View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

February 24, 1984

NOTES ON
INSURANCE OF BANK LENDING TO DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
by
Henry C. Wallich

The possibility of an insurance scheme for bank loans to
developing countries has been broached from time to time, most recently
by Dr. Johannes Witteveen, Chairman of the Group of Thirty, in his 1983
I
!
Per Jacobsson lecture.

The present note lists a number of considerations,

by no means complete, bearing on such an insurance scheme.
to explore some aspects of an uncharted area.

It was written

It should not be interpreted

as prejudging the feasibility of such a plan under prevailing circumstances.
.1.

Prototypes
A wide range of credit insurance plans is in operation today.

In

the United States, mortgages are insured/guaranteed by the Federal Housing
Administration and the Veterans Administration, while investments in mortgage pools are guaranteed by the Government National Mortgage Association
("Ginny Mae"), the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation ("Freddie Mac"),
and other institutions.

Private mortgage insurance, in diverse technical

forms, is offered by insurance companies, such as Mortgage Guarantee
Insurance Corporation (MGIC) , various banks operating mortgage pools, and
others.

The low credit risks on mortgages make mortgage insurance an

actuarially viable operation.

Prepared for the Group of 30.

-2-

Municipal bond insurance is offered by American Municipal Bond
Assurance Corporation (AMBAC) and Municipal Bond Insurance Association (MBIA) ,
a consortium of five large insurance companies, and municipal bond portfolio
insurance by MGIC Indemnity.

Some export credit is insured by Export-Import

Bank, a government institution, and the Private Export Financing Corporation
(PEFCO), a private organization.

Some foreign direct investment can be insured,

mainly against political risk, by Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC),
a wholly owned U.S. government corporation.

Bank credit, particularly to

individuals, is insured through numerous credit, life and casualty insurers.
Commercial and savings bank deposits are insured by the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC), savings and loan association deposits by the
Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC), credit-union shares
by the National Credit Union Administration, and brokerage accounts through
the Securities Investor Protective Corporation (SIPC).

Credit insurance,

evidently, is widely practiced in the United States.

2.

Alternative Objectives of Insurance
Insurance can be applied to LDC lending for the purpose both of

encouraging such lending and of increasing the safety of banks.

It is

widely believed that continued lending, although on a more moderate scale,
is necessary for the good functioning of the world economy and the health
of the international monetary system.

It is also believed widely that many

banks, especially smaller ones, feel considerable reluctance in that regard.
Insurance may ease this problem.
Several approaches appear possible.

Particular loans could be

insured, liabilities of banks could be insured, loan portfolios of banks
could be insured.

For several reasons, insurance of loans and of deposits

seems less feasible than insurance of portfolios.

-3-

Irisurance of loans tends to create moral hazard.

Lenders and

borrowers might contract loans, and borrowers might subsequently engage in
policies that would inappropriately increase risk.

This could perhaps be

dealt with by co-insurance, deductibles, partial insurance, and the like.
But these devices have costs in terms of the economic effectiveness of the
insurance in promoting sound lending.
Loan insurance also raises the question of resource allocation.
The insuring agency influences the allocation of credit to particular
borrowers.

Differential insurance premia might be employed to deal with

differential risks.

They would be difficult to apply, however, for

obvious political reasons, if the insuring agency is a governmental
organization.
Insurance of loans would also discriminate in an undesirable way
against borrowers whose obligations can stand on their own feet.

The spreads

which today measure or should measure the degree of risk of different loans
and borrowers work to allocate credit to stronger borrowers.

If the

insurance scheme were somehow made comprehensive, covering all loans made
by a given group of banks, or obtained by a given group of countries, the
stronger borrowers would be subsidizing the weaker unless premia are
adequately differentiated.
The alternative of insuring the deposits of a bank, which is one
of the principal insurance features in American banking, seems to lack
applicability with respect to bank lending to developing countries.

Given

the wholesale character of international banks, limitation of deposit
insurance to some particular amount —
would not be meaningful.

in the United States $100,000

The volume of deposits to be insured would,

—

-4-

therefore, be very large.

More importantly, while deposit insurance

protects the creditor and, by forestalling runs, also the bank, it would
not meet the needs of borrowers since banks' willingness to lend to a
particular class of borrowers should not be influenced significantly by
greater stability of deposits.

At the same time, stability of deposits

would remove some of the discipline of the market that is needed to limit
risk taking.
Some "insurance" already is provided to banks through the presence
in the market of central banks as lenders of last resort.

This protects

bank and depositor, not against loss, but against illiquidity.

The lender-

of-last-resort function is well established, even though in its international
aspects, for good reason, not very fully spelled out.

Its presence no doubt

influences the willingness of banks to lend to developing countries in some
nonmeasurable degree, but does not fall under the general heading of credit
insurance.
The most viable technique seems to be the insurance of portfolios.
This would mean to insure a portfolio of LDC loans up to some fraction against
loss.

To encourage bank prudence, only some large fraction of each loan

within the insured part of the portfolio might be insurable, i.e., there
would remain an element of co-insurance.
No distinction, therefore, would be made between "insured" and
"uninsured" loans.

Any loan would, in effect, be insured if it should get

into difficulties provided that, together with other loans already in
troubled condition, it does not cause the share of such loans in a bank's
portfolio to exceed the insured fraction.

The problems inherent in insuring

-5-

particular loans, as noted above, would thus be avoided.

The main difficulty

is to determine the fraction of the portfolio to be insured, so that it would
give banks adequate protection without being so large as to be actuarially
unmanageable.
Banks engage in this measurement of the risk factor in many phases
of their operations.

The spread over LIBOR is intended to account for risk,

in addition to covering the costs of operation and of the capital needed to
support the loan.

Annual allocations to loan-loss reserves and the level of

these reserves are measures of risk. So are the actual loan-loss experience
and nonperformance experience.

Supervisory classification of loans is an

official indicator of risk, but not easily quantifiable.
Most of the available indicators of risk suggest that banking risk
in general is modest.
of their portfolio.

Bankers do not expect to lose a significant portion
Spreads have frequently been below one percent, and only

in some cases, and more recently in reschedulings, above two percent.
costs of operation and of capital, only a fraction -- if any —
spreads is available to cover risk.

Given

of these

Nevertheless, from an annual charge, a

reserve pool can be built up unless the bank chooses to distribute it as
dividends.

In any event, bankers' policies with regard to spreads on inter-

national loans do not suggest any expectation of large loan losses.
The loan-loss reserve of large American banks averages somewhat
above one percent (1.2 percent) of loans.

Their loss ratio on domestic

loans reached recent peak levels of .58 percent in 1975 and .56 percent
in 1982.

The loss ratio on international loans was .30 percent, significantly

below the domestic ratio, but with little or no allowance for possible

-6-

ultimate default on sovereign loans.

Nonperforming loans for major banks,

as of the third quarter of 1983, were 3.7 percent of loans.

Historical

experience has, of course, been more favorable.
All these indicators, taken by themselves, would seem to suggest
that the insured fraction of the portfolio need not be high.

Insuring a

fraction of two percent might provide a considerable safety factor for a
bank, even though, of course, not total protection.

These numbers neverthe-

less are not a good measure of the degree of uncertainty that many banks are
likely to feel with respect to their LDC portfolio.

Recent reschedulings

often have reflected some kind of irregularity of debt service, even though
not rising in all cases to the level of nonperformance, nonaccrual, or
regulatory classification as "substandard."

The proportion of loans

affected by such irregularities may be of the order of 60 percent of LDC
loans of American banks.

Given that, in the most likely course of events

and barring unforeseeable catastrophies, the ultimate loss would be small,
nothing like this fraction would require insurance.

What is required is

that the annual receipts of the insurance fund should, on average, exceed
the annual losses, and that the insurance fund should accumulate enough,
after paying off losses, to take care of peak-loss years.
The insurance may be designed to cover principal only, or interest
only, or both.

If principal only is covered, which may be subject to long

grace periods, substantial funds could accumulate in the meantime from premia,
even if eventual benefits are paid promptly instead of after some delay
associated with the need to demonstrate that the debtor in fact is defaulting.

-7-

The amounts to be covered, however, would be large.

Hence the fraction of

the portfolio that could be insured would be quite small.
Insurance may also be designed to cover income, exclusively or in
combination with principal.

If exclusively, the amounts to be covered would

be relatively moderate (compared to principal) and the fraction of the portfolio that could be insured would be larger.

Banks1 immediate concern often

is a loss of income. For a bank receiving an average interest rate of 12 percent, and a net return of 0.75 percent on assets

(all before taxes, taxable-

equivalent basis), a loss of interest on a little over 6 percent of
its assets would wipe out profits entirely.

Many banks, therefore,

may prefer to guard against this more immediate risk and face up to risk of
loss of principal only over a longer period which in any event can be
stretched out by rescheduling so long as interest is paid through insurance
or perhaps new loans.
If interest is the primary focus of insurance, benefit payments
would have to be prompt.
to cover principal.

Some allowance would nevertheless have to be made

The amounts then could become very large.

Perhaps

insurance of principal could be made contingent on availability of funds
after interest (up to the insured fraction of the portfolio) had been paid
from the insurance fund.
Portfolio insurance, moreover, need not take the form of "first-loss"
insurance, several variants of which have been discussed so far.

Instead,

each of these versions could be cast in the form of catastrophe insurance,
such as is familiar in the health-insurance field.

Initial losses, of

principal or income, could be allowed to be absorbed by the insured.

Beyond

-8-

that, the insurance would take over, in full or in part, up to some limit
consistent with the resources of the insurance fund.

Insurance of the

entire remainder of the portfolio is conceivable, and the risk of such
catastrophic losses probably is slight, but nevertheless would be so far
beyond the resources of the insurance fund as to lack credibility.

It

would be very difficult to quantify the proportions of the portfolio
representing the lower and upper bounds of the catastrophe-insured part,
and no attempt is made here to do so.

The possibility nevertheless seems

worth exploring if banks should have a preference for catastrophe insurance,
as many individuals have with respect to health insurance.
Separation of the insured risks into earlier and later maturities
would be still another device.

This separation frequently is made when

commercial banks co-finance with the World Bank, the World Bank then
frequently taking the longer maturities.

Since risk on the shorter

maturities generally is regarded as being lower than on the longer maturities,
there could be an opportunity for this approach by an insurance fund if this
were the preferred technique on the part of the banks.

Further discussion

will proceed, however, on the premise that the insurance takes the form of
insurance against the first tranche of losses, with some co-insurance.

3.

Sources of Funds
An effective insurance fund will need a flow of receipts sufficient

on average to take care of losses, and beyond that an amount sufficient to
generate confidence that even occasional very large losses can be met.

The

-9-

international lending field differs from many others in that actuarial
calculations of both magnitudes are very uncertain.

It may be possible

to create an effective insurance based only on contributions by the insured,
i.e., by banks and/or borrowing countries.

This is what, in effect, banks

have been doing, or should have been doing, in their own strategies of
charging for risk and accumulating reserves.
amounts to self-insurance.
spreads the risk.

That activity, however,

Pooled insurance is more efficient, because it

Accordingly, if the banks have been doing enough in the

way of self-insurance, accumulating these risk premia in a pool would provide
more than adequate coverage.
The possibility must be faced that the banks may not have done
enough to guard against a period of high losses.

To make up for that,

larger contributions or some outside source of funds would be required to
establish credible insurance.

The additional charges might take the form of

a surcharge on the loan, or of some fraction of the spread.

The high spreads

charged in reschedulings have become controversial, and it might be feasible,
as well as appropriate, to channel a large share of them into an insurance
pool.

The pool would protect only loan portfolios for which a contribution

had been made since the inception of the loan.

Loans on behalf of which no

contribution was made would not be covered.
The inclusion or exclusion of rescheduled loans would present a
particular problem.

To include them would imply a degree of adverse selec-

tion, since these loans are by definition weak.

On the other hand, most of

the potential interest in an insurance plan may well focus on rescheduled

-10-

loans.

The high premia currently being charged on such loans would provide

an opportunity to create a rapidly growing insurance fund, if the larger
part of them could be channeled into such a fund.

Given the presence of

insurance, banks might be satisfied with a lower net return.

Acceptance of

a lower return would also seem advisable in the light of the criticism leveled
against reschedulings where fees and spreads have been sharply increased.
A weighty objection to the inclusion of rescheduled loans is that it
would not serve one of the main purposes of the insurance plan.

That purpose

would be to encourage new lending (the other being to protect the banks with
respect to the consequences of past loans).

Limiting the plan to new loans

would, of course, make its overall scale much more moderate and probably more
manageable.
In any event, the possibility that the plan may require outside
resources cannot be rejected.

If only funds contributed by the banks are

available, it could be argued that the insurance would only give the banks
their own money back.

Of course this would not be so bank by bank.

If port-

folio compositions differ, some banks would get back more than their own money,
others less.

That is the nature, and the advantage, of pooled insurance as

contrasted with self-insurance.

But if the banks in the aggregate have not

charged enough of an insurance premium through spreads and fees, an insurance
fund derived from contributions based on spreads and fees may not be large
enough.
An outside source of funds, in any case, whether from government
or other sources, should not be a permanent net contribution.
it would be a subsidy.

If it were,

Rather, it should be in the nature of a facility

-11-

that takes care of peak loads in bad years or that provides an emergency
reserve, but it should be paid back over time.

Particularly in the early

years, before the fund had had time to accumulate adequate reserves, or
if losses in the early years should be particularly heavy, such an outside
source would be very valuable, perhaps essential.

One may recall the

"pipeline" into the U.S. Treasury that was established at the inception
of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.

It was never used, but it

gave credibility to U.S. deposit insurance in its early years.
Outside funds need not come from governments, but could also be
from private sources.

If from governments, they need not be funds

appropriated specifically for such purpose, but conceivably might be
provided by existing official agencies with insurance or guarantee powers,
such as the U.S. Export-Import Bank, the U.K. Export Credit Guarantee
Department, or the World Bank.

While such guarantees would absorb

funds that otherwise could be used to finance other LDC credit, use in
an insurance plan for commercial bank loans that insured only a fraction
of the portfolio would have higher leverage.

In order to gain some

perspective on the orders of magnitude that might be involved, some purely,
illustrative figures are presented.

Various observers have estimated that

for 1983, $20 billion of net new bank lending (in addition to lending from
other sources) would be adequate to cover the borrowing needs of the major
borrowing countries.

If bank lending proceeded at this rate for five years,

with grace periods for each loan of five years, a total volume of new loans
of $100 billion would be built up.

If one percent premium were paid per year

on the outstandings, a total insurance pool of $3 billion would be accumulated
(ignoring interest), as detailed in the table below:

-12-

Premia Receipts
(In $ billions)
Year
Year
Year
Year
Year

Maximum Interest
Losses

Annual

Cumulative

Annual

$0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0

0.2
0.6
1.2
2.0
3.0

1.5
3.0
4.5
6.0
7.5

one
two
three
four
five

Cumulative
1.5
4.5
9.0
15.0
22.5

These $3 billion would be available to meet defaults on either principal or
interest.

With respect to principal defaults (which could occur only after

the five-year grace period), the fund is very small, although losses of
3 percent exceed by far any normal loss ratio in domestic banking.

With

respect to defaults on interest, if $20 billion are loaned per year at
10 percent, and if coinsurance of 25 percent is assumed, maximum annual
losses to the fund would be $1.5 billion in the first year, rising to $7.5
billion in the fifth, and cumulative potential losses would be $22.5 billion
after five years, ignoring that total nonpayment of interest as here assumed
would make continued annual lending at $20 billion per year unlikely.

Thus

for each year, and for the five-year period as a whole, the insurance fund
would have resources equal to 13.3 percent of the maximum interest loss
chargeable to the fund.
An accumulation of premia of $3 billion over five years is modest,
to be sure, whether matched against total LDC lending, or lending to one of
the largest debtors, or the potential guarantee capacity of some official
institutions.

On the other hand, a fund that (after coinsurance of 25 percent)

Would be able to insure 13 percent of the new loans portfolio in the case
of income loss, or, alternatively, up to 4 percent in the case of principal
l°ss, would not seem negligible in relation to historical average loss
experience of banks.

-13-

If outside sources of funds are regarded as necessary, both
national and international sources could be considered.

National export

credit insurance or guarantee organizations have already been noted.

The

International Monetary Fund is not authorized by its statutes to provide
insurance or guarantees, but might be able to establish a trust fund, such
as was done in other contexts, that could do so.

Contributions to such a

fund presumably would have to come from outside the International Monetary
Fund's own resources.

The World Bank is authorized to give guarantees.

These, as already noted, absorb lending capacity dollar for dollar, but the
leverage with respect to the volume of bank lending that could thus be induced
might be much higher.

Any contributions from national or international

sources should not be designed as subsidies, but as temporary resources that
lend credibility to the insurance plan and that should be repaid by the
insurance plan if drawn upon.
Private insurance companies, finally, could also be thought of
as outside sources.

Particularly if reinsurance were involved, this would

not be altogether out of line with their business.

But they could not rely

on actuarial experience derived from that business, as far as LDC risk was
concerned.

Indeed, if such an insurance scheme were viable, consideration

of the potential role of private insurers raises the question why the market
has not already produced such a scheme.

However, while high risks may be an

adequate explanation, the lack of demand for such a scheme until quite recently,
and the possibly negative attitude toward it on the part of many banks even
now, may also have been a reason.

-14-

Finally, consideration might be given to national rather than
international insurance schemes.

These would be easier to negotiate.

However, if they required substantial contributions from the banks of the
respective country or from their customers, those banks might find themselves at a competitive disadvantage.

4.

Sponsorship and Management
Sponsorship of the insurance plan, and its continuing management,

presumably would depend on the source of funds.

If the sole or principal

source were to be contributions by the banks, in proportion to covered loans,
a banking syndicate or some bank-related group would be the logical sponsor.
Syndications and reschedulings have created working relationships among
large international banks that may make such an arrangement possible.

If

substantial contributions from governments were involved, the organization
presumably would have to have official character.

Possibly, the IMF and the

IBRD, whether they supply the resources or not, could serve as initiators and
administrators.

If existing insurance organizations were to participate on a

large scale, protection of their interests would require participation in
management.

j,.

Other constellations, of course, are conceivable.

Participation in the Plan
How general should the participation of banks and borrowers be?

Is it conceivable that, without legislation or official agreement, all LDC
loans could become subject to such a scheme?

If universality were aimed at,

would it place a burden on strong borrowers and strong banks for the benefit
of the rest?
m

If participation were voluntary, both for banks and borrowers,

ight it create opportunities for free-riders, or for the development of

-15-

uncovered weak spots?

What would be the means by which some kind of order

and coordination could be achieved?

Could governments, even in the absence

of firmer arrangements, encourage participation by more favorable treatment
of insured loans in bank supervision?

Could appropriate arrangements be

made with respect to country classification, loan classification, capitaladequacy requirements, provisioning requirements?

Could the IMF and the

IBRD exert an influence toward participation?
What kinds of loans would be subject to such a scheme? LDC loans,
East-Bloc loans, small developed-country loans, all international loans?
Should there be differential treatment for syndicated loans, trade credit,
guaranteed credit, shorter and longer portions of syndicated loans, interbank loans, offshore-center placements, and for rescheduled loans, if
included?

Should there be country limits, and how would they be established

and administered?

Should there be special treatment for countries that in

a regulatory framework had received adverse classification?
supervisory authorities be involved in some form?

Should national

None of these matters

seems decisive, but they need to be addressed.

_6.

Nature and Timing of Compensation of Losses
As noted before, some co-insurance by insured banks would be

desirable to ward off moral hazard.
the above illustrative calculations.

A portion of 25 percent was assumed in
Such a level of coinsurance ought to

be sufficient to guard against any temptation either to allow losses to
increase up to the insured level, or to weight the scales in favor of
accepting default instead of refinancing.

-16-

Given this, what is the appropriate time for recognition or
pay-off on a loss?

Insurers in other fields have established routine

practices that may provide guidelines.

In the case of some forms of

insurance, failure to receive payment of interest and principal on a
timely basis gives rise to an immediate claim.

In others, there may be

a protracted process of documenting the nature of the loss, its definitiveness, or possible redress open to the insured.
matter is apt to be particularly difficult.

For sovereign risks, the

Lack of perfect punctuality

in the service of principal and often even interest has become a not
unusual event.

Should the insurer of a sovereign credit subrogate himself

immediately for the lender and pay off the latter?

Banks in many cases, as

already noted, may be more concerned about timely receipt of interest than
about ultimate repayment because of the implications of nonaccrual status
of loans.

Moreover, determination of ultimate loss in the case of a sovereign

borrower may be virtually impossible.

Even repudiation need not be definitive,

since a successor government may resume payments.

In the case of sovereign

loans, judgmental provisioning, voluntary or mandated by supervisors, may be
the most tangible evidence of "loss."

Resolution of the definition of "loss,"

in turn, may bear upon the question who is to act with respect to the defaulting
debtor.

Representation of continued creditor interests could remain in the

hands of the banks involved, or it could pass to the insuring agency.

J.

Probable Attitudes of Banks
For lending banks, an insurance scheme has attractions but also

drawbacks.

Among the advantages are the greater risk protection at least

for those banks that have done no more than average provisioning.

Whether

-17-

the insurance plan is additional to provisioning, or in part a substitute,
pooled insurance in any event is more efficient than self-insurance.
Insurance might be welcomed by banks as protection against the extreme
competition that during the late 1970!s brought spreads down to levels
inadequate to cover risk.

Channeling part or all of the spread into an

insurance fund would allow these resources to accumulate untaxed, whereas
in most countries they would be taxed if taken into income.

Banks may

expect that the ultimate burden of insurance can be shifted to the borrower.
They may be attracted by the prospect of more liberal supervisory treatment
of loans in an insurance plan.

The IMF may take a more positive view of

loans that are in an insurance plan.

Borrowing countries may be under

better discipline if their loans are in an insurance plan.

Indeed, some

firmer relation to the IMF than is provided by its present practices and
statutes, such as commitment in the loan-contract to go to the IMF at an
early point of a problem situation, might be made part of a loan and insurance
contract.

Better regulatory treatment, tax exemption of the insurance

premium, and a close IMF relation might be important plusses for banks in
addition to the insurance itself.
On the other hand, banks may find much to object to in an insurance
plan.

There is the cost to bank or customer.

There is the fact that insurane

can never provide complete protection, short of some legislative commitment.
Strong banks may believe that they are better off accumulating their own
reserves.

They may see weaker banks becoming more competitive by virtue

of insurance.

Problems may be seen in the appearance of free-riders,

mavericks, and other nonparticipants.

-18-

8.

Attitudes of Borrowers
While the insurance plan should benefit borrowers by encouraging

banks to lend, these borrowers may be concerned about possibly higher costs.
A market analysis may lead to the conclusion that costs diminish under
pooled insurance, but this would be true only if banks acting independently
were in the practice of establishing adequate reserves.
concerned about pressure coming from the insurer.

Borrowers might be

They might be concerned

about substitution of the insurer for the bank in case of loss, if the plan
so provides instead of leaving administration of the delinquent loan in the
hands of the bank.

Declaration of default by the insurer might loom as a

threat to the borrower.

If participation is a matter of choice for the

borrower, he faces additional problems.

9.

Broader Economic Implications of an Insurance Plan
Insurance plans may have secondary repercussions that are not

intended but would nevertheless be damaging.
discipline of the market.

Insurance might reduce the

It might lead to subsidization, of the weak by

the strong, or of private interests by the public.
to "adverse selection."

It might be vulnerable

It might be viewed as a "bail-out" for banks.

It

might inappropriately change the allocation of credit from what the market
would bring about.
On the other hand, these dangers seem avoidable, through the proper
structuring of the plan, through charging of differential rates and, in general
by taking these concerns into account in the design and the administration of
the plan.

The basic principle of risk-pooling is in any event well established

has widely been recognized as beneficial, and should be applicable also to the
field of international bank lending.

#