View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
TUESDAY, OCTOBER 8, 1974
1:00 P.M. EDT




STRUCTURAL CHANGES IN THE BOND MARKET
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Second Institutional Investor Bond Conference
Waldorf Astoria
New York City
Tuesday, October 8, 1974, 1:00 P.M.

STRUCTURAL CHANGES IN THE BOND MARKET
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Second Institutional Investor Bond Conference
Waldorf Astoria
New York City
Tuesday, October 8, 1974, 1:00 P.M.

In recent weeks I have had numerous occasions to listen to
bond market people, and their views have given me considerable food
for thought.

(That, some said, was the only food the market supplied

these days.)

One school of thought, representing principally buyers,

points to the fact that bonds have stood up better than equities and
that for the time being debt issues have in fact largely replaced
equities.

A second school, representing predominatly sellers, points

to the advantages that banks have in raising and supplying funds in
contrast to the bond market.

In effect, it says that bank credit is

tending to displace open market borrowing and that commercial bankers
are out competing underwriters.
contemporary truth.

Both views, I believe, contain some

In both cases, the underlying cause is inflation.

Let me begin by examining what has been going on in the bond market.




2

The data show that since 1970 the share of total funds
raised by nonfinandal borrowers by means of bond issues declined
from 21 per cent to 8 per cent (year ending June 1974).

Over this

time, the share raised by means of stock issues declined from
6 per cent to less than 4 per cent.

Meanwhile the share of bank

credit rose from less than 7 per cent to 20 per cent.

These shifts,

substantial as they are, do not go beyond the range of fluctuations
experienced in past years.

The accompanying circumstances are

different, however, and they may indeed alter the case and its
significance.
Within the total of recent bond issues, there has been a
variety of departures from customary practices, such as
(a)

a shortening of the maturity of issues, presumably
in order to take advantage of yield relationships
and to increase participation by individual investors;

(b)

a lengthening of the period of call protection;

(c)

a move of some public utilities from competitively
bid offerings to negotiated issues.

These shifts have taken place within the context of a
downward sloping yield structure.
is no absolute abnormality.

On historical grounds, this too,

In fact, it was more nearly the rule in

the bond markets of the 1920!s and earlier.

The premium that the

market places on short-term assets naturally does not make longer







3

term issues easy to sell.

At the same time I draw at least this

much encouragement from a downward sloping yield structure:

it

implies that investors have expected inflation to come down over
the long run.

Present inflation rates have not been fully absorbed

into expectations.
One must not forget that bond investors are compelled to
look to the very distant future if they want to evaluate rationally
the discounted present value of all the payments, including principal,
that they will receive on their bonds.

In fact, more than one-half

of the discounted present value of all future receipts on a 10 per
cent, 30-year bond reflects payments due more than 14 years from
now.

One may wonder how effectively these far distant receipts

are translated into present value and whether an excessive weight
may not be given to the near-term future and to the possibility that
inflation may not come down as rapidly as we would like during that
small stretch of the road that we believe we can see.
I might parenthetically extend that comment to the stock
market.

For a stock with a price/earnings ratio of 10, whose

quotation reflects the discounted present value of all future
earnings, more than one-half of this value represents earnings
expected to accrue after 7 years.

Anyone who notes the wide swings

that have occurred in the price of many stocks, must wonder whether
investors really have so fundamentally changed their mind about events
in the American economy after 1981, or whether they are perhaps giving

4

excessive weight to what they think they see ahead for the next
year.
A second striking feature of the interest rate scene that
has developed of late is, of course, the tiering process.

One can

only specualte whether it is indeed true that risks have increased
so substantially, or whether it is the price of risk, i.e.,
the risk aversion exhibited by the average investor, that
has risen.

The fact remains that high risk premia today greatly

increase the cost of capital and ultimately the price of everything
produced with the aid of capital.

Furthermore, it has become evident

that there is no truly riskless asset left in our economy, if we
take into account the increasingly severe price level risk that
affects even highly liquid short-term assets.

This is of importance

not only to the devotees of the beta factor, the underlying theory of
which demands the existence of riskless asset«

Far more important

is the impact of this circumstance upon the many people in our
economy who need the financial and emotional security that a riskless
asset can provide.

I need hardly add that this is another of the

fruits of inflation.

Innovations
The bond market has responded to the travails of inflation
with a variety of interesting technical innovations.




It would be

5

far preferable, of course, if an ending of inflation made many of
these expedients unnecessary.

Meanwhile, however, the market has

demonstrated an ability to defend itself.
The floating interest rate has been one such development.
It seems to have been generated in the Euro bond market some four
years ago, and has featured in a considerable number of issues of Euro
bonds.

It has not protected that market against the ravages of two-digit

inflation, unless one were to assume that the virtual cessation
of its new issue activity was the result exclusively of the
ending of our interest equalization tax.

Meanwhile the floating

rate principle has leaped across the Atlantic and found embodiment,
with the addition of a put feature, in such issues as the Citicorp
note.

The floating rate poses some very interesting problems for

borrowers and lenders and also for the monetary authority.
For the borrower the floating rate implies an increase in
one form of risk and a reduction in another.

A borrower who must

raise long-term money in order to finance an investment project
with a given rate of return incurs the risk that the rate on his
obligation may rise above that rate of return.

This is a very serious

risk, for instance, for utilities, and for many manufacturing firms.
It makes calculation of the cost of capital impossible.

The borrower,

to be sure, is better off than he would be if he had to finance his
project with short-term money in the hope of rolling over.
He has long-term money (unless he has given a put), but at a




6

short-term rate, depending on what kind of rate the interest on his
obligation is pegged to -- the London interbank rate, the Treasury
bill rate, the commercial paper rate, or whatever.

A utility,

and many types of manufacturing or mining companies, might find
this kind of financing very hard to accept.

A government, which

has control over taxes and money, or a financial institution,
which can adjust the interest rate it charges to those it has to
pay, might find the risk very acceptable.

A financial institution

making long-term commitments, such as a thrift institution writing
mortgages, could, of course, use a floating rate for its liabilities
only if there were flexibility also in the mortgage rate.
Another aspect of the borrower’s risk, however, is
reduced by a floating rate.

That is the risk that his timing in

issuing a long-term obligation might be bad and that he might find
himself caught with a rate higher than that paid by his competitors
until the obligation matures, or at least to the call date.
With a floating rate, the borrower always pays what others
pay who borrow in similar form.

Of course, a difference might still

develop between him and a competitor who borrowed on a regular long­
term bond.

But if the short-long rate relationship returned to its

predominant upward-sloping form, the spread would still work out in
favor of the floating rate borrower.




7

It is the reduction of the timing risk that creates a problem
for the monetary authority.

Monetary restraint in part at least

works through the hesitancy that a borrower must feel if he has to
commit himself to a high rate for a long time if he finances during
a period of restraint.

If that concern is lifted from the borrower,

he may be willing to finance even at very high rates, knowing that
he will not be penalized for that decision when rates come down.
Floating rates may weaken the effectiveness of monetary policy, or
at least require policymakers to increase the degree of restraint in
order to achieve the same effect.
To conclude this subject, I would point out that a floating
rate obligation is the nearest thing we have today to an indexed bond.
Bond insurance is another innovation, discussion of which has
gained relevance in the present state of the bond market.

It is not a

completely new feature, because the market has produced its own institu­
tions to perform that function at least for municipal bonds.

Evidently

the innovators had diagnosed a market need, where particular borrowers
were so little known, or restricted by other circumstances in their
access to the open capital market, as to be able to benefit from
insurance.
Today, bond insurance is beind discussed, not in relation
to small or relatively weak borrowers, but in the context of the sudden
dramatic borrowing difficulties of some very well known enterprises
which have long had unquestioned access to the bond market -- principally




8

enterprises in the utilities industry.

It has been proposed to

provide government-sponsored bond insurance, financed by premium
payments of the insured but ultimately backstopped by government
money, in order to restore adequate borrowing power to these
enterprises at a cost that would avoid the risk premium imposed by
the market.
The proposal has characteristics that make it worth study
even though one may well find that its negative features outweigh
the positive.

Insurance in the form of a pooling of risks generally

is more efficient than self-insurance which takes the form of a risk
premium charged to each particular borrower.

But that is the case

only when the risk to be insured involved a substantial random factor.
When there is a common risk affecting the entire group of insurance
buyers, pooling that risk does not help.

The premium rate required

to cover the risk for all will be no smaller than the premium rate
required to cover an average single insurance buyer.

This might

well be the case of the utilities industry.
This reasoning leads to the conclusion that the proposed
kind of bond insurance would have to charge a very high premium if
that premium is to cover the risk adequately, or else would have to
rely importantly on an ultimate backing by government.




The latter

9

possibility in turn lends strength to the concern that a government
guarantee might be only a first step on the road to greater
government involvement in private industry than one would like to
see.

The second question that must be raised about any bond
insurance scheme concerns its effect on the allocation of capital.
If a scheme could be developed to make bonds free from credit risk
and therefore virtually as good as government bonds, what would be
the results?

Yield differentials among bonds would largely disappear,

and so would the effect of these differentials in steering capital
into the most productive uses.

Perhaps a complicated scheme of

gearing the insurance premia to be paid by borrowers to each
borrower1s individual risk might be designed to help offset this
effect.

In any event, the volume of bond issues might greatly

increase, thereby possibly displacing other borrowers from the
market,

I see no need to pursue hypothetical speculations about

this intriguing subject any further, but I hope that I have said
enought to indicate that bond insurance raises many fundamental
questions that should give pause to its advocates.




10

Bonds and Banks
The innovative thinking in the bond market that I have
examined may help the bond market in defending its share of total
financing against the competition of bank credit.
have been highly innovative competitors of late.

The banks certainly
Underwriters to

whom I have listened seem to think that big banks have a built-in
advantage in providing credit because it is easier to use one's own
money than to find money from other people.




In the present situation

they may have a point although it needs to be remembered that banks,
too, use other people’s money.

In an age of liability management

they have to go out to find it rather than wait for it to come.
Underwriters also seem to think that the banks have a
special advantage by virtue of the Federal Reserve role as a lender
of last resort.

It needs to be remembered that the Federal Reserve's

role is concerned with safeguarding the market and the depositor,
not the management and the shareholder.
The issue of bond versus bank financing is essentially the
issue of intermediated (indirect) versus direct financing.

The

advantages of intermediation are well known -- risk pooling, expertise
in financing, economies of scale, and the possibility of maturity
transformation, i.e., the conversion of short-term money into longer
term money.

These advantages, however, have never been sufficiently

decisive to tilt the balance very far in favor of term lending by banks

11

as against bonds.

The individual bond buyer for a while had largely

vanished from the markets, but he has returned.

Even in the short-term

market direct financing in the form of commercial paper in recent years
has competed with successfully against intermediated credit.
I find it hard to believe that a balance that has been maintained
for such a long time, between bank financing and bond financing, even
though with very substantial fluctuations, should become permanently
disturbed.

There are financial systems in which the great preponderance

of financing has been through the banking system and where the bond
market has played only a modest role, such as that of Japan.

It is

my understanding, however, that the Japanese authorities, who are
very deliberate about the structure of their financial markets and
institutions, do not regard that situation as optimal.

A good bond

market is a major asset for an economy.
I think we can look with a fair amount of pride at the workings
of our markets in a time of rate structure, competition for funds and
uncertainties such as it has never seen before during the lifetime of
anyone presently in the market.

The bond market, in my judgment has

responded to this time of unprecedented difficulties with courage,
vitality and intelligence.
There is a heavy bond calendar ahead.

That is to say, our

money market has not clammed shut in the face of current high interest
rates as has the Eurodollar market.




The fact that a strong crop of

12

issues is coming to market indicates that money managers share my
view that the market has the vitality to continue to function despite
the heights to which it must currently climb on the rate structure to
obtain funds.
This is not merely an expression of sentiment on my part.
These indications of doggedness and vitality in the money market
are heartening, for they suggest that the forecasts one hears of
imminent collapse of the financial system are highly premature.
The fact that the market has continued to function, and even to do so
with a certain degree of grace under pressure, has been a major factor
in shaping my conviction that our financial system--far from approaching
a state of collapse--has reserves of strength and resourcefulness left,
and that no collapse is either imminent or likely.

In my view, the

fact that the market is continuing to schedule a large amount of
offerings is further evidence that the financial doomsayers among us
are wrong.
I think, further, that the market has moved intelligently
along the precipices it has had to traverse in recent times.

As I

have indicated, it has responded with innovations, new or borrowed,
but innovations that have tended to meet the prevailing uncertainties
and unprecedented conditions in mature and thoughtful ways.




13

A case in point, and a case very much to the point at the
moment, is the market*s response to the recent decline of short-term
rates.

There have been many who interpreted this as evidence that

the Federal Reserve had let go, and reversed direction, moving away
from the policy of careful restraint of the past year and more.
bond market, I think, has reacted much more rationally.

The

If it had

joined in interpreting the slight relaxation of recent weeks as an
abandonment by the Federal Reserve of its fight against inflation,
and if there had been an expectation of sharply increasing supplies
of credit in relation to demand, the reaction in the money market
could have been very pronounced.

No such reaction has taken place.

No such reaction should have taken place.

In this, as in many other

instances during the season of stress the market has had to endure,
I think it has shown a high degree of commendable caution and realism.