View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

RELEASE ON DELIVERY
AY, JANUARY 21, 1983
A.M. EST




CHANGES IN MONETARY POLICY AND THE FIGHT AGAINST INFLATION

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a conference on
"The Search for Stable Money"
sponsored by the
Cato Institute
Washington, D.C.
January 21, 1983

CHANGES IN MONETARY POLICY AND THE FIGHT AGAINST INFLATION

Remarks by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at a conference on
"The Search for Stable Money'*
sponsored by the
Cato Institute
Washington, D.C.
January 21, 1983

In addressing myself to the topic "Changes in Monetary Policy
and the Fight Against Inflation," I would like to begin by dispelling two
myths that have grown up about monetary policy in the United States.

One

is that until October 1979 the Fed targeted on interest rates and then
switched to a money-supply target.

The other is that the Fed recently has

given up money-supply targeting and is simply trying to bring interest
rates down by inflating the currency.
complicated.
than fiction.

Monetary policy, to be sure, is

But, this is not one of those cases where fact is stranger
The facts about Federal Reserve policy are readily available.

What is puzzling is how such myths get started and proliferated until they
are accepted as unquestioned fact.




-2The Shift to Honey-Supply Targeting
As for the alleged switch from interest-rate to money-supply
targeting in October 1979, the record shows that the Fed began to target
primarily on money supply early in 1970.

Beginning in 1975, under a joint

Congressional resolution, the Fed began to present its money-supply targets
to the Congress at quarterly intervals.

Subsequently, the Humphrey-Hawkins

Act of 1978 mandated semiannual reports to Congress of intended growthrate ranges for calendar year periods.

All this is readily available in

the public record of Congressional hearings, of Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) meetings, and numerous other public statements.
What changed in October 1979 was not the target, but the techniques
of implementing it.

Up to that time, the Fed had sought to implement its

Ml and M2 and, at times, other targets by moving the federal funds rate, i.e.,
the interbank rate, so as to influence the demand for money.

This was a

perfectly workable technique, but it suffered from a reluctance of the FOMC
to move the funds rate fast enough and far enough to keep the money supply
on track even over intervals of several months or longer.

Because nobody,

including the Fed, likes to see interest rates go up, thsre was over time a
bias in policy which allowed the money supply to expand excessively.
The 1979 shift in the implementation of money-supply targets was
from a funds-rate technique to a reserve technique.

By limiting the supply

of reserves and, therefore, the amount of money the banks could create on
the basis of these reserves, greater control of the money supply became
possible.

It was understood that this procedure would make interest rate

movements more flexible, since the funds rate would be determined by the




-3market rather than by the smoothing action of the FOMC. That the new technique
yielded a better control of the money supply -- at least in the long run -- is
indicated by the fact that while under the old technique inflation continued
to accelerate, under the new technique it has come down very substantially.
It must be noted, nevertheless, that the decline in inflation did not bear
a very stable relation to that of money growth and that inflation both accelerated
and slowed down faster than money growth, in their respective upward and downward
movements.

Evidently, allowance must be made for the impact on inflation

of many other factors besides money, including unemployment, capacity
utilization, oil and food prices, wage pressures, the exchange rate of the
dollar, and a wide array of government policies directly contributing to
inflation.

Money-Supply Targeting Still Observed
The second myth, as I have already noted, is that some time around
the middle of 1982 the Federal Reserve abandoned money-supply targeting.
The evidence, it is alleged, is that since that time the monetary aggregates
have been allowed to run somewhat above their targets and that beginning in
October, the Ml target was sharply deemphasized while Ml accelerated rapidly.
The facts, again, are on record from FOMC meetings, Congressional
hearings, and other statements.

During 1982, a pronounced precautionary

demand for money developed, which was indicated by the sharp fall in velocity
of monetary aggregates.

In other words, households and firms decided to

hold more money in relation to income and transactions than before.

They

may have been motivated to do so not only by concern about the economic
situation, but also by falling inflation and interest rate% which made the




-4holding of monoy less costly.

Since the targets were constructed on the

assumption that tha velocity of Ml would continue to rise while that of
M2 and M3 would be roughly stable, following their respective historical
patterns, the fall in velocity would have made the targets excessively
tight.
In addition to these factors affecting all the aggregates, Ml
particularly was subject to a series of unique developments.

First, there

was the repayment of some $36 billion of all-savers certificates which
most holders had to reinvest in some form.
accumulation of liquid balances.

This caused a temporary

Then came the prospect of possibly very

attractive new deposit accounts, as a result of interest-rate deregulation
by the DIDC (Depository Institutions Deregulation Committee).

One of the

new options, the money-market deposit account (MMDA) could be expected to
attract funds out of Ml, since the MMDA is a nontransaction
forms part of the broader aggregates.
account, is a transaction

account and

A second option, the super NOW

account forming part of Ml.

holders are attracted by it, funds may shift into Ml.

To the extent that
M2, in either case,

would not be affected by the bulk of these shifts, since they would be
taking place between different components of M2, although M2 would be
boosted by shifts of funds into the new accounts from market investments
excluded from M2.

Whether the rate of growth of Ml is lowered or raised

by the public's response to these two options depends on how relatively
attractive the banks and thrift institutions make the accounts, and on
how the public views the relative benefits of freedom to draw checks without
limitation, differential interest rates, and the advantages of deposit insurance.




-5Since under these circumstances the probable near-term evolution
of Ml became unforeseeable, targeting on this aggregate ceased to be advisable.
The FOMC had little alternative but to downgrade it at least for the time
being in favor of other targets.

As is evident from the last published

policy record of the FOMC for its November 16, 1982 meeting released on
December 27, 1982, the FOMC chose to give greater emphasis to M2 and M3.

Interest-Rate Targets
But, while the Fed has not given up on money targets, today the
argument is increasingly heard that the Federal Reserve ought indeed to
abandon them and instead target on interest rates.

This idea is supported

by the myth to which I have already alluded, that before October 1979 the
Fed did in effect target interest rates.

The fact is that the Fed did so

only in a much more distant period, during World War II and the late 1940's,
and to a lesser degree during the 1950's and 1960's.

In those days, people

were far less conscious of inflation than they are today.

Potentially

inflationary policies could be pursued for some time without having their
full consequences.

Even then, it was recognized by Chairman Eccles of the

Federal Reserve that the policy of pegging interest rates turned the Fed
into "an engine of inflation."

Following the pegging episode, which ended

early in 1951, the Fed devoted much of its energies to getting as far away
as it could from a rigid pegging of interest rates.
but in the event not enough.

Some progress vas made,

Efforts to keep interest rates low led to

acceleration of the money supply, especially during the second half of the
1960's.

It was realization of this defect of interest-rate targeting that

in early 1970 led to a shift to money-supply targeting.




-6To go back to interest-rate targeting now presumably would have
analagous effects.

But businesses, consumers, and home owners have mean­

while become sophisticated about inflation.
highly sensitized.
more quickly.

The whole economy now is

The inflationary results, therefore, would come much

By the same token, the ability of the Federal Reserve to

keep interest rates down in such conditions would be much less than it
was decades ago.
Low interest rates are highly desirable as a stimulant to invest­
ment and, thereby, economic activity.
earned by a low rate of inflation.

But they have to be earned, and

If they are brought abou*: artificially

by the flooding of the economy with liquidity, their sti ..ulative effect
will soon be terminated by accelerating inflation.

The way to bring

interest rates down lastingly is to bring down the inflation.

The

effort to do so did temporarily add to upward pressure on
interest rates.
come down.

But, as inflation came down, interest rates also have

It would be a tragedy to jeopardize this

3olid success for

the sake of a brief stimulus likely to be followed by eve.?, greater pain
than we have suffered so far.

Both inflación and, evertvally, unemploy­

ment could become more severe than we have seen.

Real Interest-Rate Targeting
Suggestions have been made also that the Fed cc get cn real
interest rates.

Real interest rates, i.e., interest rates adjusted t'or

inflation, are a key variable affecting the economy.

It is on them chat

investment and perhaps even saving largely depend.
The problem with targeting on real interest rates in the first
place is that the Fed cannot measure them with any precision, ii"1, aven




-7if it could, it cannot achieve them except very temporarily.

If

the Fed tried to set them higher or lower than required for market balance,
forces of contraction or expansion would be set in motion.

For a short

period, the impulse so imparted to the economy presumably would be of the
sort desired by the central bank.

But if maintained continuously, the

impulse would overshoot and defeat the central bank's purposes.
Furthermore, low real rates, while highly desirable, are so only
in the same sense that low nominal rates are desirable —
achieved in a noninflationary way.

when they arc

Low real rates, to be sure, can be

achieved also by inflation, for temporary periods.

But that would merely

assure that inflation will continue or accelerate further.

When a r_al

interest rate of say, one percent, is achieved by a nominal interest rate
of 20 and an inflation of 19, the unwisdom of this form of interest-rate
targeting quickly becomes obvious.

Low real interest rates have to be

attained by nominal rates coming down faster than inflation, rather than
by inflation rising faster than nominal rates.
In our process of disinflation, short-term interest rates have
come down from their peaks about as far as inflation has from its own peak.
Thus, real short-term rates are about unchanged.

For instance, the prime

rate has dropped from a peak of 21-1/2 percent to 11 percent and the
commercial paper rate has dropped from nearly 20-3/4 to 8 percent, while infla­
tion, as measured by the CPI over 12-month periods, has come down from a
peak of 14.7 percent to 4.6 percent.

Long-term nominal rates have not come

down proportionately, which perhaps indicates that people are still not
optimistic on the long-term outlook for inflation.




Their peak was about

-8 18 percent compared with a present 11-3/4 percent for AAA utilities.
progress needs to be made in bringing real rates down.

More

But, it will not

be durably achieved by a self-defeating increase in the money supply.

"Easing"
Frequently, the Fed is being urged to "ease" without specific
indication of what manner of easing is meant.
rates?

Is it a lowering of interest

Is it an increase in the growth of the money supply induced by the

Federal Reserve?

In the short run, the two tend to go together, especially

as regards short-term rates.

For long-term rates, the effect is less certain

and, in any event, probably much more short-lived.
Easing is desirable if it takes the form of lower interest rates
resulting from lower inflation.

But a reduction in interest rates achieved

by a sustained acceleration of money growth eventually has to be paid for by
higher inflation.

Higher inflation also means higher interest rates, that

is, a reversal of any initial reduction.

To be sure, "higher" inflation is

higher only relative to what inflation would have been if such "easing"
action had not taken place.

If th£re are strong downward pressures on prices

and wages from high excess capacity and unemployment, inflation may never­
theless continue to decline.

But, it will decline more slowly and less far

than it would in the absence of monetary acceleration.

Once excess capacity

and unemployment have been reduced to a level where they no longer work against
inflation, which indeed will take some time, all that is left of the exercise
is a greater amount of money in the economy than there would have been other­
wise, and a higher level of prices.




-9The Fiscal-Monetary Mix
Easing is urged upon the Federal Reserve particularly as a "quid
pro quo" for budget tightening.

It is generally recognizcd that the large

structural component in our present huge budget deficit, now of the order of
$70 billion or more and in danger of going much higher if nothing is done, is
at the root of many of our problems, including high real interest rates.
A reduction in the deficit, to become effective at a time when the economy
no longer needs the stimulus in order to recover, is urgently needed.

But,

would it make sense to ease monetary policy to compensate for the reduction
in purchasing power resulting from a lower deficit?

Reducing the deficit

will make a large contribution toward reducing real interest rates, as the
government's demands on the national supply of saving diminishes. Accelerating
the money supply for an extended period would mean temporarily lower interest rates
but more inflation and higher interest rates eventually, relative to the results
of a stable money-supply policy.

There is a lasting benefit to be gained

from a lower budget deficit but not from combining it with greater monetary
ease.

Trying to change the fiscal-monetary mix in the direction of greater

fiscal tightness and greater monetary case is not a meaningful policy for
more than a short period.

All the lasting benefit to be obtained comes

from the reduction in the deficit.
the fiscal-monetary area.

That should be our major objective in

It is fiscal policy, not monetary policy,

that can lastingly change real interest rates.
A temporary change in the fiscal-monetary mix is a theoretical
possibility.

If a temporary acceleration of the money supply were reversed

in a timely fashion, and the extra money put into the economy taken out




10again, no lasting damage and some temporary benefit would result.

But,

this is a degree of fine tuning that our experience shows to be virtually
beyond our powers.

Slowing the growth of money sufficiently to make up

for temporary overexpansion is difficult and painful.
create credibility problems for the Fed.

It would also

Certainly, it would be a highr

risk operation.
The best contribution that monetary policy can make is to con­
tinue to bring down inflation.

That is entirely consistent with a moderate

rate of economic growth and a decline in unemployment to less unacceptable
levels.

Only if economic growth becomes very rapid, t'hich does not seem

likely at this time, would the inflation-reducing effects of high excess
capacity and, unfortunately, high unemployment be nullified and perhaps
reversed.

The best way in which the Federal Reserve could contribute to

this continued reduction in inflation would be to continue its discipline
on the growth of money and credit.

Targeting in the Face of Monetary Innovation
Despite what has been happening to Ml, M2 and M3 seem to be
continuously usable.

They are somewhat harder to control than Ml, because

the bulk of their components are not reservable and because their marketinterest-related components make them less sensitive to interest-rate
changes.

A credit aggregate target conceivably also could serve.

There

is a choice across the spectrum from bank credit, which is a relatively
small variable, to total credit raised by all nonfinancial sectors,
including government.

Even the monetary base could serve, although a

serious problem results from the fact that three-quarters of the base




-11consists of currency and that nobody knows whete much of this currency is.
Targeting on nominal GNP I would regard as inadvisable because it is
technically difficult and because there is a clear danger of an upward
bias.

While most people intuitively sense that where money supply is

concerned, less is better than more, most would probably assume that, in
the case of nominal GNP, more is better than less.

Obviously, "more"

resulting from a higher inflation component in nominal GNP is not better.
There has been a great deal of debate over techniques of monetary
targeting.

Such debate, however meritorious, runs the risk of distracting

our attention from the principal goal, which is to overcome the inflationary
forces in the economy.

Techniques of money-supply targeting do matter.

There

is a need for continuing improvement, and for adaptation to changing condi­
tions of regulation and changing payments techniques.

But, the effect of

targeting on money-supply or credit does not basically depend on the
techniques employed.

It depends on its being done in a way designed to

reduce inflation while helping the economy to recover.

What matters is

that policies having these effects not be given up in favor of others that,
in the long run, if not immediately, would have the opposite effect.

It

would be unfortunate if those of us who regard price stability as an essential
condition of sustainable economic growth were to weaken our own cause by
continuous debate over techniques and so, in effect, put fqrm over
substance.




#