View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Expected at 10:00 AM (E .S .T.)
March 23, 1984




Statement by
Henry C. Walllch
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Finance
United States Senate

The U.S. Trade D e fic it:

Causes, Consequences and Policy Options

SUMMARY POINTS
1.

The strong d o lla r and our large trade and current account d e fic its are

related 1n a fundamental sense to the large federal budget d e fic it .
2.

Import re strictin g actions, whether broadly or narrowly applied, are

contrary to the national Interest of the United States, except where foreign
competition Is judged to be unfair as defined by our trade acts.
3.

The only appropriate policy prescription fo r beginning to deal with the

trade and current account d e fic its and avoid an excessively strong d o lla r, in my
view, is to reduce the structural d e fic it In our federal budget.

Other proposals

fo r reducing the external d e fic its without reducing the budget d e fic it would, i f
successful, only s h ift the Impact of our nation's budget problems by putting
upward pressure on real Interest rates.




The U.S. Trade D e fic it:

Causes, Consequences and Policy Options

The U.S. merchandise trade and current account d e fic its widened considerably
during 1983.

For 1983 as a whole, the trade d e fic it exceeded $60 b illio n , and by

the fourth quarter i t had reached a $75 b illio n annual rate.

The current account

was in d e fic it by more than $40 b illio n for the year as a whole, and reached a
$60 b illio n annual rate in the fourth quarter.

Many are predicting that the

current account d e fic it w ill be around $80 b illio n for 1984 as a whole, and the
trade d e fic it around $100 b illio n .
Causes of the External D e ficits
It is customary to analyze changes in the external d e fic its by focusing on
proximate causes, such as changes in exchange rates and the growth of economic
a c tiv ity at home and abroad.

In that tra d itio n , the widening of the external

d e fic its can be related, f i r s t and foremost, to the very substantial appreciation
of the d o lla r and the conditions that have given ris e to the appreciation.

On a

weighted-average basis against the currencies of the other major industrial
countries, the d o lla r has appreciated by more than 45 percent since the fourth
quarter of 1980, when our current account balance was showing a small surplus.
Some of the appreciation has reflected our re la tiv e ly good in fla tio n performance,
but even in real terms — adjusted for changes in consumer price levels — the
weighted-average value of the d o lla r is now nearly 40 percent higher than i t was
at the end of 1980, and roughly 25 percent higher than it s average for the entire
floating rate period since 1973.

Against the European currencies the

appreciation in real terms has come to 30 percent against the Swiss franc, 45
percent against the German mark, and higher amounts against the weaker
currencies.

Against the Japanese yen the d o lla r has risen 20 percent in real

terms; against the Canadian d o lla r i t has depreciated s lig h tly .




-

2-

The cy clic a l behavior of the U.S. and foreign economies has been a second
factor contributing both to the time p ro file and to the widening of the U.S.
trade d e fic it .

The U.S. recession held down imports and thus delayed the rise in

the trade d e fic it until a fte r the middle of 1982, and the re la tiv e ly rapid
expansion of the U.S. economy in 1983 was a dominant element in la st year's trade
developments, accounting for more than half of the $30 b illio n increase in our
trade d e fic it from the fourth quarter of 1982 to the fourth quarter of 1983.
As a third factor, the external financing problems of some countries,
especially of our neighbors 1n Latin America, have resulted in lower exports to
these countries.
A fourth factor has been the fa ilu re in the past of some of our industries
to adjust adequately to the pressures of International competition.
While the strong d o lla r and our large external d e fic its re fle c t, in part,
our improved macroeconomic performance and the greater return on financial
Investment in th is country, in a more fundamental sense they are related to the
budget d e f ic it .

When the U.S. government runs a d e f ic it , other sectors must, on

balance, finance 1t.

Part of the financing has been provided by foreigners in

the form of the net capital inflow that is the counterpart of the current account
d e f ic it .

The remainder of the financing has been provided by private domestic

residents and state and local governments, which has diverted resources from
productive domestic capital formation.

Naturally, the net capital inflow and the

surplus of private domestic saving over private domestic investment have not
arisen automatically, but have had to be induced. As a re su lt, real interest
rates have been higher then they would otherwise have been.

In addition, the

higher real interest rates have been associated with upward pressure on the




-3d o lla r: such upward pressure has prevailed over whatever downward pressure may
have emanated from the external d e f ic it , which usually is a negative element in
the market's evaluation of a currency.

Thus the d o lla r has risen.

In th is way,

high real Interest rates, the strong d o lla r, and large external d e fic its are a ll
linked to large federal budget d e fic its .
Consequences of the D e ficits and the Strong Dollar
Some of the damaging consequences of the d e fic its and the strong d o lla r are
reflected 1n the decline in our exports. In value terms, exports declined by
%
about $25 b illio n from the fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of 1983,
with two-thirds of the drop accounted fo r by a 40 percent contraction of
shipments to Latin America, mainly to Mexico, and the other th ird reflecting a 15
percent reduction 1n shipments to Western Europe.

It is noteworthy that exports

to both Japan and Canada expanded somewhat from 1980 to 1983.
In volume terms, our merchandise exports were more than 15 percent lower in
the fourth quarter of 1983 than 1n the fourth quarter of 1980.

Exports of

capital goods declined by more than 25 percent 1n volume terms, exports of
nonagricultural industrial supplies by more than 20 percent, and exports of
agricultural products by about 10 percent.

The longer exports remain depressed,

the more d if f ic u lt It becomes to maintain marketing networks, and the more costly
and d if f ic u lt 1t becomes to recover foreign sales.
If our current account d e fic it were to continue for long at the rate of
around $80 b illio n that 1s lik e ly to be recorded 1n 1984, the United States would
soon become an International debtor country.

At the end of 1983, the United

States had an estimated International net cred itor position of about $125
b illio n .

This balance could be pushed to the minus side in l i t t l e more than one




-4year.

Our position as an International creditor has been a major support to our

balance of payments so fa r.

Thanks to the very productive character of some of

our foreign assets, the United States had a surplus of investment income
averaging more than $30 b illio n annually during the years 1979-81.

This has

meant that we have been able to tolerate a sizable trade d e fic it without thereby
incurring a d e fic it in the current account, which combines services and trade.
If our International position sh ifts to that of a debtor country, th is advantage
w ill be eroded; indeed, i t is estimated that our surplus of investment income
f e ll below $25 b illio n in 1983.

Eventually, the United States might find it s e lf

in the position of having to earn a surplus in the trade balance in order to
cover a d e fic it on investment income.

Other things equal, the larger the net

debtor position we build up, the lower w ill be the value of the d o lla r necessary
in the long run to generate the required trade balance.
In addition, I might say that, for one of the richest countries in the
world, i t seems hardly appropriate either to be borrowing currently on a massive
scale from the rest of the world or to be a net debtor to i t .
The external d e fic it also has a strong bearing on the future of the d o lla r.
I have noted the severe appreciation the d o llar has experienced against a number
of currencies, which has been one — but only one — of the reasons for the trade
d e f ic it .

As the United States continues to borrow abroad and moves toward net

debtor status, causing the rest of the world to hold ever larger amounts of
dollar-denominated assets, the good acceptance that our currency has had in the
world may wear out.

Nobody can predict the timing, but in the longer run i t

seems probable that the dollar-depressing effect of the external d e fic it w ill
begin to overwhelm the dollar-supporting effect of higher interest rates.




-5I do not believe, therefore, that the current value of the d o lla r is
sustainable, although i t is impossible to predict the sequence or timing of
events that w ill bring i t down.

If the d o llar does decline substantially while

the budget d e fic it remains unchanged, the external d e fic it w ill, with a lag, also
decline.

That would reduce, in a sense, the magnitude of the problem that this

Committee is addressing.

It would also, however, intensify other problems

created by the budget d e f ic it .

With a return of the external sector toward

balance, the foreign financing of the budget d e fic it would cease.

It would have

to be financed entirely at home, absorbing a s t i l l higher fraction of scarce
available savings, thereby raising interest rates.

The "crowding out" resulting

from the budget d e f ic it , which now goes in part against the foreign-trade related
sectors of the U.S. economy and in part only against other sectors of the
economy, would then be directed fu lly against the other sectors.

This needs to

be emphasized in order to make clear that a reduction or ending in the external
d e f ic it , without a reduction in the budget d e f ic it , would only s h ift the impact
of our nation's budget problems without resolving them.
The impacts of the external d e fic it and the strong d o lla r have been fe lt by
our manufacturing industries, the agricultural sector, and some of our services
industries.

The effects are adverse not only for exports, but also for domestic

import-competing sectors.
quite well absorbed.

On the whole, nevertheless, these impacts have been

The American economy has expanded strongly.

This has

offset some of the pressure of mounting import competition deriving from a strong
d o lla r.

Moreover, some of the industries that have suffered from import

competition are in that condition more because of factors sp e cific to th e ir
industry than because of the high d o lla r.




Industries that have fa iled to invest

-6and reduce costs, have not kept up with modern technology, and in some cases have
paid wages fa r above the national average for production workers, are bound to
suffer even at a lower level of the d o lla r.
Aside from such industry-specific problems, I do not see the United States
being deindustralized.

The combined domestic and foreign demand for U.S.

industrial output has increased since 1980.

In p a rticu la r, the industrial

production index for manufacturing is currently almost 7-1/2 percent higher than
it s level at the end of 1980, when the d o llar began to appreciate.

Employment in

the manufacturing sector, on the other hand, is currently 3-1/2 percent below it s
level at the end of 1980, partly reflecting re la tiv e ly rapid productivity growth
in the manufacturing sector, which h is to ric a lly has contributed to a negative
trend in the share of manufacturing employment 1n total private employment.
Arguments Against Import Restrictions
My purpose in citin g these s ta tis tic s is to counsel strongly against
additional import restriction s at th is juncture as a means of dealing with the
trade d e fic it .

The type of import restricting actions authorized by Section 122

of the Trade Act, which would apply on a broad and uniform basis, are certainly
contrary to the national interest of the United States.

Thanks to the strong

economic recovery last year, our tradeable-goods industries as a group have not
been severely injured on balance.

Their circumstances cannot ju s tify additional

import re strictio n s , except where foreign competition is judged to be unfair as
defined by our trade acts.




-7The costs of import protection are well known.

The decision to protect one

industry invariably Imposes costs elsewhere in the economy.

It is costly to

other industries i f foreign countries re ta lia te against U.S. exports, of i f
Import restrictio n s lead to higher d o lla r exchange rates than would otherwise
p re va il, or i f the prices they must pay for inputs ris e .
leads also to higher prices and less choice for consumers.

Protection ty p ic a lly
An example of the

consequences of protection for consumers we now observe in the recent very high
p ro fits of the automobile Industry, which is protected by "voluntary" export
restraints in Japan.

F in a lly , protected Industries ty p ic a lly delay making the

adjustments that are necessary i f they are ever to stand on th e ir own feet.
These costs should make us hesitant even to reciprocate against foreign
protectionist actions.

Retaliatory measures taken by us damage our own

Interests, whatever they may do to foreigners.
Reducing the trade d e fic it by protectionist methods without reducing the
budget d e fic it would not resolve our problems.

It w u ld certainly not ease the

pressures on our export Industries which, thanks to tfte d isc ip lin e of
International competition, are bound to be among our most e ffic ie n t.
Other Policy Options
The appropriate policy presciptlon for dealing with the trade d e fic it and
the excessively strong d o lla r, 1n my view, is to reduce the structural d e fic it in
our federal budget.

Controls on trade or on capital inflows, or any other

proposals fo r reducing the external d e fic its without reducing the budget d e f ic it ,
would only s h ift the impact of our nation's budget problems by pushing up real
interest rates.




-8You have asked, as w ell, for an analysis of whether the floating exchange
rate system I ts e lf may have contributed to our problems.
floating rate system has served us f a ir ly well.

In my view, the

Swings in exchange rates over

the past decade, to be sure, have been extremely wide.

But many of these swings

can be related mainly to changes in the rela tive outlooks fo r interest rates,
Inflation and real growth in d ifferent countries.

A good part of the changes in

re la tiv e economic outlooks in turn can be related to changes in monetary and
fisc a l p o lic ie s .

Given the stances of monetary and fis c a l p o licie s in the United

States and abroad during the past four or fiv e years, i t is hard to believe that
the Bretton Woods system of pegged exchange rates would have survived, and
certain ly not without major upward adjustments 1n the exchange value of the
d o lla r.

Greater s ta b ility of exchange rates, which 1s greatly to be desired,

must be founded in the f i r s t place on greater domestic s ta b ilit y 1n a ll
countries, and on p o licie s supporting th is s t a b ilit y .
F in a lly , you raised the question of whether the d o lla r 1s overvalued.
view, the meaningful answer to th is question 1s yes.

In my

It 1s sometimes argued, to

be sure, that whatever exchange rate prevails in the market at any moment
balances demand and supply and therefore cannot be over or undervalued.
however, begs the question.

That,

Interpreting the question as referring to the effect

of the exchange rate on the economic magnitudes in which th is Committee is
interested, such as the trade balance or the current account, 1t seems evident
that the recent value of the d o lla r has been c le a rly Inconsistent with even very
approximate balance 1n either the trade or the current account and that,
therefore, in th is sense, the d o lla r is overvalued.




Given th is interpretation of our situation , the right policy prescription
for dealing with the trade d e fic it is to deal with the circumstance that is at
the root of the high d o lla r. This brings me back to the need to reduce the
structural d e fic it in our federal budget.

Such action, of course, would not cure

a ll the diverse problems encountered in the various sectors of our economy.

But

a substantial adjustment of the budget toward balance, other things equal, would
lead to declines in real interest rates, a depreciation of the d o lla r in exchange
markets, and (with some lag) a reduction in the external d e fic its .

Recent

statements by the President and members of Congress, such as the statement of the
Chairman of th is Committee announcing these hearings, give hope that some
progress may be made in that direction.

I hope that my remarks have conveyed the

message that the strong d o lla r and large external d e fic its are partly symptoms,
themselves damaging, of large budget d e fic its .

I hope as well that the Congress

and the Administration w ill re sist temptations to try to suppress the symptoms
without curing the disease.