View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY, JANUARY 24, 1980
1:45 P.M. EST




THE FUTURE R0I£ OF THE COMMERCIAL BANKS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the conference on
New Approaches and Techniques for Managing Country Risk
New York City
January 24, 1980

THE FUTURE ROLE OF THE COMMERCIAL BANKS
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the conference on
New Approaches and Techniques for Managing Country Risk
New York City
January 24, 1980

1 am happy to have this opportunity to address the seminar on
managing country risk.

The topic once more has become a timely one.

Two-

and-a-half years ago, some of us participated in a symposium on "financing
and risk in developing countries," the organization of which, like that of
the present seminar, also was in the capable hands of Steve Goodman.
Some of the problems that we have to discuss today are quite
reminiscent of those of mid-1977.

Curiously, however, this is in good

part not because the problems have persisted, but because, after at least
in some degree having gone away, they have now come back with a vengeance.
By that I mean, o£ course, that in 1977 we were still concerned with the
problems created by the oil price rises of 1973-74.

One pressing issue

was the allocation of OPEC-induced current account deficits.

Should the

deficits end up in the LDCs where the capital inflow might be most needed,
or in the industrial countries that could best finance them?

In the period

following, the surplus of the OPEC nations largely vanished, a massive
deficit appeared in the United States and disappeared again, and the
developing countries continued to grow, thanks in large part to
continued heavy bank borrowing.




Now the OPEC surplus is back bigger

-2-

than ever.

One factor» however I believe, has changed significantly:

the

ability of the banking system to handle the ensuing deficits on the terms
and conditions to which the market had become accustomed in the meantime.
During the last two years or so until very recently, the market
has become very much a borrower's market.

Minimal spreads, a severely

compressed differential among spreads for different borrowers, longer
maturities, and the large size of loans all document this condition.
There are several reasons why this situation is likely to change.
lie both on the side of the borrowers and of the banks.

They

On the side of

the borrowing LDCs there is, first, the higher burden of oil imports.
This comes on top of an already visible increase in burden of debt
relative to the ability to carry it.

At the new level of oil prices,

the oil import bill will absorb, on average, one-third of the export
receipts of oil-importing LDCs in contrast to an earlier one-sixth.
This leaves less available for debt service as well as for payment of
other imports.

It changes, in other words, the meaning of a given debt

service ratio.
There is, second, the previous rise in the burden of debt.
This rise is by no means spectacular, but neither can it continue to be
overlooked.

Aggregate foreign debts of non-oil LDCs approximately tripled

in the five years from 1973 to 1978 and rose perhaps an additional 25 per­
cent in 1979.

These rough numbers ignore unrecorded short-term debt, which

adds to the burden, as well as the growth of foreign exchange reserves,
which reduces it.

But the proportionate increase in the debt would hardly

be much altered if these variables, which probably rose on roughly the same
scale during the period, were taken more fully into account.

Since oil-

importing developing countries experienced substantial inflation in their




-3-

fotfeign trade prices —
in import unit values —
less.

perhaps 70 percent in export unit values and 80 percent
the increase in debt burden in real terms is a good deal

What is more, the real interest rate paid by the average borrower was

probably negative.

LIBOR (London Inter-Bank Offer Rate) for 90-day dollar

obligations averaged 7.9 percent over the years 1973-78, as against an average
price increase of about 11.0 percent.

Only in 1979, did LIBOR at 12.0 percent

exceed a rise in the price of primary products (excluding oil) of 10.4 percentage
points.

Of course, the experience of some countries is bound to have differed

from these averages.

Because of these differences, the real interest rate,

defined as the nominal interest rate minus the expected rate of inflation over
the life of a loan, in an international context, is less meaningful than in a
domestic context.
But despite negative real interest rates, the familiar debt ratios have
tended to increase.

From 1973 to 1978, the average ratio of gross debt to GNP

rose from 17 to 23 percent, that of net debt (after deducting reserves) to GNP
from 11 to 17 percent, and debt service requirements to total exports rose from
14 to 17 percent, for a group of 99 non-oil LDCs.

Recognizing the wide variance

of these ratios among countries, as well as great differences among countries
in their ability to handle debt, and keeping in mind also the limitations of
any form of ratio analysis, these data nevertheless signify some deterioration
up to the end of 1978.
It is at this point in the story that the rising price of oil threatens
to raise the deficit of non-oil LDCs from $25 billion (including official transfers)
in 1978 to perhaps $50 billion (including official transfers) in 1980.

To me,

this suggests a different response to the problem of deficits than was widely
adopted in 1973-74.

If at that time the principle was to finance rather than

adjust, today it may need to be reversed.

Many developing countries will be well

advised to stress balance-of-payments adjustment in preference to additional




-4financing.

Some adjustments are already underway, as witness the devaluations

in Brazil, Chile, and Korea.

Such adjustments should be easier to make in

today's environment than in 1974-75 because world economic activity is better
maintained presently than it was then.
My main concern here today, however, is with the lenders rather than
with the borrowers. How much of the borrowing of the developing countries will
the bank be able and willing to handle?

Outstanding claims on non-oil LDCs of

all banks reporting to the BIS rose at an average rate of 23 percent per year
from December 1975 through June 1979.

Such a rate of growth exceeds, of course,

the rate of overall credit expansion that can be sustained by any banking system
not in the grip of galloping inflation.
For instance, total bank credit in the United States, over the same
3-1/2 years, grew at an average annual rate of 10.9 percent.

Shifts in the

composition of assets, implying faster growth of some and slower growth of
other components are, of course, always going on and are indicative of the
flexibility of the banking system; but as particular components, such as IDC
loans, come to constitute an increasing share of the tocal, their growth
necessarily must slow down.

Thus, the rapid growth of LDC lending had some

of the characteristics of the filling of a vacuum.

Lenders, borrowers, and

regulators all have an interest in seeing that this vacuum is not converted
into a compression chamber.
pattern.

That is implicit in the dynamics of any growth

In the case of bank lending to non-oil LDCs, it is the consequence

also of particular limitations encountered by banks in terms of their risk
exposure with respect to particular borrowers and their overall ratio of
capital to assets.




-5-

U.S. banks already have substantially slowed their lending to
developing countries.

Between December 1975 and June 1979, their share

in total international claims on non-oil LDCs of banks reporting to the
BIS dropped from 54 percent to 38 percent.

Their share in annual net

new lending (after repayments) dropped from 46 percent ($13 billion) to
15 percent ($6 billion).

The U.S. bank share in claims on oil-exporting

countries dropped from 52 percent to 35 percent; their share in net new
lending dropped from 58 percent to 5 percent.
The substantial slowing that has taken place in LDC lending by
U.S. banks sometimes is overlooked when attention is focused on the
geographic location of the lending office instead of on the nationality
of its control.

For example, U.S. balance of payments data on bank claims

cover all banking institutions located in the United States, including
the U.S. agencies and branches of foreign banks.

Thus, while these data

are useful for capital flow analysis, they do not necessarily reflect the
office of the bank responsible for the lending decision, nor the country
of the bank which bears the ultimate exposure to risk on a loan.

Control

of lending policy, as well as risk exposure, of course, runs to the bank’s
head office independently of the country in which the lending office happens
to be located.
The slowing of LDC lending by U.S. banks no doubt reflects in part
their often-voiced concern about the inadequacy of spreads on syndicated
Eurocurrency credits.

It reflects also the stronger demand for funds in

the U.S. domestic market.

Finally, it may reflect tightening monetary

policy and rising interest rates in the United States as well as greater
monetary ease in many foreign countries, although to the extent that




6-

foreign banks make dollar loans, the volume of their lending is also
influenced by U.S. monetary policies.
Capital ratios and LDC risk exposure of American banks may also
be assumed to have played a role in their decision to slow LDC lending.
The ratio of equity capital to total assets of the nine U.S. banks with
the most international business, after improving from a low of 3.7 percent
in 1974 to 4.3 percent in 1976, once more deteriorated to 3.9 percent by
mid-1979.

Bank earnings have been inadequate to keep bank capital growing

in line with the inflation-driven volume of bank assets.

Assuming a

dividend payout of one-third, banks would have had to earn 18 percent on
assets in order to keep up with the approximate 12 percent average growth
of bank assets during the years 1976-78 if they are to rely almost exclusively
on retentions.

But new stock issues, which could relieve this situation,

have been very difficult to make, given the very low price/earnings ratios
characteristic of leading American banks.

These reflect, in turn, the

market's realization that the real value of bank capital and, therefore,
bank earnings is reduced by a factor of about 3/4 of the going rate of
inflation, making allowance for nonmonetary assets equal to only about
1/4 of capital that could protect that capital against inflation.
Foreign banks in many instances are less constrained by capital
than are American banks and thus can accept lower spreads.

In some

countries, lower capital ratios than in the United States are charac­
teristic of most banks.

In some countries also, foreign banks receive

better protection against inflation by a greater ownership of nonmonetary
assets such as participations and real estate.

Maintenance of capital

ratios has been easier for such banks because a better inflation-fsotection




-7-

of earnings hat permitted stock issue?.

Ir. some countries.. iinelly, bam t, a; <

owncc anc backed by their government.
But it is probably in terms of risk exposure vit.I:

1

e s p r i t : it

particular borrowing countries that U.S. banks have encountered some oi
their most obvious limitations.

The in-house country limits set by banks,

arrived at normally on the basis of careful country risk analysis, are, of
course, fairly flexible.

But banks nevertheless have to watch carefully their

concentration ratios, which are monitored by means of the Federal Reserve FDIC - Comptroller of the Currency's country risk evaluation system.

These

focus on the percentage of capital exposed to risk in each particular country.
For most industrial countries, regulatory considerations are not particularly
inhibiting.

Exposures over 25 perccnt of capital funds in any such country'

are "listed1' in examination reports, but usually no comment on such exposures
is made.

For most G-10 countries, lending by many U.S. banks exceeds 25 per­

cent of capital.
For many LDCs, however, exposures even to most of the financially
stronger borrowers, would be "listed" if the level exceeded

1 0

percent of

capital funds, and exposures in excess of 15 percent receive special comment
in the examination reports.

The largest LDC borrowers would be subject to

such comment in a number of U.S. banks.

Comment does not necessarily imply

that there is an inherent credit weakness, but is made to alert management
to exposure levels.

While banks are not prevented in any way from making loans

to LDCs in excess cf the comment level, a decision to raise exposure significantly
is properly one to be taken in full awareness of the facts by senior management.
Qualitative differences in exposure, as inherent for instance in the difference
between short-term, trade-related credits and long-term, syndicated loans,
are important.




8

If banks with exposures above the comment level wished to avoid
an increase in these exposures, their Tending could increase only in
proportion to the growth of their capital, i.e., roughly on the order
of 10 percent of present lending levels.

For the group of banks having

much the largest part of the loans to Brazil and Mexico, for instance,
such an internal decision would mean an increase in loans to Brazil of
about $1.5 billion over the next year.
Broader participation in LDC lending by larger nun&ers of banks
would help to make more flexible the supply of bank loans for LDCs.

The

reduction in the share of U.S. banks in this lending, accompanied by
strong expansion, at least until recently, by banks of many other
countries, represents one such form of diversification.

However,

within the confines of U.S. banks, there has been no broadening of
participation in foreign lending generally.

On the contrary, the share

of the nine largest money center banks in loans to foreign banks and
nonbanks remained virtually unchanged at 68.2 percent in December 1977 and
68.6 percent in June 1979.

The share of these banks in loans to LDCs

stood at 63.9 percent and 64.5 percent during the same period.

Meanwhile,

15 regional banks reduced their share in total loans to foreigners from
17*4 perçoit to 16.5 percent iriiile that in loans to LDCs remained constant
at 18.7 percent.

Other banks, accounting for relatively small amounts,

reduced their share of lending to LDCs.
So far, the slower LDC lending by U.S. banks seems to have
been compensated by more aggressive lending on the part of the banks of
other countries.

If the slower expansion of LDC lending by U.S. banks

has continued since mid-1979, there Would nevertheless be room in the




-9portfolios of banks in other countries or the obligations of creditworthy
LDCs.

Most of the large non-U.S. banks still appear to have a lower ratio

of foreign assets to total assets than do large U.S. banks.

They should be

able therefore to at-conmodate a relative increase in foreign lending.

It

seems likely though, chat lenders will have to be offered better terms and
that borrowers may have to look toward adjustment rather than financing to
an increasing degree.

In this regard, it might be noted that Japanese

banks have recently also curtailed their foreign lending.
For the longer run one must ask whether the world's banking
system can meet increasing demands by the LDCs even if these demands
reflect genuine investment financing rather than the financing of consumption-oriented oil imports.
LDC lending.

The banks have, in a sense, pioneered

Their lending practices have many desirable attributes

that would make a continued strong role of the banks in LDC financing
constructive.
There is no shortage of funds in world financial markets,
thanks not only to OPEC surpluses, but to the demonstrated ability of
the Euromarkets to draw funds from all over the world by offering
attractive interest rates.

Nor is there a shorage of high quality

assets in which OPEC and other surplus countries, if there are any,
could invest these surpluses.

The difficulty resides in recycling

these funds toward the deficit countries, where they would be at some
risk.

It seems incumbent on OPEC to assume some of the risks inherent

in the process.
New forms of bank pioneering may be needed.

For instance, banks

might take on the role of arrangers or brokers of loans.




The risk of

-

10 -

such loans would fall on the ultimate lender, Instead of a bank sub­
stituting Its own credit for that of the borrower.

Such activities

would not strain the banks' capital ratios.
The IMF may have to play a larger role.

Banks have been partly

at fault in creating a situation in which the IMF has been brought into
the financing picture only after the banks have vanished from the scene
as willing suppliers of a weakening borrower's credit.

Banks have seemed

to act as if countries were either creditworthy, in which case they got
all the money they wanted, or they were not, in which case no further
credit was offered.

Some form of cooperation with the IMF, which would

strengthen the borrower's performance through IMF conditionality, would
be preferable to such an all or nothing approach.

As we look toward the

longer-run future, more new forms of LDC financing, will probably need
to be developed.




#