View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
WEDNESDAY, DECEMBER 28, 1977
12:30 P.M. EST

REFLECTIONS ON THE U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
joint luncheon of the
American Economic Association and American Finance Association




New York City
Wednesday, December 28, 1977

REFLECTIONS ON THE U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
joint luncheon of the
American Economic Association and American Finance Association
New York City
Wednesday, December 28, 1977

As we look, from the year end watershed, upon what happened
in 1977 and what is likely to happen in 1978, we can derive some
satisfaction from progress made and progress that we have reason to
believe lies ahead.

In international comparison, the United States

economy did well in 1977 and seems likely to hold its own in 1978.
Nevertheless we face serious challenges.

At home, while growth has been

reasonably satisfactory, unemployment and inflation continue at
excessive levels.

Important adjustments, such as in the energy

field, remain to be made.

Internationally, we confront a very large

current account deficit and have witnessed a substantial decline in
the dollar.

These are matters to keep in mind as we count such

blessings as we have.




-2We operate under an exchange rate regime in which it has
been accepted that underlying economic and financial factors are to
govern the level and movement of exchange rates.

In the long run,

I believe that this is not just a prescription for exchange market
policy, but an imperative of economic life.

Unrealistic exchange

rates cannot long be sustained in a world in which the flows of goods,
services, and particularly capital are gratifyingly free and are
becoming increasingly large.
In the short run, to be sure, exchange rates can be influenced
by factors other than these fundamentals.

Uncertainties, erroneous

perceptions and destabilizing speculation are likely to bring about
such departures from time to time.

In recent months, the exchange markets

seem to have been passing through such a period.

In particular, I believe

that erroneous perceptions have played a role in the recent turbulence
of the market.
One such erroneous perception seems to have been an apparently
widespread belief that the United States is practicing so called "benign
neglect" with respect to the value of its currency.

This conclusion

many market participants seem to have derived from the fact that U.S.
exchange market intervention, although rising of late, has been con­
ducted on a relatively moderate scale.

In my view, any thought that

the United States is unconcerned about the value of its currency, and
perhaps even would like to see it decline in order to gain a trade
advantage, is altogether erroneous.

The United States has many reasons

to want its currency to be as strong as the fundamentals would justify.




-3First, we have learned that exchange rate depreciation
contributes significantly to inflation.

This has been the lesson

of the devaluation of 1971 and subsequent exchange rate movements.
Prior to that, it had been widely thought that the small size of
our foreign sector meant that the dollar rate had almost no influence
on the domestic price level.

Experience has shown that depreciation

influences prices beyond the export and import sectors.

Domestic

prices are influenced also through the mechanism of competition.
A depreciation of the dollar reduces competition for a wide range
of domestically sold goods.

Moreover, since 1971, the foreign

sector of the U.S. economy has increased from 6 per cent of GNP
to 10 per cent.

The American economy has become more open.

Thus

the immediate impact of exchange rates on domestic prices has also
increased.
The price of oil is another important factor that may be
influenced by the exchange rate of the dollar.

Some OPEC spokesmen

have said that their decisions with regard to the price of oil will
be influenced by what happens to the dollar.

Although it seems clear

to me that this is not a valid argument and that the OPEC would
damage their own interests by raising the price of oil, one must
recognize that the price of oil is of enormous significance.
Third, the usefulness of the dollar as a reserve, trade,
and investment currency, both to the United States and to the world,
depends on the dollar remaining an attractive asset.

The United

States draws advantages from this international role of the




-4dollar.

It facilitates, for instance, the smooth financing of

a large current account deficit.

But we must bear in mind that

a currency in which the assets of official and private parties
are denominated will always tend to be compared with whatever are
the strongest major currencies at the time.
the returns

Investors will compare

from holding dollar-denominated assets with the returns

available on assets denominated in other currencies, making allowance
for differential interest rates and exchange rate movements.

If a

widespread feeling should gain ground among investors that dollar
assets are unattractive, an effort to get out of these assets into
other currencies could produce great instability.
Finally, the value of the dollar influences business
conditions abroad.

When the value of an asset that is so widely

held becomes uncertain, the plans of businesses and households may
be upset, leading possibly to a reduction in investment and perhaps
even consumption abroad.

When the dollar declines sharply, profits

in export industries and import-competing industries abroad shrink,
and so does investment.

The world's recovery from recession, which

is proceeding at a painfully slow pace, could be further slowed, unless
countries abroad are able to take advantage of such added

slack

to engage in additional stimulation.
U.S. interest in a strong dollar is undeniable.

It would

be a mistake, however, to say that this interest should be measured
by the scale of U.S. intervention in the exchange market.

U.S.

intervention has been adequate to the degree of disorder in the




-5market.

As disorder has mounted in recent weeks, so has the scale

of our intervention.

But exchange market intervention should not

and indeed cannot influence basic trends.

These trends rest upon

fundamentals.
The evidence that intervention cannot dominate exchange
market treads is all around us.

In the course of the present year,

net intervention purchases of dollars by major central banks have
amounted to more than $30 billion.

It is probable that this inter­

vention has had an impact on the value of the dollar, but it has
not prevented a 5 per cent depreciation of the dollar against the
weighted average of major currencies during 1977.

The reason for this

could be a perception that fundamentals did not justify a higher value for
the dollar.

It is only when fundamentals are appropriate and the

market has moved out of line with them that intervention can be
expected to have a lasting effect.

But the reason could also lie,

as already noted, in market psychology, which has often shown itself
capable of exaggerating exchange rate movements.

Fundamentals do not

necessarily assert themselves instantaneously or with complete
precision.
It is necessary, therefore, to examine the fundamentals of
the dollar.

The large current account deficit of the United States is

the principal factor now being looked at by the market.




This deficit

-6was not fully anticipated and hence has led to a change in the market's
evaluation of the dollar's prospects.

But it is necessary to look

through the size of the deficit to the circumstances that produce
it and that are likely to condition its duration.

One important

component of the deficit is the volume of oil imports, now at a rate
of 9-1/2 million barrels a day worthabout $45 billion at an annual
rate.

Of course, this amount is not a proper measure of the "oil

deficit."

That measure is not even correctly taken by the excess of

U.S. oil imports over exports to the OPEC countries, since we have
also large invisible net receipts from the OPEC countries for which
data are not readily available.

Moreover, a bilateral deficit can in

some degree be covered by bilateral surpluses with other countries.
For instance, the modest surplus that the United States has in its trade
with some European countries which in turn are selling to the OPEC
countries is an indirect way of covering a part

of the oil deficit.

Nevertheless, unrestrained U.S. consumption of oil and a
consequent mounting of our oil imports is rightly regarded as a heavy
burden on our trade account.

The energy legislation now in the

Congress, preceded by the measures announced by the President, should
bring a reduction in the upward trend of our oil imports.

Conser­

vation of energy and development of additional and substitute energy
sources is widely recognized to be necessary for reasons of national
security that go beyond considerations of the balance of payments.




-7A second important component of the current account deficit
is of a cyclical character.

The United States has moved well ahead

of the lest of the world in recovering from the 1974-75 recession and
moving into new high ground.

We can reasonably expect that eventually

the rest of the world will follow.

No one, I am sure, wants the U.S.

to reduce its current account deficit by slowing down its economy.
The underlying character of the deficit must be assessed, therefore,
by making a cyclical adjustment.

What, in other words, would be the

magnitude of the deficit if the world as a whole were at reasonably
full employment?
The methodology of a cyclical adjustment involves estimating
first what economic activity and prices, both at home and abroad, would
have been if there had been full employment during the period in
question.

Then trade flows can be estimated.

An econometric model

that relates U.S. trade flows to such income and price estimates
suggests that the U.S. trade deficit of about $30 billion might be
$10-20 billion lower if there were full employment in major industrialized
countries.

Since the surplus of about $12 billion on services would not

be much changed by a return to high employment, the U.S. current account
deficit of about $18 billion would be very substantially reduced under
those conditions.




-

8-

Not too much weight should be attached to calculations
like these, particularly since we do not know how long it might take
the world to return to high rates of employment.

And, in assessing

such very tentative calculations, it should also be borne in mind
that some deficit for the United States is not inappropriate so long
as the OPEC countries maintain a sizable surplus.

The deficits

corresponding to that surplus must be shared around the world.
While the United States, under ordinary conditions, and, given its
wealth and economic structure, ought to be a capital exporter, a
sharing in the non-OPEC world's aggregate deficit does not seem
inappropriate so long as some other countries may have difficulty
financing large deficits.
Computation of a cyclically adjusted U.S. trade deficit,
nevertheless, does not resolve the question whether the United
States has not in some fundamental sense lost competitiveness.
An analysis of the fundamentals, therefore, must focus also on
competitiveness.
There is a fair amount of evidence on this point.
of it comes from the analysis of market shares of exports.

Some
The

United States' share of exports of G-10 countries (a measure that
minimizes the impact of recent unusual developments in petroleum
and other commodity markets) declined in 1976 and again slightly
in the first half of this year.

But those declines followed three

years of increases in the U.S.£flfii^e>o.fs;&ports in the wake of two
&

.V'

'

■

years during which exchange r\ifc^s Jigd.been substantially realigned.




-9Thus the U.S. share, which measured 20.0 per cent during the first
half of this year, is essentially unchanged since 1971 when it measured
20.1 per cent.

And it should be noted that many countries that have

traditionally been large customers of ours have not expanded
particularly rapidly during this period.
Another source of concern about competitiveness apparently
is ready to be laid to rest.

Research dating from the 1950's to the

mid-1960's seemed to indicate that the elasticity of demand for U.S.
exports with respect to foreign income was substantially below the
elasticity for the exports of others with respect to our own income.
More recent work by the Federal Reserve staff indicates that there
is no statistical

significant difference between those elasticities.

In other words, so long as the United States and the rest of the
world grow at approximately the same rate, these studies suggest that
U.S. exports and imports should grow at roughly equal rates.
Finally, some evidence on competitiveness comes from the
calculations of "real" exchange rates.

These are exchange rates

adjusted for international differences in rates of inflation.

The real

exchange rate of the dollar will remain unchanged with respect to
any other currency or group of currencies so long as the movement in
the nominal exchange rate is equal to the differential movement
of prices.
Like all index numbers, calculations of real exchange rates
raise questions as to the kind of index used, and the starting level.
For some countries, for instance Japan, different indexes yield very




-10different results.

For the United States, however, the four

customarily used indexes —

consumer prices, wholesale prices,

export unit values, and unit labor costs -- all yield appromimately
the same result.

If a comparison is made between the dollar's

value at the beginning of the float of exchange rates in March
1973 as well as the average of rates during the period from March
1973 and the present, the real exchange rate of the dollar on a
trade weighted basis has depreciated and competitiveness has
increased.
The real exchange rate of the D-mark, computed similarly,
shows little change over the same period.

For the yen, as noted,

meaningful results are more difficult to obtain.
It must be remembered that an absence of major changes
in real exchange rates is not necessarily evidence of equilibrium.
When real rather than monetary shocks cause changes in the balance of
payments, real exchange rates ought to change.

But when examination

of structural factors in the world economy suggests that no major
adjustment is needed, movements in the real rate can be regarded as
indicative of changes in competitiveness, particularly when the
various indexes tend to produce roughly similar results.
One further element of competitiveness of the dollar remains
to be considered.
account.

It relates to the capital rather than the current

How competitive is the dollar as a capital asset?

This

depends both on interest rates and on expected exchange rate movements.
Together they produce the total expected return on dollar assets in




-11terms of foreign currencies.

The dollar solidified its role as the

world's leading reserve and investment currency during the postwar
period when interest rates were low in the United States and high
almost everywhere else.

Meanwhile, this relationship has been

reversed with respect to the strongest currencies.

U.S. interest

rates today are significantly higher than those of Switzerland,
Germany, and even Japan.
During periods of market turbulence, when exchange rates
and related capital values change rapidly and substantially, interest
rate considerations are likely to fade into the background.

But,

when markets settle down, interest rates are bound to carry weight.
Today, interest rate differentials among three important investment
currencies -- the dollar, the D-mark, and the Swiss franc —

reflect

very closely differential rates of inflation experienced in the three
respective countries.

Real interest rates, in other words, in these

countries, are approximately equal.
In this fundamental sense, the dollar does not seem to have
lost competitiveness as an asset.

If that can be accepted, one would

conclude that the financing of the U.S. current account deficit,
which in 1977 was accomplished almost entirely through movements of
official capital resulting from intervention, can also be accomplished
by private capital, at an unchanged exchange rate.
Let me summarize the elements of strength of the dollar
as I see them.
deficit.




First, there is a large cyclical component of the

We do not know how long it will take other countries to

-12re turn to high employment, but at any rate there is light at the end
of the tunnel.
Second, there is the modest improvement in U.S. competitiveness
since 1973, as measured in terms of the "real" exchange rate.

It

reflects the moderately good, though far from excellent, inflation
performance of the United States.

The main contribution to future

strength of the dollar will have to come from a continuation and
improvement in this performance.
Third, there are several other indicators of effective
competitiveness of U.S. goods, expecially market shares and demand
elasticities.

This competitiveness should begin to show through

as world trade recovers.
Fourth, there are substantial interest rate differentials
with respect to competing currencies.

As markets settle down, these

should increasingly assert themselves.
Not yet in this picture is concrete evidence that oil imports
will be held down.

Even strong legislation, as I expect to be enacted,

will not reduce U.S. oil imports in the immediate future.

But, such

legislation, once in place, should provide assurance to the markets that
the dollar strength will not be sapped by spiraling oil imports and
that, indeed, the longer run prospect is for reduced U.S. dependence
on imported oil in the future.




#