View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Monday, MAY 22, 1978
10:00 A.M. EDT




Statement by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Before the
United States Senate
Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs
Anti-Inflation Hearings
Washington, D.C.
Monday, May 22, 1978

I am pleased to peasant before this distinguished Counnittee
my personal views on the subject of tax-based incomes policies (TIP).
Among the several versions of TIP that have been under discussion,
r y testimony will focus on the approach colloquially referred to
a
as the "stick approach," on which Professor Sidney Weintraub of
the University of Pennsylvania and I have collaborated since 1971.
The stick version of TIP seeks to restrain inflation by imposing
a tax on employers granting excessive wage increases.
interference with the forces of the market:

There is no

employers who, for some

reason, wish to raise wages substantially, can do so; TIP, therefore,
in no way involves wage and price controls.
Various other forms of TIP have been proposed, especially
the "carrot" approach, which rewards employers and employees for
maintaining moderation in wage increases.

A few comnents on the

differences between the two approaches will be made later in this
testimony.

I would like to stress, however, that what counts at

this time is the general principle rather than the specifics.

What

needs to be examined now is whether any form of TIP can contribute
to restraining inflation, rather than whether one or the other version
may be preferable.
If other well-functioning weapons against inflation were
readily available, there would be no need to discuss TIP.

It is

because the orthodox method* work slowly that leads me to believe
that a device such as TIP, despite its obvious inconvenience«?,
deserves consideration at this time.




- 2 -

Fiscal and monetary policy, the orthodox weapons against
inflation, so far have not been successful in winding it down.

This

does not mean that they would be without effect in the long run.

Nor

do 1 believe that the cost of applying them, measured against realistic
alternatives, would be as high as is sometimes believed.

The alternative

to successfully combating inflation is not a constant rate of inflation.
We do not have the choice between doing something about inflation and
leaving it alone.

Left alone, it will accelerate.

This tendency

results from the fact that inflation increases the degree of uncer­
tainty with which all participants in the market must cope.

Thus

business, labor, borrowers, lenders will all tend to inject mounting
insurance premia into their wage, price, and interest rate behavior
to guard against the contingency of higher inflation.

Inflation

itself tends to generate accelerating inflation unless effectively
restrained.

Accelerating inflation, however, means sure recession

sooner or later.

The cost of letting inflation run, therefore, is

higher than even a costly form of restraining it.
TIP, moreover, should not be viewed as an outright alternative
to monetary and fiscal restraint.

In 1971, wage and price controls

were viewed as such an alternative, and fiscal and monetary policy
accordingly turned expansive.

I do not believe that TIP could

offset the consequences of excessively expansive monetary and fiscal
policies.

Some restraint by use of these traditional tools will continue

to be needed.




-3 Nevertheless, an appropriate combination of TIP and
the standard tools of fiscal and monetary policy offers great
promise for the longer run, once the present inflation has been
wound down.

TIP, continuously employed, would exert continuous

restraint on wages and prices.

This means that fiscal and monetary

policies could be somewhat more expansionary once reasonable price
stability has been restored.

TIP would tend to reduce the "noninfla-

tionary rate of unemployment."

Whatever the level of unemployment

consistent with reasonable price stability (or a constant rate of
inflation), the restraints imposed by TIP would tend to make it
somewhat lower.

Fuller utilization of resources and larger output

would thus become possible.

The payoff to a successful effort to

wind down inflation would thus become very large over time.

Distinctive Features of Carrot and Stick Approach
Both approaches rest on the well documented fact that
prices follow wages.
conclusion.

Numerous researchers have arrived at that

At the same time, of course, prices influence wages,

although the relationship is less close.

There are other cost

factors that often are claimed to be responsible for inflation high profits, high interest rates, monopolistic practices, high
prices of food, of oil, and the depreciation of the dollar.

While

at times each of these does exert an effect, the main factor governing




- 4 -

prices nevertheless is wages.

With about 75 per cent of national

income representing compensation of labor, it could not be other­
wise.

All other elements, although at times possibly significant,

are bound to be small by comparison.
means restraint'of prices.

Therefore, restraint of wages

Labor does not lose from wage restraint.

Whatever it gives up in the form of higher wage increases, it can
expect to get back in the form of lower price increases.
Such unchanging real wage gains as wages and prices
decelerate is all that the stick approach offers.

The carrot

approach offers that, plus the benefits from a tax bonus.

The

stick approach operates by shifting the balance of bargaining
power between management and labor.

The carrot approach breaks

into the wage-price cycle by providing a tax bonus for wage earners —
and possibly price setters -- conditional on wage and price restraint.
There are further differences inherent in the two approaches.
One difference is implicit in the fact that adherence to a carrot
scheme can be made voluntary but also would probably have to be
made universally accessible.

The stick approach would have to be

mandatory but could be limited to a group of the largest firms.
Another difference would result if the carrot approach were so
formulated as to require meeting a wage guideline accurately on
penalty of losing the carrot.

The stick approach proposes the

penalty to be scaled to the degree of overshooting of the guideline.




- 5 Finally there is the fact that ':» nks to i.3 yolantary character
ia
and availability of a reward the cac:dt approach should be more
readily acceptable while the stick approach avoids a revenue loss
and may even yield additional revenues.
1/
Form of Tax Under Stick Approach
A penalty in the form of an increase in the corporate income
tax rate, equal to soma multiple of the excess of a wage increase over
a guideline, is one of several options.

It would have the advantage

of relative difficulty of shifting the burden to consumers.

It would

have the disadvantage, on the other hand, of uneven impact as between
capita’ intensive and labor intensive firms.
,

Also, it would not be

applicable to firms with losses, although such firms are perhaps
less likely to grant excessive wage increases.

The difficulty of

applying an incomes tax penalty to unincorporated business, nonprofit
institutions, and governments, would not weigh heavily if TIP is
applied only to a limited group of large corporations.
Disallowance of an excess wage increase for corporate tax
purposes would be a second option.

It has the advantage of simplicity

and of having been on the statute books on prior occasions.

Its main

disadvantage is greater shiftability.
A payroll tax offers a third option.

Against the advantage

of simplicity of administration stands the fact that it appears to
penalize labor when the purpose of the tax is to exert pressure on
management.

1/ These and many other technical aspects are examined by Richard E.
Slitor in a report, "Tax-Based Incomes Policy: Technical and Administrative
Aspects," prepared for the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.




-6 The Guideline
The setting of a guideline for nonexcessive wage increases
is not as critical a decision within the TIP framework as is some­
times argued.

The consequences of a relatively high guideline can

be compensated by more severe penalties for overshooting.

The

likelihood that a relatively low guideline will be frequently over­
shot can be compensated by a more moderate penalty.

The concern

that a guideline will become the minimum rather than the maximum
should be largely allayed by the favorable effects of a guideline on
wage setting in smaller firms, unincorporated businesses, and other
employers that probably would not be covered.

The guideline should

embody the well-known principle that nationwide rather than industry
or firm-wide productivity gains are the proper standard for wage increases.
The g-aideline would be the sum of this long-term nationwide productivity
trend and an amount, such as perhaps one-half of the going rate of
inflation, that would allow for the fact that inflation must be wound
down gradually rather than overnight.

At the present time, this sum

aiight be 5.5 per cent, reflecting 2 per cent for productivity and 3.5
per cent for inflation.

The guideline would have to be reset periodically,

perhaps annually, at lower levels ideally, until wage increases equal
productivity gains.
If prices follow wages, as can be expected, labor would
not suffer from accepting a moderate guideline even if, at the
original rate of inflation, this guideline seemed to leave no room for
real wage increases.




As inflation decelerates, real wage gains will

- 7be restored to their normal level, i.e., on average equal to average
productivity gains.

Costing the Wage Increase
To establish the tax consequences of overshooting the
wage guideline, exact costing of a bargaining agreement including
all types of fringes, is necessary.

This requires measuring the

total increase in compensation, including pensions, medical benefits,
cost-of-living adjustments, improvements in working conditions,
and others.

It also becomes necessary to determine the increase

per employee, or per hour worked, or per hour worked in each
differently paid employee category.

In all probability, the best

approach would be an index of increases covering all employee
categories, weighted by hours worked.
For both types of calculation -- total increase in compensation,
and the per cent increase for a given firm -- there are well established
precedents.

The Internal Revenue Service continually has to deal

with the question of what constitutes compensation and what does not.
From the experience of the Council on Wage and Price Stability and
before it that of the Pay Board, which administered wage controls
during Phase Two, the problems involved in costing out a percentage
increase are familiar.

They are not simple, but they would yield

to careful writing of regulations.




The task would be made easier

- 8 -

if the number of firms to be covered is limited.

It would be eased

also by the fact that small differences between taxpayers and the
IRS would have only small consequences in terms of the penalty
to be assessed under a graduated penalty scheme.
If a surcharge on the corporate income tax is employed
as the tax "stick," the unit for which the wage increase must be
computed clearly must be the parent corporation, rather than
particular subsidiaries or plants.

This means that a number of

bargaining units may be involved, with different wage settlements.
The fact that in such a situation management would be impelled by
TIP to resist all wage increase demands, both high and low, is not a
disadvantage, however.

Wage restraint, to the extent possible, should

be applied with equal strength at all margins.

Coverage
Conceptually, TIP can be applied to all employers, including
unincorporated business, nonprofit institutions, and governments.
Penalties other than the corporate income tax would, of course, have
to be employed for some of these.

In practice, limiting applicability

to the largest thousand or two thousand firms seems preferable from
an administrative point of view.

The largest one thousand firms alone

cover about 26 per cent of all nongovernmental payroll employees.
These firms also are the pattern setters for wages so long as the
economy is not overheating.
uncovered employers restra




The..existence of a guideline should help
i confronting them.
s

- 9 -

Narrow coverage would reduce a number of troublesome
administrative problems.

Among these are problems of new firms,

and of merging or splitting firms.
One possible defect is inherent in narrower coverage.
The closeness o f the relation of prices and wages may diminish if
'
coverage is incomplete.

A loosening of this linkage could, of

course, occur in special circumstances.

A manner of dealing with

it is outlined in the next section.

Restraining an Increase in Profits
In terms of nationwide averages, prices move with wages.
Under some circumstances, the link may loosen, some of these instances
are not capable of being remedied.

For instance, a decline in

productivity, a rise in oil prices, and the consequences of a drop in
the dollar, are "real" phenomena which affect the availability of
goods.

They are bound to affect real wages.

This is not the case,

however, of a loosening of the linkage of wages and prices that is
reflected in a change in profit margins.

In the unlikely event that

deceleration of wages should fail to be followed by deceleration of
prices without any of the above noted factors being present, profit
margins would widen.

The share of profits in GNP, in that event,

would rise as a consequence of wage restraint.
This contingency could be guarded against by changing the
corporate profits tax rate in such a way as to restore the after-tax




- 10 share of profits to its previous level.

In order to eliminate the

influence of purely cyclical factors, some benchmark for the profit
share based on historical relationships might be established.

A tax

designed to hold profits down to this share could be regarded as an
"excess profits tax" on the profits of the entire corporate sector.
It would fall on corporations with high and low earnings.

It would

probably have a very moderate impact, thereby avoiding the familiar
drawbacks of an excess profits tax geared to the profits of particular
enterprises.

Given the close historical link between wages and

prices, this "corporate sector excess profits tax" probably would
rarely, if ever, be triggered.

But its existence would serve as a

protection against an adverse shift in the distribution of income.

Revenues
Neither the penalty tax on excess wage increases nor the
"corporate sector excess profits tax" are intended to raise revenue
although they may do so.

Any revenue that does accrue could be

employed to reduce income taxes.

The amounts raised by the penalty

tax depend, of course, on the level at which the guideline would
be set and on the penalty rate on overshooting these guidelines.
The objectives in setting rates should be not the raising of revenue,
but the optimal functioning of TIP.