View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Tuesday, MAY 9, 1978
3:00 P.M. LOCAL TIME (10:00 A.M. EDT)




INTERNATIONAL LENDING AND THE EUROMARKETS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
1978 Euromarkets Conference
sponsored by the
Financial Times
London, England
Tuesday, May 9, 1978

INTERNATIONAL LENDING AND THE EUROMARKETS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
1978 Euromarkets Conference
sponsored by the
Financial Times
London; England
Tuesday, May 9, 1978

The Euromarkets are one of the success stories of our day,
which needs a few successes.

In difficult times, they have helped

to keep trade flowing, they have financed investment and development,
they have enabled countries to deal with their balance-of-payments
problems.

The Euromarkets serve as a reminder of what a market

system can achieve when it is allowed to operate freely.
But the Euromarkets also have been a cause for concern
from time to time.

Supervisors, commercial bankers, central bankers,

and perhaps even the public have worried periodically about the
soundness of the Eurobanks, the soundness of the Euroborrowers,
and the possible inflationary implications of the market.
this worrying has helped to forestall the problems.

Perhaps

In a well-

functioning market, crises worried about in advance usually do not




-2-

occur.

By not dealing with these matters here I do not mean to

imply that grounds for worry have been altogether eliminated.
First and foremost, however, the subject to worry about today
in the syndicated loan market is spreads.
are of the same opinion.

Many of you probably

What my remarks may lack in novelty I

hope they can make up by being emphatic.

Euromarket Spreads
The dramatic decline in spreads between lending rates and
the cost of money is not altogether unprecedented.
spreads also were severely squeezed.

In 1972-73,

For a spectrum of 15 major

borrowing countries, they reached an approximate low, on a weighted
average basis, of 1.11 per cent in the fourth quarter of 1973.

That

was a time of dangerous euphoria when international indebtedness was
much lower than it is today, the expansive forces of the international
economy much stronger, and when one could not anticipate the financing
problems that were to follow the rise in the price of oil.
In 1974, spreads expanded once again as the realization of
risk in Euromarkets, following the Herstatt and Franklin failures,
pushed risk premia to more realistic levels.

By the fourth quarter

of 1975, they reached a level of 1.63 per cent and remained approximately
on that plateau through the middle of 1977.

More recently, however,

spreads once more have been cut to the bone by lessened balance of
payments financing needs and the pressure of strong competition among
banks resulting from slack loan demand in home markets, and by a
large inflow of funds.




-3-

For particular groups of countries, the time pattern varied
somewhat, with those for non-OPEC IDCs rising through 1976 and those
for small OECD countries declining appreciably after 1975.
Naturally, there are always special circumstances that
could explain low spreads on particular loans.

At the short end,

a one-shot deal at a very low spread, in the hope of being able to
employ the funds more productively later, may be preferable to
locking them in for a longer period at a not much better return.
At the longer end, there may be considerations of collateral
business, ongoing relationships with the borrowing country, hopes
of regulatory preferment in winning approval for branches and the like
that may explain, although not justify, extraordinarily low margins.
There are fees, especially for lead banks, there may sometimes be
balances, and sometimes banks can fund a quarter or even a helf
of a per cent below Libor (London Interbank Offering Rate), especially
if they are prepared to do a little mismatching of maturities.

On the

other hand, I would not accept a bank's explanation of an unjustifiably
low spread on the grounds that the bank had to maintain its share of
the market.

The implication that because some banks overlend, all

others ought to do the same obviously points toward trouble.

The Composition of the Spread
I would, if I may, devote a few minutes to a conceptual
exercise in studying the anatomy of a spread.
at least three elements:




The spread must cover

(1) The risk premium to cover losses,

(2) the contribution to the bank's cost of capital related to the
loan, and (3) the out-of-pocket and overhead operating costs.
The risk premium must be evaluated for each individual
loan in the light of the circumstances of the borrower.

An overall

indication of loss prospects in international lending, which, of
course, does not apply to any individual loan, can be derived from
the loan losses that banks have already experienced.

For a small

group of American banks, the average loss during the years 1976-77
on foreign loans has been about.one-third of one per cent, as
against a domestic loan loss ratio of over three-quarters of one
per cent.

The range of individual bank experience, of course, is

a good deal wider, especially on foreign loans.
The past, moveover, is not necessarily a guide to the future.
Differences in individual bank experience as well as differences in
the credit standing of particular borrowers, indicate that it
would not be appropriate to impute to the spread some fixed risk
component.

But the order of magnitude, to date, of loss experience

on international loans, when compared with syndicated loan spreads,
nevertheless provides a useful benchmark.
The spread further must contain a contribution toward the
cost of the bank's capital.

It is a function of the bank's capital

to support the holding of risk assets.

Of course, if the bank

believes itself to be acquiring a risk-free asset —

a short-term

inter-bank placement might come close to this -- the acquisition
would not raise the bank's ratio of risk assets to capital.




The

-5-

return on such an asset might not be required to make much of a
contribution toward covering the cost of capital.

But assuming a not

unusual capital/total assets ratio of 5 per cent, the spread on a
loan of average risk must cover the required income before tax on
capital equal to 5 per cent of the loan.

Given further a not

untypical return on capital after tax of 10 per cent, and a marginal
tax rate of about 50 per cent, the loan must earn 20 per cent of
5 per cent of capital, or 1.0 per cent.
capital surely are quite modest.

These assumptions concerning

Strictly speaking, it might be more

appropriate to base this calculation on the ratio of risk assets to
capital, which would call for a higher return.

For some banks, however,

particularly non-U.S. banks, capital ratios may be even lower than the
5 per cent illustratively assumed.

To the extent that banks and their

supervisors regard such ratios as adequate, the cost-of-capital
component of the spread is reduced.
Concerning the operating costs of putting on a loan, I
have no information, although I have heard complaints about the
high level of rents, the high price of lunches, and the costs inflicted
by recent U.S. tax changes affecting American citizens abroad.
Putting the foregoing data together, it would appear that
a spread of 1.0 per cent, that for a while was considered a minimum,
hardly gives a well capitalized bank an adequate return on capital and
a reasonable risk premium, with nothing left over for operating costs.
A spread of .75 per cent does not cover the cost of capital of even
a very modestly capitalized bank plus a reasonable risk premium.







-6-

Banks that are putting on loans at such a spread, or even less,
must have substantial funding advantages, or income and other
benefits from the loan, aside from the spread, or they are
diluting their earnings.
I do not find at all convincing an effort to justify low
premia by a misguided appeal to the principle of marginal cost
pricing —

that is, that any income above out-of-pocket costs is

so much money to the good.

There are risks to be taken into

account, and there is the bank's balance sheet, with its capital
ratios and corresponding cost of capital, to be considered.

A

measure of cost that ignores these legitimate components of marginal
cost undermines the application of a sound economic concept.
While spreads have been declining, maturities have been
advancing.

In terms of risk, this implies an added cost which is

not covered by the movement of spreads.

Longer maturities convey

an indirect benefit in reducing the prospective bunching of roll­
overs and in reducing somewhat the disparity between the length of
loans and the pay-out period of the investments that, however
indirectly and remotely, are financed by them.

But the lender

must bear in mind that loans of long maturity are almost certain
to be tested by a variety of adverse circumstances.
A Comparison of Euromarket and U.S. Bond Market Spreads
It is interesting to compare changes in the dispersion of
spreads among high- and low-risk borrowers in the Euromarket with
similar changes among borrowers in the American bond market.

In

the Eurocurrency market, the rise in spreads was accompanied by
a narrowing of the dispersion.

Spreads rose most for what had

originally been the low spread borrowers.

In the U.S. bond market,

spreads widened as interest rates rose during 1973 and 1974.

The

lower quality risks had to pay substantially more relative to the
higher grades.
In terms of credit risk, it would seem that the American
market evaluated changing risks rationally, allowing for a greater
increase in the danger of failure among the borrowers where risk
was perceived as high to begin with.

The Euromarket, to the contrary,

appeared to wipe out differences among borrowers and to assign to
all of them a similar higher risk rating.• Conceivably, this may
reflect the difference between credit risk and sovereign or country
risk.

The circumstances of 1974 may have been of a sort to exacerbate

primarily the element of country risk.
A second and more casual observation may follow from an
inspection of quality spreads in the Eurocurrency market and the U.S.
bond market.

In the Eurocurrency market, the spread even for

relatively weak risks rarely has gone much above 2 per cent,
representing a differential over prime risks of perhaps 1.5 per
cent at most.

In the U.S. bond market, the differential between

A-rated utilities, by no means a weak risk, and U.S. Government
bonds in 1975 went above 2 per cent.

Given the absence of country

risk in the U.S. bond market, it is hard to avoid the impression




-8-

that the latter evaluates risks more sensitively and conservatively
than the market for syndicated Eurocurrency loans.

Whether front

end fees and the like provide reason to modify this assessment
significantly, cannot be said with any assurance.

The Recent Decline in Spreads
Why are spreads declining so sharply in the Euromarkets?
Are risks clearly diminishing?




Or have banks come under such pressure

to lend that the market has become clearly a borrower's market?
To both questions, the answer is "yes."
of many borrowers has improved.

The condition

But unfortunately it is also true

that the pressure on banks to lend has increased.

To that extent,

the decline in spreads must be viewed as a very uncomfortable
development.
Among the pressures converging on the bank are the following:
(1)

Liquidity is high.

Rising assets and liabilities in

the Euromarket do not absorb limited supplies of reserves, as they
would in national money markets.

Monetary authorities, in pursuing

their monetary targets, in some cases have overshot, in part due to
exchange market intervention.

Monetary authorities must bear in

mind that money creation in the Euromarket, although historically quite
limited, nevertheless occurs, and must factor it into their overall
assessment of liquidity needs.

-9(2)

Domestic loan demands in many countries other than

the United States has been weak.

In the United States, the large

money market banks have experienced weaker demand than the rest of
the banking system.

They, of course, are the principal U.S. lenders

in the Eurocurrency markets.
(3)

There is pressure to maintain earnings growth, on

penalty of being downgraded by security analysts.

If their stock

fails to advance, their prospects of raising new capital diminish.
Yet they need to raise new capital if they want to continue to
lend.
(4)

Banks have built up large establishments and have

built in high costs which require continued activity.

It would

be costly to disassemble and perhaps later reassemble these.
(5)

Borrowing countries today are exerting powerful

pressures, reminding banks of the need to maintain a continuing
relationship, and meanwhile taking advantage of their ability
to repay and refund earlier loans at lower spreads.
(6)

Finally, all banks look at their peer group.

So long

as all do the same, no single bank needs to feel that it is making
an obvious mistake.

That, in some circles, is known as the lemming

theory of banking.
Obviously, however compelling these considerations may
appear to the individual bank, they do not justify a lowering of




-10credit standards.

Banks in the Euromarkets enjoy a degree of

freedom from control that is unusual in domestic banking systems,
although they, and particularly U.S. banks, are by no means unsuper­
vised and unregulated.

U.S. banks, in particular, are subject to

the regular examinations and other supervisory activities of the
U.S. banking agencies, no matter where their branches and sub­
sidiaries are located.

But it is true that the volume of lending

in Euromarkets is less directly controlled by central bank action
than is the volume of domestic lending.

Hence, banks should be

disciplined all the more by high credit standards as they expand
in these markets.
The Euromarkets, as I said at the beginning, have given
evidence of what a market system can achieve when it is allowed to
operate freely subject only to prudential supervision.

The continuance

of this freedom will depend on the responsibility with which it is
used.




ïable 1
Interest Spreads and Maturities of Euro-currency Credits to
Selected Countries Arranged by Category

Q4 1973
Average
Spread
(basis
points)

Non-nil ISCfli/
OPECi/

Q4 1975

V

Q4 1976

Average
Spread
Average
(basis
Maturity
_(yearsl_ points)

4.6

132

5.5
5.3

Average
Maturity
(years)

Average
Maturity
(years)

177

7.3

158

8.3

5.6

159

5.5

104

8.5

113S/

7.0S/

116£/

6.0£/

123

7.2

120

6.5

109

6.8

83

7.2

Average
Maturity
(years)

Average
Maturity
(years)

121

10.9

165

5.4

187

5.1

179

129

7.3

167

5.7

133

7.0

Eastern E u r o p e ^

61

8.8

149

5.5

129

Small OECD Countries^/

94

9.1

158

6.5

137

Average of individual
countries:
Weighted
(Unweighted)

(

Minimum spread f o r .
individual loansS/

111
99)
56

< 18)

(

9.5
9.6)

163
(166)
125

( 58>

5.7
(5.6)

161
(159)
113

Average
Maturity

.teesra).

(58)

_ C 66)

5.6
(5.7)

153
(155)
88

5.3
(5.9)

155
(149)

( 75 )

7.0
(6.4)

88

£/ Average spreadsfor Individual countries shown In Table 3 weighted by total volume of borrowing by each country,
b / Rate shown is lowestT rate for syndicated Eurocurrency credit to all borrowers. . To avoid extreme observations, rate
reported Is lowest rate for minimum of three credits.
cj Observation from a single loan.
Source: IBRD, Borrowing in International Capital Markets, various issues.




Qi 1978
Average
Spread
(basis
points)

Average
Spread
(basis
points)

( 68)

«4 1L977
Average
Spread
(basis
points)

Average
Spread
(basis
points)

Range of spreads among
country groups

L977

132
023)
57

8.2
<8.1)