View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

INFIATION AND ACCOUNTING
Ex Post Notes on
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the meeting of the
Mid-Atlantic Council of the
National As.sociation of Accountants
Arlington, Virginia
Friday, November 11, 1977

Speaking not as an accountant but as an economist, I
am aware that I am taking a chance in discussing the impact of
inflation on accounting.

I shal l begin with what is perhaps

the most widely discussed aspect of this relationship -- the
accounting for profits.
Profit Adjustments
Everyone knows that profits are distorted by inflation
and how very difficult it is to come to grips with this phenomenon.
The simplest cases are, of course, inventory and fixed assets.
Accounting for iµventory on a FIFO basis and accounting for fixed
assets and their depreciation on an original cost basis both
overstate "capital sustaining or economic" profits.
In its national income accounts, the Department of
Conrrnerce now makes allowance for these defects by referring to
"operating profits."

For example, in the third quarter of 1977

profits before taxes and before being adjust ed for inflation




-2-

amounted to $174 billion or 9.1 per cent of GNP.

Operating

profits after making the Department of Commerce adjustments
were 15 per cent lower, equal to only 7.8 per ·cent of GNP, a
figure that is historically very low.

And while the accounting

and tax systems do not reflect this, the stock market does.
Moreover, the Department of Corrunerce makes its adjustment on the basis of straight-line depreciation and 90 per cent
of Bulletin F useful lives.

If fixed assets were depreciated at

a more accelerated rate or were assigne.d shorter useful lives
than those used in the Department of Conunerce adjustments, underdepreciation resulting from inflation would turn out to have
been even more severe.
Incidentally, the Department of Connnerce adjustments
are, of course, conceptually analogous to those required by the
SEC for its 10-K reports.

There, a statement has to be made about

replacement costs of inventories and fixed assets.

That statement

can serve as a means of approximating the impact of inflation; but
.it falls far short of a complete evaluation.
These misstatements of profits have far-reaching effects
on the economy.

They interfere with the expansion of plant and

equipment, with the progress of the recovery, and ultimately with
the ability to create jobs.

Perhaps the most critical difficulty

in the present expansion is that businessmen are hesitant to make




'··

-3-

conunitments for new capital spending.
for this is the profit picture.

At least one of the reasons

That is, although profits seem

to be close to their historic percentage of GNP, inflation adjusted
they are much less.
Devices for Compens a ting Profits Distortion
Some ad hoc devices that help to cope with the inflation
problem do exist in our accounting system.
inventories on the basis of LIFO.

Firms can value their

I am always surprised, however,

to find that relatively £ew firms have shifted from FIFO to LIFO.
Based on a 1976 survey of 600 firms taken by the American Institute
of Certified Public Accountants, a.bout 50 per cent of the firms
were using LIFO in 1975, compared to about 25 per cent in 1973.
Those firms that continue to use FIFO induce a larger degree of
overstatement in profit determination.
Under-depreciation based on original cost can to some
extent be compensated by accelerated methods of depreciation, by
shorter Bulletin F lives, and by availability of the investment
tax credit.

However, these are not

ad~quate

substitutes for a

more comprehensive inflation adjustment.

General-Price-Level Accounting
More

~ophisticated

methods of dealing with inflation in

the accounts of a company have been suggested.

Oneis so-called

general-price-level accounting (GPLA) which was proposed by the




-4Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) in their much discussed
draft, "Financial Reporting in Units of General Purchasing Power,"
issued December 31, 1974.

Although it has been applied in a

tentative way by many firms, it now seems to be quiescent.
Moreover, I find ·GPLA potentially misleading.

The key to

GPLA is to revalue nonfinancial ass ets and equity by the rate of
inflation without regard to the changing prices of individual assets.
Doing this leads to the firm's net monetary asset position; a company is
either a net debtor or a net creditor.

During inflation, a company

then benefits from a net debtor and suffers from a net creditor
position.
When these GPLA adjustments are made, some very interesting
results are obtained.

A staff economist at the Federal Reserve Bank

of Boston recomputed the domestic profits of nonfinancial corporations
which in 1975 were $102 billion.

When adjusted by GPLA methods,

profits were reduced to $68 billion.

Of that amount, moreover,

only $44 billion were operating profits.

Some $24 billion were

profits resulting from a negative net monetary asset position,
reflecting the fact that the corporate sector 'as a whole is a
. net debtor.

These profits are of little value to the firm

because they are not cash profits.
be paid from them.

No dividends, no taxes can

If such profits were made the basis for tax

liabilities, or, by internal corporate decision, the .basis for
dividend payments, the company would soon find itself in trouble.




-5For example, Con Edison was quite profitable by GPLA standards
on the day the com
pany cut the dividend.

Thus, GPIA

seems to me a dubious way of adjusting for inflation.

There is

one area where I be lieve it has applicability -- the banking system.
To this aspect I will revert later.
Current Value Accoun ting
Current-value accounting
ment for inflation .

(CV~)

is another form of adj ust-

CVA emphasizes the present ·value of assets

and the way they may have appreciated or depreciated over time.
This again is a noncash adjustment.

It focuses on the value of

assets and liabilities and the way in which they may have changed
rather than on cash flows.
The same economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
found that the 1975 profits just mentioned,

$102 billion before

adjustment, rose to $146 billion when adjusted to CVA methods.

One

reason for this is that when inflation strikes, interest rates rise.
When interest rates rise, the market values of bonds that are already
outstanding fall.

By CVA standards, this decline in bond values

represents a profit to the issuer.
Due to inflation, for example; a 4-1/2 per cent bond issued
by a company years ago may now be selling at 70 in the market.

The

company could buy the bond a t a profit of 30 cents on the dollar, and
add that to i t s profit account .




However , the las t thing probably

-6-

that a company would want to do during inflation is to issue shortterm debt in order to buy in long-tenu debt.

In fact, the company

probably would be very glad that it had th at old debt outstanding.
But this noncash item goes to swell total profits by CVA method s.
Pushed to an extreme, if a company were in really bad
shape and its bond depreciated severely, the CVA method would suggest
mounting profits.

If tax liability were based on these profits, the

company could go into receivership.

This kind of current-value

accounting, therefore, would not be a helpful procedure to adjust
corporate profits for the effect of inflation.
For a test of a sensible approach to the adjustment of
profits for inflation, look at the stock market.
fooled by phony profits.

The market is not

Any accounting system trying to adjust for

inflation ought to reflect the judgment and the verdict of the market.
It ought to produce a stated level of profits approximately equal to
what the market seems to think is the
and 1975, stocks were very low.
large discounts from book value.

leve~

of profits.

Many enterprises were selling at
Those years, of course, were a period

of maximum impact of inflation on profi t s.

The market seemed to say

that, in 1974-75, profits were exceptionally low.




During 1974

-7-:-

Bank Profits
Of particular interest is the problem of bank profits
during inflation and how to deal with it from an accounting point of
view.

Banks differ from other corporations in that nearly all of their

assets are monetary.

Therefore, it seems to make sense to apply a

general price index to the valuation of bank assets and bank liabilities,
as GPLA does.

When both assets and liabilities are mostly in money,

the value of money as measured by either the consumer price index or
the wholesale price index or the GNP De.flat or does qecome meaningful.
It is clear, therefore, that general-price-level accounting seems to
be most nearly applicable to banks.
Let us look at the structure of a bank's balance sheet.
All its assets are monetary, except the building it may own which is
usually a small part of a bank 1 s
are monetary.

ass~ts.

It also has equity capital.

Its liabilities, by definition,
Typically bank equity capital

amounts to from six to ten per cent of total assets.

The value of

the building, if any, normally is substantially less than the equity.
Thus, banks typically are net creditors.
their monetary liabilities.
in inflation.

Their monetary assets exceed

And a net creditor is, of course, a loser

Banks are natural losers in an inflation.

Bankers may think that their profits are adequate because
they make 10-13 per cent on capital after taxes, . of which they pay out
only one-third to one-half in dividends while retaining the rest.

But

GPLA. indicates that the truth, as far as accounting can reveal it, is




-8-

otherwise.

In 1974, banks actually paid out in dividends more than

their GPLA-adjusted earnings.

In two other years, 1973 and 1975,

their earnings barely exceeded dividends.
Banks paid taxes, however, on unadjusted earnings.

There-

fore, when relating bank taxes to adjusted earnings for those years,
the rate turns out to have been

twi~e

its reported value.

Meanwhile

the GPLA-corrected rate of return on equity for the period has been
of the order of 3-5 per cent, instead of a reported 10-12 per cent.
Taxes and dividends are real.
phenomenon.

Profits are an accounting

What inflation is doing to banks is a form of decapitaliza-

tion.
Another aspect of banking during inflation reflects
certain losses caused by inflation.

The problems of the REIT's

have to do at least in part with inflation and rising interest
rates.
Let me turn to another

inflation.

asp~ct

of · the banking system under

While it has to do perhaps as much with losses as with

inflation, many of these losses have been produced by inflation.

In

particular the problems of the REIT' s ha.v e in good part been caused
by inflation and rising interest rates, -although also, of course, by
ill-conceived projects.
One possible way of dealing with the accounts of a bank is
to apply current value accounting and to require a bank to write down
to market instantly its weak loans.




Suppose a bank owns bonds that it

-9··

has bought at par..
70.

Meanwhile the bonds have gone _ own to perhaps
d

Should the bank write off that de preci ation immediately even

though presumably the bonds will event ually be paid off at par?
current value accounting system says write "it off now."

A

And if

that were done, capital might have been reduced and the bank might
have to be closed.
Applying this technique to the banking system can have
drastic cons eque nces.

It carries us back to the conditions of the

1930's when examiners did something similar.

They went into the

banks, looked at the bond portfolios, which sometimes were well
below cost and made those banks write off such bonds.
were closed in consequence.

Many banks

In 1938, the bank supervisory agencies

concluded that this was not a good system.

The examiners were

instructed to give the banks time to work out some ·Of their
depreciated assets or to wait until they recovered.

This involves

the risk, to be sure, that a bank may carry an asset too long at
book value instead of making proper adjustments on its books for a
probable loss.
There are good reasons nevertheless ' for proceeding as we have
been doing since 1938, letting a bank postpone a write-off if there is
the prospect of collecting at maturity - - based on considerations that
are implicit even .in the "Conceptual Framework" of FASB.
theory of risk diversification.

I refer to the

That theory says th.at assets that move

independently in price, so that one asset may improve while another




-10-

deteriorates, are helpful in limiting risk exposure.

Risk increases

when all of a bank's assets depreciate at the same time.
Therefore, when banks diversify their assets, and it turns
out that some assets do well and some do less well, they are following
that portfolio philosophy.

Their assets then should be looked at as

a portf olio, rather than as individual pieces.
badly, it need not be
chance to work out.

writ~en

If any one of them does

off immediately, but should be given a

Else diversification would become very difficult.

A bank could then only focus on the

saf~st

assets.

A diversified

portfolio instead allows a bank to take somewhat larger risks on
individual assets.

Such a strategy does, of course, require

acceptance of the prospect of losses on some

ot

the higher risk assets.

If those losses are compensated by better performances of other assets,
the overall performance of the portfolio will be superior.

In a well

put together portfolio there will almost inevitably be some losses
just as there will be some successes.

The accounting system should

make it possible for the bank to carry these assets temporarily rather
than to write them off immediately.
Inflation Premia in Interest Rates
Let me turn to another problem that inflation poses for
savers, for investors, and, therefore, for accountants.

I refer to

the treatment of the inflation premium that the market has built into
interest rates.




We all understand that ·an 8 or 9 per cent interest

-11-

rate is not a normal economic rate. The "real" interest rate has
been estimated to be in the range of 3 per cent.
inflation premium.

The rest is

If inflation proceeds indefinitely at a rate

of 5-6 per cent, then a bond bearing 8 or 9 per cent interest
provides an inflation premium just enough to cover the inflation
loss to the investor.
But this investor must be nontaxable in order to get an
adequate benefit from the inflation premium. For a pension fund or
for Yale University, a 5 or 6 per cent inflation premium takes care
of the depreciation of the purchasing power of a bond in an ongoing
5-6 per cent inflation.

It becomes in effect a continuing repayment

of capital, the remaining value of the debt being reduced (by inflation)
in real terms.

A taxable investor who pays, say, 50 per cent tax on

his 8 per cent interest, has 4 per cent left after tax.

After 5 or 6

per cent inflation the real return to this investor is negative.
The reverse is true from the
be a corporation or a homeowner.
'interest is tax deductible.

sid~

of the debtor, who might

To the debtor, the 8 per cent

The 5 per cent inflation premium, in

effect a repayment of principal, is part of the deductible amount.
The government thereby helps the debtor _
and hurts the creditor. Since
inflation by its nature hurts the creditor and helps the debtor; we
hardly need the government, with its tax laws, to add to the difficulty.
But that is exactly what happens.




The government, by insisting on

-11-

taxability and tax deductibility of the inflation premium intensifies
the effect of inflation.
This, incidentally, also furth e r intensifies the inflation
itself. · A firm paying an interest rate of 8 per ce nt presumably builds
that interest rate into its .price, treating it as a cost.
what it is doing is to charge to the customer part of the
of its debt, by raising its price.

Actually,
amortiz ~ tion

Inflation thus accelerates.

Cost of Capital
These cost distortions are at least matched by further distortions which relate to the cost of c a pital.

I said earlier that for

a taxable debtor the real interest rate may be negative.
suggest that capital would be cheap to
is not so.

a

corporation.

That would

However, that

The cost of capital to a corporation is a composite of

interest cost and the cost of . equity capital.

The cost of equity is

represented not so much by the income that needs to be earned on new
issues, which today are infrequent.

It is determined mainly by the

equity that is outstanding and by what has to be earned on it in order to
,
induce the stockholder. to hold his stock at the going price.

Today, in

the face of a low real interest rate, the cost of equity nevertheless
is very high.

This is · implicit in the price/earnings ratios observable

in the stock market, which are very low.

A price/ea rnings ratio of 6,

where years ago one might have s e en oae of 18, means that the cost of




-Bequity capital to that corporation has become 16.7 per cent when
earlier it was 5. 6 per cent.

Since much _th~ .bie:_ s.t part of total
e:e_

new financing is by means of equity, including, of 'course, retentions,
the dominant element in the cost of capital is in fact the cost of
equity capital.
debt.

Its very high cost today outweighs the low cost of

The overall cost of c api tal, the refore, is high.

This is

another reason why today business investment is sluggish.
Inflation is at the bottom of this high cost of capital.
It is inflation that the market responds to when it lowers the multiples .
Recent experience has shown that rising expectations of inflation
adversely affect stock prices.

The causal chain seems to run from

higher inflation to higher interest rates to lower stock prices, and
from higher inflation to lower operating profits after taxes to lower
stock prices.

The distortions that, as we have seen, enter into the

economic calculus through these various channels, enhance the adverse
effects of inflation.
£apital Gains Taxation
'

Let

m~

supply one last instance of the impact of inflation

on accounting that promises to become relevant if one of the tax
reform proposals that have been about should attract further attention.
It has been propo sed to tax capital gains at ordinary rates, with no
allowance to be made for inflation in evaluating these capital gains.




-14This is being argued despite the fact that for many investors the
value of their stock mainly reflects past inflation.
i~e.,

In real t .e rms,

in constant dollars, such holdings often · show little gain or

even a loss.
The justification given for this deliberate disregard of the
effect ~

of inflation is one that does not stand up under analysis.

is argued that no

inflatio~

It

adjustment should be made for investors

because none is made under the tax system for other income receivers.
People who

~arn

income from employment

likewise are exposed to higher

taxes as inflation raises them into higher tax brackets.

If no adjust-

ment is made for this (as a matter of fact, periodic tax cuts to offset the shift into higher tax brackets

frequen~ly

are proposed), there

also should be no adjustment for the inflation effect on capital gains.
I think this is a profoundly wrong argument.
This can be seen easily when one traces through what is th·e
effect of inflation on a taxpayer with employment income and one with
only investment income.

Suppose the taxpayer with employment income

has the median family income of about $14,000.
10 per cent inflation.

Assume, for simplicity,

If all prices and incomes adjust perfectly,

this raises the taxpayer to $15,400.
$14,000 investment income.

Suppose a second taxpayer with

If everything adjusts perfectly to inflation,

including dividends, that investment income will go from $14,000 to
$15,400.




For both taxpayers taxes increase equally, by something more

-15-

than 10 per cent, reflecting the progressivity of the tax structure.
But this is true only if the taxpayer receiving only investment income
does not make any portfolio changes.

If, as in this example, everything

adjusts perfectly to 10 per cent inflation, he will have unrealized
gains (over and above his initial p_ sition) of 10 per cent of his
o
portfolio.

Let us suppose that , at a 5 per cent yield, his $14,000

income implied initial assets are $280,000.
10 per cent to $308,000.

Inflation raises these by

He has a nominal profit of $28,000 and, if he

realizes this, he now pays capit a l gains tax.
real gain at all.

The taxp ayer has had no

Even if he paid at less than ordinary rates, he would

be worse off than the taxpayer whose income is from employment.
would have suffered a loss in real terms.

He

It is clear, therefore,

that no inequity would be involved in making an inflation adjustment
for capital gains even if none were made for ordinary income.

Failure

to make such an adjustment would convert the capital gains tax into a
capital levy with further damage to cap_
ital formation and investment
incentives.
My talk has covered a random assortment of instances in which
inflation distorts nominal magnitudes.

It is up to the accountants

to find ways of dealing with these p:r:-oblems.
described go part of the way, but
right direction.

s~me

The techniques I have

of them do not even go in the

Better approaches are needed.

This, I think, is

the conclusion at which one must arrive from the point of view of the
accounting profession in the face of a continuing inflation.




•• '

ti;.

-16-

There is a broader conclusion, however.

That conclusion

is that inflation probably cannot be fully coped with by accounting
techniques.

Inflation damages the economy no matter how profits, truces,

values of assets and liabilities are restated.

The only way to avoid

the damages, and to get back to more meaningful accounting data, is to
put an end to inflation itself'.




11