View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
WEDNESDAY, DECEMBER 3, 1980
6:30 P.M. EST




FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
to the
Chesapeake Chapter of Robert Morris Associates
Bethesda, Maryland
Wednesday, December 3, 1980

ÎT.DERAL RESERVE POLICY AND TTTE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
to the
Chesapeake Chapter of Robert Morris Associates
Bethosda, Maryland
Wednesday, December 3, 1980

I am happy to .peak to you tonight about Federal Reserve policy
and the economic outlook.

My most useful contribution to your view of

uhe outlook, I should think, would be to comment on what I would regard
as a desirable and, I hope, realizable pattern for 1981, and then to discuss
the role of monetary policy in such a recovery.

A Desirable Path
The economy has become highly sensitized to short-run influences.
This suggests that wc cannot count firmly on having the kind of steady
expansion that we used to enjoy after the recessions of the past.

At 10 per­

cent inflation, developments inherently become unstable. Desirable would be
a moderate rate of expansion that would allow enough slack in the economy
to begin winding down the inflation.

In the past, cyclical expansions have

almost invariably been accompanied by price increases at the raw material
level, although unit, labor costs hnve fallen as productivity gains increased.
The outlook for productivity r'ti:is, in this round cf the cycle, is not strong.




2-

Accordingly, we must lean on the side of caution and strengthen all our
defenses against inflation.

Monetary policy is only one of these and

cannot be expected to do the job alone.

I would like to make this point

clearly even though I shall address myself principally to monetary policy.

Monetary Policy Concerns
Monetary policy, as I have said before, will have to play an
important role in the development of the economic outlook.

Currently, a

number of concerns have arisen, as a result of the movements of the
aggregates, of interest rates, and of output and prices that have given
rise to widespread debate about the conduct of monetary policy.

I would

like to comment on some of these criticisms and to state the case as I
see it.
For about a year now, monetary policy has operated under a new
procedure.

It has shifted from a looser to a tighter form of control of

the monetary aggregates, and accordingly to a diminished emphasis on interest
rates.

This shift was made because in practice interest rates were not moved

sufficiently, especially when the economy was strong, to maintain adequate
control of the aggregates.

Under the new system, both the rate of growth

of the aggregates and interest rates have been very volatile.

This has caused

concern on the side both of those concerned primarily with high interest rates
and those concerned primarily or exclusively with the growth rate of the
monetary aggregates.




-3-

"High interest rates.”

Concern has been voiced with the level to which

interest rates have risen -- levels which are regarded by many observers as
likely to slow significantly the immediate recovery prospects.

This rise

in interest rates is to some extent the logical consequence of a more rigorous
control of the aggregates.

When the economy strengthens, the demand for

money and credit picks up.

In the face of a stably growing money supply,

the market will drive up interest rates.

The only way to avoid this would

be by accommodating the increased demand for money and credit, which would
mean to give up tight control of the aggregates and to overshoot the targets.
Beyond that, however, one must ask whether interest rates are
"really" high.

If we consider that the average mortgage and business

borrower probably pays a marginal tax of at least one-third, an 18 percent
prime rate becomes 12 percent after taxes.
of inflation according to the CPI.

That is about the present rate

In the short run, therefore, the present

prime rate is barely positive in real terms.
To be sure, this rate may pose a cash flow problem for the borrower.
Even though very moderate in real after-tax terms, interest payments need to
be financed.

However, for the taxpaying borrower the kindly government makes

its contribution every three months and to that extent relieves the burden.
The situation is different for a borrower who has no profits and
who at best gets a loss carry-forward from a high interest rate.

It is

different also for a borrower who takes the standard deduction.

However,

at today's mortgage rates it is reasonable to assume that most new mortgage
borrowers itemize their deductions.




-4-

Historically high interest rates, to be sure, also have a
psychological deterrent effect.

They are in collision, moreover, with

institutional rigidities such as usury ceilings and lenders' rules of
thumb concerning the debt-carrying ability of borrowers in different
income brackets.
diminishing.
lifted.

Nevertheless, these institutional restraints seem to be

Usury ceilings have been preempted or are in process of being

Lenders find ways, in effect, of basing their assessment of debt-

carrying capacity upon borrowers' income a couple of years from now.

A

changing attitude on the part of borrowers is characterized by the not
unusual comment that a rate that seemed an outrage some time ago now looks
like a bargain.

Interest rates too variable?

Another criticism has focused on the

wide variability rather than the level of interest rates under the new
procedures.

This was, of course, foreseen when these procedures were

instituted.

But even so the extent of the swings, from a federal funds

rate of 19-1/2 to one of 8-3/4 and a Treasury bill rate of 15-3/4 to one of
6-1/2, has been surprising.

One would have thought that while the funds

rate might become very bouncy, other rates would become somewhat detached,
since the funds rate is a daily rate and most other money-market rates are
for longer periods up to one year.

This, by and large, has not happened,

or only to a slight degree and quite recently.

One might also have expected

that, if a sharp rise in short-term rates were regarded as evidence of a more
effective anti-inflationary policy, long-term rates would not go up and
perhaps might even come down.




This, too, has by and large not happened,

-5-

w hich r a i s e s some q u e s tio n aH.^it w hether th e m arket re g a rd s even no m in ally
>

h ig h i n t e r e s t r a t e s a s adequ ate to cu rb e x c e s s iv e money c r e a t io n and

i n f ’ a tio n .

Concern about wide volatility of interest rates has been expressed
particularly in the international sector, including, of course, by foreign
observers.

These rates have caused exchange rates to move in ways not

clearly justified by underlying economic factors.

It has made it more

difficult for other countries to move their interest rates as their domestic
conditions made advisable. Thus, the new procedures are being pursued at
some cost to our own international sector and to foreign countries.

They

will have to be justified in terms of their ultimately better anti-inflationary
results.
Wide i n t e r e s t - r a t e f lu c t u a t io n s have a ls o a c c e le r a t e d c o n s id e r a b ly
th e im pact o f m onetary p o lic y on th e d o m estic economy.

T y p ic a lly , m onetary

p o lic y has worked w ith a la g o f 6 -9 m onths, w ith o u t t h i s r e la t io n s h ip b ein g
at a ll r e lia b le .
and v a r i a b l e .

In th e words o f M ilto n Fried m an, th e la g has been long

B u t v e ry sharp swings in i n t e r e s t r a t e s may w e ll have q u ic k e r

e f f e c t s , p a r t i c u l a r l y on h o u sin g and perhaps a u to m o b ile s.

The drop in

i n t e r e s t r a t e s t h a t began in A p r il o f t h i s y e a r preceded th e f i r s t t r a c e s
o f an u ptu rn t h a t began in J u ly o r August by only th r e e or fo u r months.

Had the money-supply targets been fully achieved during the intervening
months, interest rates presumably would have dropped still further, the
economy might have reacted even earlier or at least more strongly, and
the subsequent bounceback of interest rates and their impact on the recovery
would likewise have been still greater.




-6-

Wide swings in interest rates, of a sort that older techniques
would not have produced, thus may have some advantages. They seem to
accelerate control over the cyclical fluctuations of the economy.
the other hand, they are doing so at some cost.

On

Among the costs conceivably

might be a deterioration of financial and economic institutions, such as
the bond market, financial intermediaries, and the housing industry.

Inter­

national relations and perhaps freedom of trade and capital movements could
also suffer.

Fluctuations in money growth too wide?

It has been said, probably

correctly, that under the new procedures we have had the widest fluctuations
in both interest rates and monetary aggregates.

This fact must be seen

against the unusual cyclical background of the year 1980 —

an inflationary

boom, a long-predicted recession, and an unexpectedly early recovery.

The

rapidly shifting demand for money and credit under these circumstances
combined with the imposition and removal of credit controls accounts for
the sad record of the monetary aggregates —

an overshoot during the

inflationary boom, a collapse during the recession, with substantial short­
fall from the targets, and rapid resumption of growth in the recovery phase
leading to serious overshooting of some though not all of the targets.
If the interest rate fluctuations had been the result of changes
in supply, overshooting of the monetary targets presumably would have brought
a decline at least of short-term interest rates, and undershooting would
have brought a rise.

But since the monetary undershoots and overshoots were

the result of changes in demand, interest rates moved in the same direction




as the growth rate o£ the aggregates,

¿he

entra’ h-mk could have moved

more forc'cully to keep trx» moi:etary aggrenrt-.es on ^rack.

Tlv t would have

increased the response oZ interest rates* to oomand -hiits and would have
wionned their swings.

liy,in part at le^t, accommodating t!>c supply of

money to changes in demand, interest-rate ¡novements were "moderated."
It has been argued that the aggregates should have been kept on
track rather than allowed to over- and undershoot.

The ensuing wider

interept-rate fluctuations would then have had the effects I have already
sketched —

stronger and quicker impact on the real sector, wider exchange-

rate fluctuations, probably sc-e damage to the financial system.
The experieo.ee of this year supports the view that the causal
relationsuip of monetary-policy action runs from the money supply to interest
rates to the economy.

It does not run directly from the money supply to

the economy, regardless of interest rates.

High interest rates up to April

(together with the credit control program) curbed the boom.

Sharply dropping

interest rates from April through June restimulated the economy.
interest rates beginning in July once more dampercd the expansion.
the.«e effects was achieved with an unusually short lag.

Resurgent
Erch of

To attempt to trace

a direct effect of the money supply upon the economy, one would have to assume
zero lags.

Money supply and the economy both boomed until April, both

contracted thereafter, and both reaccelerated at almost the same time.

In

f-his relationship, it is, of course, far more plausible to assume that movennnts in the economy more or less instantaneously changed the demand for money,
than that changes in the money supply more or less instantaneously changed
the economy.




-8We use the money supply as our policy instrument not because it
directly controls the economy, but because it leads to better setting of
interest rates.

Historical experience shows that so long as the monetary

authorities tried to set interest rates, they were likely to act too late
and, on the upside at least, also too little.

Setting the money supply,

and letting it, in interaction with the market, set interest rates, is
better procedure.

That, as I see it, is the rationale for preferring a

money supply to an interest rate focus for monetary policy.

This argument

gains in persuasiveness the higher the rate of inflation, because the
appropriate level of interest rates becomes increasingly hard to discern.
It is sometimes argued that tight control of the monetary aggregates,
adhering firmly to preannounced targets, would lead to stabler and ultimately
lower interest rates than a procedure that accepts temporary over- and under­
shoots.

In the longer run, this seems very plausible.

Firm control of

monetary growth at a diminishing rate will help bring down inflation.
Diminishing inflation will bring down interest rates.

With prices reasonably

stable, interest-rate fluctuations should also be minor.

But in the short

run monetary restraint, however steady, cannot quickly bring down inflation
nor interest rates.

The most plausible view is that the main impact of

monetary restraint on prices occurs with a two-year lag.

Expectations as the crucial factor?

A sophisticated version of the

"tight money-supply control" view holds that even though the inflation itself
will not be immediately affected, a credible monetary restraint will reduce
inflation expectations.




These in turn will immediately reduce interest rates,

-9-

especially at the long end.

Monetary restraint will be the more credible

the more stable it has been.

This calls for a completely steady rate of

growth of the aggregates, free from temporary overshoots and undershoots.
ITence, it is argued, it is not enough to hit the targets over the period
of a year, as the Federal Reserve has done to an approximation, or even over
one or two quarters.

Even though this would probably be sufficient to avoid

real-sector impacts, the intervening monthly or quarterly deviations would
destabilize expectations.
This view raises fundamental questions.
freedom of speech and
can be established?

In a democracy with

inquiry, is there a way in which firm expectations
Probably a large majority of the population judges

monetary policy by interest rates, not by the growth of the money supply.
Quite possibly a majority of the economics profession takes the same view.
Many people believe that if policies are pushed to extremes, they sow the
seed of their own reversal.

There are enough uncertainties and loose ends

about a money-supply strategy, such as the shifting character of the
individual aggregates to inject reasonable doubt into any money-supply
proposition.

Moreover, the relation between the monetary aggregates and

GNP has suffered major shifts, including one from 1974 to 1977 which
reduced the amount of money demanded at a given level of income and
interest rates very substantially.
Under such circumstances, it may be risky to become irrevocably
committed to a numerical set of targets.

And it may take a philosopher-king,

rather than a Congress and President, not to interfere subsequently with
a target that for some reason has become unpopular.




-10-

The difficulty of forming hard expectations under such conditions
is pointed up by experience abroad.

The countries that have been most

successful in conducting a noninflationary monetary policy are Germany
and Switzerland.

Both countries have money-supply targets.

But both

countries have been quite relaxed about their adherence to these targets.
Switzerland in 1979 altogether dropped its target and accepted an 8.5 percent
increase in M-l.

Germany overshot its targets in 1977 and 1978.

Comment

that reaches us from German and Swiss sources usually is to the effect that
reacting to weekly data means overreacting, so long as the target is observed
over longer stretches of time.

Evidently, the citizens of Germany and

Switzerland do not lose their expectation that inflation will he fought
successfully if the central bank overshoots occasionally.

But, it must be

added, their expectation probably derives from belief in a stronger commit­
ment of the entire government and the private sector to price stability than
exists in the United States.
Even so, it is hard to believe that the people and the markets
should change their long-run expectations fundamentally with every month
of high or low numbers that is published.

Interest rates do move up and

down with over- and undershoots of the aggregates.

But surely interest rates

move because most market participants reason that the Fed will eventually have
to counter the deviation and thereby cause interest rates to go up and down.
It seems unlikely that they should interpret a deviation as a permanent
change in policy implying higher or lower inflation later on and interest
rates to match.




-li­
l t would be t r a g i c i f th e view should g a in ground th a t th e
F e d e r a l R e se rv e p o s s e s s e s some u n exp lain ed power to c o n t r o l i n f l a t i o n
i f on ly i t w i l l c o n t r o l th e a g g re g a te s no t j u s t on an av erag e b a s i s but
m onth-to-m onth and perhaps w eek -to -w eek , and t h a t th e a d m in is t r a tio n , th e
C o n g ress, and th e p r iv a t e s e c t o r , h av in g thrown t h i s r e s p o n s i b i l i t y upon
th e F e d , have no f u r t h e r r e s p o n s i b i l i t y f o r ca u sin g and c u rb in g i n f l a t i o n .
Improved s h o r t-te r m m oney-supply c o n t r o l i s d e s i r a b l e , so lon g as
i t does n o t , d u rin g r e c e s s i o n s , le ad us to n e g a tiv e r e a l i n t e r e s t r a t e s .
But i t i s no p an acea.

I n p a r t i c u l a r , any form o f m oney-supply c o n t r o l ,

w hether based on m onthly o r on sem i-an n u al o r annual t a r g e t s , may become
enorm ously c o s t l y u n le s s i t i s accompanied by a move to a b alan ce d budget
as a g e n e r a l r u le and by th e r e l a x a t i o n o f th e m yriad o f government p r i c e r a i s i n g a c t i o n s , ran g in g from a l l k in d s o f r e g u la tio n to im port c o n t r o l s ,
farm p r ic e s u p p o rts , in d e x in g o f government pay s c a le s and s o c i a l s e c u r i t y ,
and th e D a v is-B a co n A c t.

A firm m onetary p o l ic y , m oreover, should be

accom panied by a c o n s t r u c t iv e d ia lo g u e o f b u s in e s s and la b o r re c o g n iz in g
t h a t b o th s id e s s u f f e r from i n f l a t i o n , and, as I have s a id many tim es
b e f o r e , by a ta x -b a s e d incom es p o l ic y .
a lo n e w ith o u t g r e a t c o s t and damage.

The F e d e r a l R ese rv e can n ot do i t
In o th e r w ords, p a ssin g th e buck to

th e Fed i s n o t th e answ er.

Are th e t a r g e t s e x c e s s iv e ly r e s t r i c t i v e ?

F o r th e y e a r 1981,

th e F e d e r a l R ese rv e t e n t a t i v e l y has s ta te d th e fo llo w in g money supply
growth t a r g e t s :

3 - 5-1/2 p e rc e n t f o r M-1A, 3-1/2 - 6 f o r M -lB , 5-1/2 -

8-1/2 f o r M-2, and 6-9 f o r M-3.

T hese t a r g e t s a re to be a ffirm e d

o r m o d ified by F e b ru a ry 20, 1981, th e d a te on




-12-

which the Federal Reserve is required to present its targets to the Congress.
The 1981 targets are 1/2 of one percent below those for 1980, following the
principle that the money-supply growth should be brought down gradually and
steadily.

Adequacy of these targets for a period of resumption of growth has

been questioned by some observers.

Can a rise in nominal GNP of perhaps

9-11 percent, consisting of not much less than the 1980 rate of inflation
and a very modest rate of growth, be financed by the aggregates growing at
the indicated rates?
This will depend on the behavior of velocity.

If there is enough

of a rise in velocity, the growth of the "effective money supply," that is
money growth plus velocity growth, will be adequate.

Otherwise, velocity

growth will have to be brought about by rising interest rates, and these
could interfere with economic expansion.
Velocity responds to three factors —

higher interest rates, which

may be an undesirable way of achieving a velocity increase, increases related
to the phase of the business cycle, based on a not altogether reliable tendency
for velocity to increase during the first year of a recovery, and shifts in
the money demand function.

These shifts, which I have already referred to,

are a new element in the velocity picture which apparently did not exist before
1974.

Since mid-1974, a whole collection of standard money-demand functions

used routinely in econometric models has misperformed on a large scale by
overpredicting the amount of money that would be demanded at given levels
of income and interest rates.

By late 1979 this overprediction amounted to

anywhere from 9-17 percent of M-1A and M-1B, or something like $35-70 billion.




-13-

This overprediction of the amount of money required in fact made the
Federal Reserve's targets, which seemed quite restrictive, turn out relatively
unrestrictive.

Shifts of this kind raise questions about a stable relation­

ship between money and income upon which the money-supply targeting approach
rests.

The problem can be remedied only if these shifts can in some degree

be predicted and integrated into the target ranges.
The evidence seems to show that shifts of this kind tend to occur
after a new peak of interest rates has been reached and passed.
of experience encourages firms and households not only to

This sort

economize routinely

on their money holdings but to undertake a thorough restructuring of their
techniques for holding money, such as shifting to zero-balance or overdraft
arrangements.

It seems likely, therefore, that the experience of very high

interest rates in 1980 is again motivating change in the practices of holding
money, minimizing the use of demand deposits and perhaps currency.

This

would allow for a shift in the demand function that would make the Federal
Reserve targets for 1981 adequate without relying mainly on higher interest
rates to achieve higher velocity.

The uncertainties inherent in this approach

underline the advisability of stating money-supply targets in terms of a
range rather than of a single number.
In conclusion, I would like to say that the money-supply targets
tentatively indicated by the Federal Reserve hold promise for bringing the
rate of inflation down.

This should be true so long as the targets are

achieved over time, even though not week-by-week and month-by-month.

An

essential prerequisite, however, is that monetary policy be not required to
carry the entire burden of fighting inflation but be firmly supported by a




-14-

move toward a balanced budget and other anti-inflationary, policies in the
public and private sectors.




#