View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
FRIDAY, OCTOBER 4, 1974
7:00 p.m. EDT




DARWINISM AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REFORM
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Twenty First Annual Bankers Forum
Georgetown University
Washington, D.C.
Friday, October 4, 1974

DARWINISM AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REFORM
Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich*
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Preserve System
at the
Twenty First Annual Bankers Forum
Georgetown University
Washington, D.C.
Friday, October 4, 1974

The title of my talk refers, of course, to the decision taken
by the Committee of Twenty to guide the process of international monetary
reform in an evolutionary direction.

No reference is intended to the

survival of the fittest, except perhaps with regard to the intensive
travel, working sessions, and food consumption necessitated by the
meetings of the CXX and their Deputies.
The Fund and Bank meeting which most of you have attended
has approved the work of the CXX.

Some of the governors expressed a

desire to go beyond the "Immediate Steps" proposed by the CXX and to
continue toward a long-term reform of the international monetary system
which the CXX has enshrined in Part I of its report entitled, "The
Reformed System."

But there were many speeches also in which support

for something more structured than the present system of floating was
at best moderate and occasionally completely absent.

Most of the addresses

made clear that the problem of oil has displaced monetary reform as the
chief concern of finance ministers and central bankers.

---The views expressed are my own and not necessarily those of the
Members of the Board or its Staff.







2

That attitude is undoubtedly realistic.

In my talk here

I shall try to show, however, that there can be no neat separation
between the two sets of problems.

What happens to oil, to the balances

of payments of oil-importing countries, to oil-associated capital flows,
to exchange rates, and to trade patterns and practices will decisively
influence the structure of the international monetary system, especially
such features as exchange rates, exchange reserves, and trade and
payments practices.

Oil Trade and Capital Flows
Let me review the elements of the oil problem.

On the

one side there are oil-exporting countries, which can increase their
imports only gradually and which therefore are bound to have, as a
group, a very large export surplus.
importing countries.

On the other side are the oil-

They can reduce their oil imports by conservation

and by creation of substitute sources of oil and other forms of energy.
Nevertheless, as a group they are bound to have a very large current
account deficit, which for 1974 has been estimated in the approximate
range of $50-60 billion.

What remains uncertain and to some extent

subject to policy decisions is the distribution of this deficit among
importing countries, the distribution among them of the capital flows
coming directly from the oil-exporting countries, and the distribution
of the risk associated with the enormous volume of assets and liabilities
that will be built up from these flows.

3

At the present time, some countries have both an oil deficit
and a non-oil deficit.

(The oil deficit is more correctly defined as their

’’incremental oil deficit,” i.e., that part of the oil deficit that arises
from the higher price of oil.

This concept will become increasingly

difficult to quantify in dollar terms as time goes on since we do not
know what might have happened in the absence of the oil price increase.
But it serves to clarify the principle involved.)

Other countries,

therefore, have by definition apart from their oil deficit, a non-oil
surplus.

Germany, for instance, has a non-oil surplus exceeding its oil

deficit, hence an overall trade surplus.

The U.S. also has a large

non-oil surplus, but its still larger oil deficit has so far in 1974
made for a small overall trade deficit.
Given that the surplus of the oil-exporting countries and hence
the combined deficit of the importing countries cannot be reduced below
some minimum level, changes in the deficit of any one importing country
can occur only if they are accompanied by an offsetting change in the
deficit or surplus of another oil-importing country.

By appropriate

policies, such as domestic contraction or expansion, exchange rate
changes, restriction of imports or promotion of exports, countries can
shift their deficits to other oil-importing countries or accept some
part of the deficit of others.

Several principles for the most desirable

allocation of deficits have been suggested as follows:
(1)

One proposal suggests that oil-importing countries should

eliminate their non-oil deficits.

If all countries with non-oil deficits

do this, they will thereby eliminate also the non-oil surpluses of the
remaining countries.




This policy would reflect something like what is




4

often called, "putting one!s house in order."

It would aim to reduce

the need to finance deficits, to the amount required to finance oil
deficits.

(2)

A second proposal asks each country to reduce its

combined oil and non-oil deficit to the amount for which it can find
financing in the capital market.

Under present conditions, this would

mean that some countries might not only have to eliminate their non-oil
deficits, but achieve a non-oil surplus sufficient to reduce the oil
deficit to a level capable of being financed.

Other countries then

would be forced to accept non-oil deficits on top of their oil deficits.
These other countries could be presumed to be able to find financing for
their deficits, since if the OPEC money is not flowing to the countries
that have to cut their deficits, it must be flowing to those whose
deficits are increasing.

Put differently, this proposal says that if

recycling proves difficult, i.e., if the money cannot be made to go
where the current account deficits are, the deficits should be made
to go where the money is.

That would imply acceptance of large deficits

by the countries that happen to attract most of the OPEC money.

(3)

A third proposal is that the big countries should accept

bigger deficits, even though their trade may not be large relative to
their GNP.

In that case, deficits would be distributed in proportion

to GNP.
(4)

A fourth proposal suggests that the economically weakest

countries should be allowed to postpone paying for the oil in real
resources, so as to soften the shock of their economies, while the
stronger economies accept the real burden of the higher cost of oil

5

immediately.

This would mean that the weaker countries would run large

deficits, that would somehow have to be financed, while the stronger
countries would eliminate their oil and non-oil deficits and thus
bear the full transfer burden.
If economic imagination has run riot in dealing with the
allocation of deficits, it is not surprising that ambitious ideas
have been expounded also with regard to their financing.

In the

aggregate, the amount that the oil-exporting countries must invest
in the importing countries in some form, liquid, illiquid, financial,
or real, arithmetically must equal their aggregate surplus.

But the

term "recycling,11 which is often applied to the process by which the
importing countries borrow back the funds they have paid to the oilexporting countries in order to pay them over again for more oil,
seems to take the ability of individual countries to obtain such
financing too much for granted.

The OPEC funds can flow into

international markets, such as the Eurodollar market, into international
institutions, such as tae IMF and IBRD, and into national financial
markets.

It is worth noting that, under today’s conditions of floating

rates, "capital inflows" into a national economy need not affect the
local money supply nor the level of interest rates.

They will instead

drive up the exchange rate and possibly alter the structure of interest
rates if the flows go predominantly into some particular assets.

This

confronts the countries receiving funds in excess of their trade deficits




6

with a choice.

They can facilitate an equivalent outflow, through

interest rate policy or in other ways, or they can accept upward
pressure on their currencies.

Countries that receive or borrow less

than the amount of their deficit, must adjust their balance of payments
by depreciation, import restrictions and so forth.

Failure of trade

deficits and capital inflows to match thus creates problems both for
those who receive more and those who receive less than they require.
Finally, the distribution of risk must be considered.

To

the extent that OPEC funds are recycled rather than moving directly
into the countries using them, the ultimate investment risk falls,
not upon the OPEC investor, but upon the recycler.

This could be a

bank, an international institution, a government, or in a broad sense,
a national economy.

The OPEC countries, in making their investment

decisions, naturally will seek to minimize risky in addition to
maximizing other investment gains.




Even if governments were not

inclined to supply some s )Vt of risk guarantee to OPEC investments,
these investors can, by purchasing the obligations of a government
in the open market, obtain the equivalent of such a guarantee if they
desire it.

7

Evolution
The foregoing examination of the problems created by the
high price of oil makes clear that the evolution of the international
monetary system anticipated by the CXX will in fact be dominated by
the evolution of the oil situation,where at an earlier stage it had
been reasonable to expect monetary evolution to take place against a
background of cyclical fluctuations of the type that had occurred
since World War II. That expectation today is no longer valid.

This

will be true even if the price of oil comes down substantially.

Such

a decline would convert a problem that may be altogether unmanageable
into one that could be managed with sufficient effort, skill, and
foresight.

It would not cause the problem to go away.
The surveillance of the adjustment process by the Interim

Committee (later the Council) of the IMF, as proposed by the CXX,
would probably be the principal means of crystalizing experience into
system.
One important lesson that will have to be distilled from the
experience ahead relates to countries1 preferences with respect to
exchange rates.

I have outlined above various ways in which the

financial pressures emanating from oil may impact upon exchange
rates.

Governments, of course, have options, with respect to rates,

financing, and trade policy.

As their preferences become apparent,

hopefully in a cooperative process of mutual accommodation and support,




8

the feasibility and advisability of moving toward the long-term
exchange rate objective of the CXX -- stable but adjustable rates
with floating . . .

in particular situations -- should become apparent.

The same applies to the concept of zones for exchange rates written
into the guidelines for floating.

Its feasibility and advisability

might be tested well ahead of the longer run goal.

For the time

being, it seems clear that floating rates are an essential protection
against the massive imbalances resulting from oil payments and capital
flows.
The demand for international reserves is another feature of
the system that will have to evolve from future experience.

The CXX

anticipated, with varying degrees of agreement, that countries would
establish norms for their reserve levels and would gradually move
their actual reserves toward those levels.

Exchange rate movements

and other adjustment measures were to be guided, in some not fully
settled degree, by the behavior of international reserves.
The oil situation is bound to affect the demand for reserve_a_^_
The uncertainties which that situation creates are likely to raise the
demand for reserves.

These same uncertainties, however, are likely also to

increase reliance upon floating rates which in turn diminish the need
for reserves.

There is some evidence showing that

the use of reserves has actually increased during the period of floating,
as compared with earlier years.




This does not mean, however, that more

9

reserves are needed with floating than with fixed rates.

It does mean

that during the period of floating imbalances were so large that despite
the reserve-economizing effects of the float, the desire to intervene
and limit the range of fluctuations has grown.
We should also bear in mind that it would not necessarily be wise
to increase the supply of international reserves to match whatever the
increase in demand may turn out to be.

Not only exchange rate variability,

but also inflation has been much higher than anticipated.

The

difficult process of halting inflation could be hampered by an
excessive creation of international reserves, whether in the form of
SDRs, Fund quotas, or other credit facilities.
The demand for international reserves, as it evolves in the
context of the oil problem, will contribute to defining the future role of
different reserve assets in the system. The CXX agreed in principle that
the SDR should become the principal reserve asset, with the role of
gold and currencies being reduced.

The SDR is indeed well on its way

to becoming the principal numeraire, i.e., unit of account, of the
international monetary system.
principal reserve asset.

That, however, does not make it the

Only a new supply of SDR issues sufficient to

meet the demand for reserves would do that, and there seems to be no
present prospect of any issues on that scale.

Gold has reacquired

indirectly some usefulness as an international reserve asset, by
becoming useable as collateral for international loans at a market







10

related price.

But with respect to both SDRs and gold, it must be

noted that their present usefulness as an international means of
payment seems to apply only to transactions among oil-importing
countries.

The principal deficits of these countries, however, are

not with each other, but with the oil-exporting countries.

So long as the

oil-exporting countries seek to acquire principally foreign currencies
and investments in currencies, the role of currencies among reserve
assets, especially the dollar, will be increasing rather than diminishing.
The payments and investment practices that will evolve
with respect to oil and oil proceeds will also contribute to define
the future role of currencies in the international monetary system,
especially that of the dollar.

The decisions of the CXX had reflected

the desire on the part of many countries for a greater degree of
symmetry in international financial relations.

Symmetry implied that

the role of the dollar, at least as a reserve asset, should resemble
the role of other currencies and accordingly should be greatly reduced
if not altogether eliminated.

The oil situation has created new

asymmetries in the world economy.

With the exception of a few

countries, the world has been divided into oil exporters and oil
importers.

The size and absorptive capacity of national capital

markets has been given an importance that it did not have in the
past.

In light of this, the future role of the dollar in the inter­

national monetary system may well proceed in directions not anticipated
by the CXX.

11

None of this means that the work of the CXX has been in vain,
or that their long-term blueprint should be scrapped.

In fact, the

urgency of protecting the world monetary system against prospective
pressures has increased.
into the foreground.

But a new and very large problem has moved

The future of the monetary system will depend

very much on how this problem is dealt with.