1970's.
tions, and we were disappointed.

The 1980's have

We entered the 1970's with great expecta­
We entered them with belief in the

natural and permanent stability of things like price levels, interest rates,
exchange rates, and asset values, and we were disabused.
have lost our money illusion.

As a result, we

That in some respects makes it harder today

for governments and central banks to do their job.

It is always easier to

conduct economic policy when people do not notice an ongoing moderate
inflation.

But the better understanding of these things by the citizens,

and the resultant prompter reaction of markets to inadequate government
response, is a more fundamental gain.
going to be easy.
do.




We know now that things are not

But I think that we also know better now what we must