View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
SATURDAY, APRIL 3, 1976
3:30 P.M. LOCAL TIME
(10:30 A.M.EST)

REFLECTIONS ON DEVELOPMENTS IN THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
Remarks by
Henry C . Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Second Conference of the
International Federation of Associations of Business Economists
King's College
Cambridge, England
Saturday, April 3, 1976

REFLECTIONS ON DEVELOPMENTS IN THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Second Conference of the
International Federation of Associations of Business Economists
King's College
Cambridge, England
Saturday, April 3, 1976

It is a particular pleasure to address the Second Conference
of the International Federation of Associations of Business Economists
here in Cambridge within the precincts of this great university.

My

topic here today is "Reflections on Developments in the International
Monetary System."

The system has undergone quite a bit of motion

in recent weeks.

I shall comment briefly on what I believe to be

the meaning of these events.

My main concern, however, will be

with the evolution of the system and particularly with the processes
of exchange market intervention and of the creation of international
liquidity.
The events of the last few weeks show that exchange markets
continue to be highly sensitive to any departure of exchange rates
from what the market believes to be appropriate levels.




Evidently

-

2-

it is still not difficult for a currency to get itself into a
position where the market believes that the only alternatives are
either no change or a movement in only one direction.

It was

these unidirectional anticipations that played havoc with the
old Bretton Woods system.

The recent evidence suggests that

under today's conditions similar reactions remain a possibility.
From the emphasis that the market places on differential
rates of inflation, it would seem that the market takes these
rates of inflation as given.
itself.

In this, the market may be deceiving

The old Bretton Woods system, and the gold standard which

preceded it, operated on the assumption that rates of inflation
would adjust so as to make balance-of-payments positions adjust.
Recent history has demonstrated that the latter assumption cannot
be plausibly maintained.

Nevertheless, we are witnessing strong

efforts in most countries to come to grips with inflation even at
considerable short-run sacrifices of employment, because the long-run
consequences of inflation have been shown to be so damaging.

Since

these efforts, if persisted in, should yield positive results,
markets eventually may be expected to feel increasingly uncertain
about the appropriateness of discounting farther and farther ahead
a specific future inflation rate.
I have seen reports that interpret the exchange rate
movement of the last few weeks as a test of the principles of the




-3-

Rambouillet Agreement.

I disagree with this interpretation.

Rambouillet Agreement stresses economic fundamentals.

The

It as well

as the proposed amendment of Article IV contain nothing to suggest
that fundamental factors influencing exchange
counteracted.

rates should be

The fundamentals of Rambouillet, to be sure,

differ from the fundamentals of Bretton Woods.

The old Bretton

Woods agreement would not have regarded as a "fundamental disequilibrium”
justifying an exchange rate movement, a short-term divergence of
interest rates or aggregate demands due to differences in cyclical
phase among countries.

The pending Article IV of the IMF Agreement,

as I interpret it, treats both of these factors as fundamentals.
The exchange rate movements of the last few weeks seem
to me to have been a test primarily of the principle of bloc floating.
This principle is backed up by a respectable economic theory -- that
of "optimum currency areas."

But that theory presupposes, of course,

that countries are able and willing to coordinate their internal
policies.

We have seen how quickly failure to abide by this

presupposition can undermine cohesion within a presumptively optimum
currency area.
In passing, I would also like to note some of the effects
that recent exchange rate movements have had on the trade-weighted
rate of the dollar.

As you know, the dollar depreciated from a

rate of 86 per cent (May 1970 parities of 10 currencies weighted




-4by 1972 trade = 100) in September 1974 to 79 per cent in February 1975,
appreciated from there to 87 per cent in September 1975, and remained
approximately at that level until January 1976.

Since then it has

risen to approximately 89 per cent.
The recent movement will not be without its effects on
the U.S. balance of payments and prices.

Research in progress at

the Federal Reserve shows that a one percentage point change in the
exchange rate normally produces, with a lag of several years, a
chafige of from $3/4 to $1 billion in the trade balance, everything
else, including price movements, being equal.

Similarly, a one

percentage point change in the exchange rate may change the U.S.
price level, again with a lag of three to four years, by something
of the order of one-eighth to three-sixteenths of a percentage
point, depending upon other developments affecting the economy.
Over time, of course, any disequilibrium that might have been
created by such movements will tend, in a floating rate system,
to be corrected by further exchange rate or price movements.
I shall now examine a little more closely the evolution
of the international financial system as regards exchange market
intervention not related to bloc floating.

Over the last few years,

we have observed two kinds of official influence on exchange
markets.

One has been exchange market intervention, which in

principle has aimed at maintenance of orderly exchange markets
with no attempt to influence the level or trend of exchange rates.




-5The other has reflected official or officially induced capital
movements as well as the use or accumulation of exchange reserves.
The second approach has been employed in order to shield
balance-of-payments positions against massive disequilibria.
Since late 1973, a major part of such disequilibria has been the
result of the skyrocketing price of oil.

In part, however, the

disequilibria experienced also reflect domestic economic policies.
I shall begin by examining exchange market intervention.
One possible test of an intervention policy that is oriented toward
maintenance of orderly markets and avoidance of erratic fluctuations
is absence of major changes in exchange reserves over some period
of time, presumably the time over which a spell of disorder or
potential disorder in the exchange market might extend.
cite numerous examples.

One could

The Bank of Canada usually operates

flexibly and speedily on both sides of the market, smoothing out
very short-term elements of "disorder."

The Federal Reserve

likewise has moved in and out over time, although not necessarily
over such short periods.

It has only occasionally accumulated

balances, usually of minimal size, and has reversed swap borrowings
undertaken since the ending of gold convertibility of the dollar
within one or two quarters.

The Deutsche Bundesbank has likewise

approximately balanced its purchases and sales, but over somewhat
longer periods.




Both in 1974 and in 1975 there were three periods

-6 -

of about three months in which reserves increased or decreased by
as much as DMark 5 billion or more, but net changes in reserves
for the year were of the order of only DMark 2 billion, in both
years reflecting a decline in reserves.
These various national practices reflect actions to
forestall different types of "disorder" or "erratic behavior"
in exchange markets, all of which are economically relevant.

At

one side of the spectrum are shortfalls from market efficiency
such as paucity of bids and offers, wide spreads between bid and
offer rates, and discontinuities in exchange rate movements.
the other side are shortfalls from market efficiency

On

in the form

of non-random behavior of exchange rates which are inconsistent
with an efficient market.

Part of this non-random behavior is

the price dynamics to which the market refers as runs or bandwagons.
Earlier work at the Federal Reserve and elsewhere had
suggested that exchange rate movements were almost entirely random,
suggesting that exchange markets were efficient.

Such randomness,

of course, is a characteristic that has been examined in the stock
market and in commodity markets many times and these markets have
usually been found to be efficient.

What that implies is that all

new information is acted upon by a sufficiently large number of market
participants so that prices change quickly to reflect new information.
This ensures that the latest price reflects all available information




-

7-

and that no predictions of the future course of prices can be made
on the basis of this already discounted information, including
information on the past behavior of the market itself.
More recent work done by the staff of the Federal Reserve
Board— ^ suggests that these findings were premature.

By applying

so-called filter rules, the authors demonstrate that, since the
beginning of floating, the exchange markets may have contained
very significant non-random elements.

These elements, presumably

reflecting price dynamics, would have made it possible to ride a
"bandwagon 11 profitably over varying periods in particular markets.
It should be noted, however, that over the period of floating
the market seems to have learned, with the result that the opportunity
of profiting from bandwagon effects has diminished.

A general

conclusion to be derived from these findings is that periods of
disorder, in the form of price dynamics, may extend well beyond
day-to-day incidents.
Next, let me turn to officially induced or executed capital
movements, including the more lasting use or accumulation of reserves.
Numerous countries, confronted with the large current account
deficits of recent years, have chosen to finance, rather than adjust

JL/Michael P. Dooley and Jeffrey R. Shafer, "Analysis of Short-Run
Exchange Rate Behavior, March 1973 to September 1975," International
Finance Discussion Pap e r s , Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, No. 76, February 1976.




-

these imbalances.

8-

Given the difficulty of reducing the surplus

of the OPEC countries very substantially in the short run, it
would obviously have been very difficult and internationally
undesirable for most oil-importing countries to achieve over-all
payments balance by allowing their exchange rates to depreciate.
Very severe depreciation no doubt would have induced some private
capital inflows that might have made it unnecessary to achieve
current account balance.

But the threat of a deep drop in the

exchange rate might also have induced capital outflows that could
have further intensified the downward exchange rate movement.
Thus Britain, France, Italy and many other countries borrowed
heavily to finance their current account deficits and to prevent
sharp declines in their exchange rates.
Some of these borrowings took the form of official loans,
the proceeds of which were temporarily lodged in central bank
reserves.

Others were private borrowings, sponsored or induced

in varying degrees by government action, the proceeds of which also
went to the central banks.

These foreign exchange assets, usually

dollars, were then fed out into the exchange market.

In addition,

the proceeds of some borrowings went into the exchange market
directly

without passing through official channels.
I see no conflict between such balance-of-payments

financing and the spirit of the Rambouillet Agreement.




Capital

-9 -

movements certainly are among the factors that can be regarded as
fundamental or "underlying."

As such, it would be appropriate to

allow them to influence exchange rates, in this particular case
in the direction of stability rather than of change.

What is

important, of course, is that these balance-of-payments financing
operations be so conducted as ,rto avoid manipulating exchange
rates or the international monetary system in order to prevent
effective balance-of-payments adjustment or to gain an unfair
competitive advantage over other members."

The application of

this clause in the proposed amendment of Article IV will require
goodwill and cooperation on all sides, because the determination of
what constitutes an unfair competitive advantage involves the
concept of under- or over-valuation of a currency, which is not
always easy to measure.
I now turn to examine briefly some interrelations between
official exchange market intervention activity and monetary policy.
Historically, exchange rate objectives have been viewed as in conflict
with an independent monetary policy.

Efforts to keep an exchange

rate from rising by buying foreign currency, whether by obligation
under fixed rates or by choice under floating, tend to expand
bank reserves and the money supply.

Many countries have experienced

difficulty in completely offsetting these expansionary effects,
whether by open market operations, by increases in reserve requirements,
or by other techniques.

Efforts to keep an exchange rate from falling

by selling foreign currency can interfere with domestic monetary
policy by posing a choice between permitting monetary contraction




-

10-

to occur in order to protect exchange reserves and pursing offsetting
operations that threaten their exhaustion.
Allowing rates to float freely has been hailed as a means
of liberating monetary policy from these constraints.
of course, has been less than total.

This liberation,

Many countries have not been

willing to accept the wide swings in exchange rates that might result
from a monetary policy totally unconcerned with such effects.

Countries

in whose economies the exchange rate plays a role of primary importance
may well find it necessary to constrain their domestically oriented
monetary policies in order to forestall wide exchange rate fluctuations.
Under floating exchange rates, however, exchange market inter­
vention poses less of a threat to monetary policy than it did under
fixed exchange rates, and in some circumstances it can also be employed
as an aid to monetary policy.

Exchange market intervention and monetary

policy are two separate instruments, with which two separate objectives
could be pursued, such as an exchange rate and an interest rate target.
The two instruments are not altogether independent, and hence the
degree to which the two targets can be pursued independently likewise
is limited.
The incomplete independence between exchange market operations
and monetary policy derives from the fact that both affect bank reserves
and the money supply.

One could conceive of a situation in which the

injection of bank reserves through the purchase of foreign currencies
offsets completely the withdrawal of bank reserves through open market
sales of securities, leaving no net effect on either exchange rate or
interest rate.




Technically, this would happen if foreign-denominated

-

11-

securities were very good substitutes for domestic securities*
However, under a regime of managed floating, home and foreign securities
are unlikely to be such good substitutes.

Research employing the data

of particular industrial countries suggests that their monetary authori­
ties can count on some degree of independence between exchange rate
and interest rate policy.
Without exaggerating these possibilities, it is worth noting
some implications of these results.

If monetary policymakers find

themselves constrained in taking action on interest rates by their
concern over possible repercussions on the exchange rate, simultaneous
use of the two instruments can be helpful.

Unintended pressure on the

exchange rate resulting from changes in interest rate policy can then,
to some degree, be offset by exchange market action.

Such exchange

market intervention would not appear to be contrary to the principle
that underlying factors are to determine exchange rates, since an
unintended side effect of monetary policy can hardly be regarded as
fundamental.

In other situations, however, the authorities very well

may regard their interest rate moves as a fundamental factor, the
exchange rate repercussions of which should not be offset.
Let me conclude with some comments on international liquidity,
a subject closely related to exchange market intervention.

During the

time of troubles preceding floating, and while the Committee of Twenty
was seeking a basic reform of the international monetary system, inter­
national liquidity was very much in the foreground of the discussion.




-

12-

Has the situation changed so drastically under floating that concern
with international liquidity should be set aside as much as it has
been recently?
"International liquidity" is not a happy concept because it
embraces so many dimensions.

In the domestic sphere, at the time of

the Radcliffe Report in the late 1950,s, we also spoke about liquidity,
seeking to analyze the effects of finance on incomes, prices and the
balance of payments in terms of liquidity.
has not proved functional.

Domestically, "liquidity"

It has largely been replaced by emphasis

on the monetary aggregates, which empirically have been shown to be
much more closely related to income and prices.

This has been found

to be true despite the many obvious objections to concentrating
attention on variables, such as M^, M^, or

that reflect only a

small segment of the spectrum of total financing.
In the international sphere, unfortunately, there is no
analogue to the domestic monetary aggregates.

To be sure, the objections

that can be raised against gross reserves as a measure of international
liquidity are not all that different from those that can be raised
against the monetary aggregates -- each represents a gross rather than
a net concept, and neither really limits spending power, since both
money and reserves can be borrowed.

But instead of what has been

shown to be a fairly stable relation between money on one side and
income and prices on the other, the relation of any form of inter­
national liquidity, including gross reserves, to trade and balances




-13of payments seems to be very loose.

Official reserves are not trans­

actions balances, but precautionary balances.
usually is, financed by the private sector.

Trade can be, and
Only at minimum levels

do reserves seem to become important for a country’
s balance-ofpayments policy.
Nevertheless, reserves matter.

There are transmission

mechanisms from reserves to other parts of the financial system and
to the real sector.

Acquisition of reserves through intervention

expands bank reserves and the domestic money supply.

Acquisition of

reserves -- but also an increase in credit facilities, i.e., no n ­
reserve liquidity —

affects the propensity to import of some, but

by no means all, countries.
reserve distribution.

This underscores the importance of

Reserves also influence countries 1 policies

with respect to exchange rates, but again far from universally.

One

is bound to conclude that effective control of an important part of
international liquidity such as gross reserves, if it were possible,
would indeed influence economic policy and behavior, but that the
degree of this influence would be far less predictable than the
influence exerted by control over the domestic money supply.
This conclusion seems no less valid under floating than
under fixed rates.
reserves.

A country seeking a pure float would need no

But the great majority of countries apparently do not

wish to float in that manner.

Nor do they probably want to be

unprotected against the possibility of externally imposed drains,




-14such as the oil deficits.

Even though such needs could be met from

borrowing instead of from reserves, the private capital market seems
to be more willing to lend to countries that have the reserves than
to countries that do not.

Floating, on the other hand, makes it

easier to acquire reserves, since a country can buy them in the market.
Clearly, international liquidity in general and reserves in
particular do matter.

Hence, there can be reasonable concern about

their appropriate level.

That concern today has shifted in good part

from earlier worries about inadequate liquidity to an emphasis on the
dangers of excessive liquidity.

Existing concern is reflected in a

desire to phase out gold, the price appreciation of which has created
an enormous potential increase in liquidity, and in the fact that no
new SDR allocation has been voted since 1969,
It has often been said that international reserves cannot be
controlled under today’
s conditions in which countries can largely,
although not entirely, have any level of reserves they want.
is a political, not an economic, statement.

That

Technically, the means

to control international reserves are available —

a rigorous asset

settlement system or a total prohibition on intervention.

To mention

such techniques suffices to reveal the obstacles to their implementation.
The recent proposal of the Managing Director of the International Monetary
Fund suggesting reserve requirements for international reserves in the
form of SDRs is somewhat less rigid, but the problems it raises are not




-15fundamentally different.

No obvious answer is in sight.

Unless and

until an answer can be developed, inflation will have to be controlled
mainly by means of appropriate domestic policies within the context
of a floating rates system.




#