View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY, APRIL 25, 1974
7 : 30 P. M. , EDT




A RETURN TO FUNDAMENTALS
Comments by
Henry C. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Concluding Meeting of the
Series "Economic Order and the Future,"
Univer s ity of Delaware,
Newark, Delaware
April 25, 1974

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY, APRIL 25, 1974
7 :30 P.M., EDT
A RETURN TO FUNDAMENTALS
Conunents by
Henry c. Wallich
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Concluding Meeting of the
Series "Economic Order and the Future,"
University of Delaware,
Newark, Delaware
April 25, 1974

It is a privilege to have the last word in a series of
lectures in which so many distinguished speakers have preceded me.
They all have, in one way or another, addressed themselves to the
theme, "The Economic Order and the Future."

I find the theme

congenial, because in speaking about the economic order one is
compelled to come face to face with fundamentals.

If our present

condition appears puzzling and even disturbed, it is, I believe,
because we have not paid enough attention to fundamentals.
I am hopeful that the tendency to ignore fundamentals is
abating.

Of late we have made, to problems calling for action,

responses I believe to be fundamentally right.

Let me begin by

sketching some of these perplexities and predicaments.




2

Domestically, our economy is going through a period of
rising prices that is almost without precedent.

At the same time,

the upward growth trend of the economy was interrupted during the
quarter that just ended, and unemployment rose higher than one would
like to see.

Scarcities of all sorts developed, some, like oil, due

to the action of foreign suppliers, others, among them many relating
to domestic industrial products, owing to inadequate productive
capacity here at home.

Internationally, the currencies of the world

fluctuate against each other, sometimes by inexplicably large margins.
Together with the enormous trade deficits imposed upon the oil
importing countries by the exporters, this causes concern over the
future of international economic relations.
Often in the past, we have met problems of this sort with
improvisations that would provide "quick relief" but would hurt us
in the long run.

As a result, we are always living in the long-run

aftermath of short-run expedients employed years ago to deal with long
forgotten emergencies.
ho~ever,

In the face of our present difficulties,

our record has been better.

in avoiding temptations of that sort.

We have on the whole succeeded
This gives me hope that we

may indeed be on our way back to the recognition of some fundamental
truths.

Let me exemplify.
In 1971, we went to wage and price controls because an

inflation that was milder than the present one was not yielding as
rapidly as we would have liked to the remedies available in a free




3

market economy.

Today, if I read the record correctly, a conviction

has taken hold, with the Congress, with the Administration, with
labor, and with business, that controls are a superficial remedy
that may help somewhat in the short run but that in the long run
does mainly damage.

In all probability, the remnants of these

controls will be allowed to expire on April 30.

We are going back

to a system in which price stability must be achieved through the
balance of supply and demand in markets that should be as competitive
as we can make them.
Take another example.

When food and later oil and gasoline

became scarce and prices skyrocketed, a public debate ensued whether
rationing should be resorted to.

The Congress discussed also a roll

back of oil prices to deal with the consequences of the shortage.
We abstained from such measures.

They might have brought some short-

run relief, but they surely would have been damaging to the basic
fabric of our economy.

Today it seems fair to assume that market

forces will be allowed to work out the problems of supply in the
areas of food, oil, and other materials.
Let me cite a third example.

In the face of a drop in the

"GNP during the first quarter it might be tempting to take massive
action to restimulate the economy, as has sometimes been done in
the past.

The result often has been that the action took effect

only with a lag and hit the economy at a time when stimulation was




4
no longer needed and restraint would have been more in order.

This

time, so far at least, we have managed to avoid that mistake.
As a fourth and last example, I shall turn to the international field.

Wide fluctuations of exchange rates have severely

tested the ability of our producers to maintain their position in
international markets.

Large international flows of capital have

challenged our ability to conduct a monetary policy oriented
exclusively toward domestic ends.

In the international area, too,

it would have been tempting at times to reach for controls of
various sorts.

Nevertheless we have abstained from the introduction

of new controls.

In fact, we have removed the controls over capital

movements that had previously been imposed.

The world has not come

to an end over this, and will probably be a better place because
more farsighted policies have been followed.
The actions I have cited have one connnon denominator.

They

have put the long-run health of the economy ahead of short-run
pain relief.

Instead of worrying about the next six months, we have

done what was right for the next ten years.

Instead of becoming

wholly absorbed in the. day-to-day performance of the economy, we
have focused on conserving its underlying structure for the long pull.
This has been a welcome change from our frequent tendency to focus
on the urgent instead of on the important, and to give priority to
short-run expediency over long-run fundamentals.




5

The examples I have cited, important as they are, represent
isolated instances.

It would not be difficult to find examples

pointing in the opposite direction.

For that reason, it is necessary

to try to arrive at a clearer view of where we want this economy
to go in the long run, what sort of economic structure we intend
to have, under what kind of rules and laws we want to live.

In

other words, we must give thought to the nature of a durable economic
order.

I would like to examine with you some of the areas in which

particularly important decisions are pending concerning this enduring
order.
The Price Mechanism Versus Central Control
There is never a shortage of data that seem to suggest that
the price mechanism is no longer working properly.

Big organizations,

whether business firms or labor unions, it is said, have so much
power over prices and wages that the laws of competition, of supply
and demand, no longer can be relied upon.

Hence it is sometimes

argued, with particular eloquence for instance by Ken Galbraith,
that government should seek to control these powerful entities and
in that way move toward a much more centrally planned economy.
Nobody can deny that big business and big labor today
exert considerable power.

We are not a nation of small merchants,

small-scale manufacturers, and of workers dealing with their employers
from a position of weakness.




But we should remember that concentrations

6

of economic power existed also in the 19th Century.

The anti-

competitive behavior of railroads, of the trusts, was effectively
dealt with.

Competition was preserved in large areas of the economy.

Today, the work of the price and wage control agencies and what they
have learned about the behavior of business and labor, suggests that
supply and demand are far from inoperative as guides to economic
action.

Economic theory has discovered far more subtle responses

to prices and interest rates, on the part of firms and households,
than had previously been believed to exist.

Improving econometric

techniques, made possible by computers, have succeeded in making
visible these subtle and nevertheless pervasive and powerful
influences in the market.

In many respects, theorists and

econometricians today know more about market responses, regard
them as more important, and find them applicable to wider areas,
than they did in the past.
Some people view this stress on market behavior, on the
effect of prices, on choices and trade-offs, with a degree of alarm.
They may have an ideological commitment to enlarging the role of
government, possibly _because they are skeptical of a system that
tolerates considerable income inequality and allows profit and
private property to remain important incentives.

I do not share

'
'
..

that ideological commitment.

But if I did, I would not regard

reliance on markets and prices as being in conflict with such an




'

7
ideology.

The market system is one thing, private ownership and

profit is something else.

The two are related, but not identical.

The defenders of the market system do indeed of ten argue that
these institutions are inseparable, that a market system cannot
survive under anything but private ownership or possibly even farreaching laissez-faire conditions.

I would not altogether ignore

the reasons they adduce, but neither would I attach decisive weight
to them.

Historically, the market system and private ownership

have gone hand in hand.

I hope that we shall not find ourselves

making the experiment, but in strict logic they are separable.
Countries like Yugoslavia seem to be supplying evidence that a
government can take advantage of the price system, of relatively
free markets, and of competition, in order to improve the performance
of an economy where ownership is vested in government.

If one

happens to believe that government is good and that more of it would
be better, it is nevertheless a mistake to conclude that therefore
the price system must be bad.
The Size of the Public Sector
But we need not go to theoretical abstractions, customary
though this kind of approach may be in a university environment, in
order to debate meaningfully the role of government.
ways,




the , q~estion

In many everyday

of the proper role of government is always with us.

8

It is with us in particular because of the ever pressing question of
the appropriate size of the public sector.
Paul Samuelson frequently refers to our economy as a "mixed"
economy, meaning that it is partly public, partly private.

In fact,

only about 21 per cent of the GNP is accounted for by Federal, State,
and local expenditures on goods and services.
are private sector expenditures.

The other 79 per cent

Sometimes I have wondered how Paul

Samuelson would describe an economy in which those proportions were
reversed -- about one-fifth private, four-fifths public.

It is not

plausible to me that a public sector which so far has been limited
to little more than one-fifth justifies calling an economy "mixed."
My doubts are not completely removed when I am reminded that the
Federal Government engages i n additional expenditures, such as
Social Security and welfare, which transfer income from one part of
the population to another and which, added to the purchases of
goods and services, raise total government spending to 31.5 per cent
of GNP.
Some people believe that more things should be done by
Government and proportionately less through the private sector.
That is one of the fundamental issues I would like to examine.
As an economist, I approach this question from the point
of view of efficiency.

Which sector is likely to do a better job?

Many noneconomists approach the matter from a moral angle.




They

9
often are put off by the fact that private production involves
profit, and some people seem to regard profit as ethically
unappealing, to put it mildly.

Hence, they prefer economic action

through the public sector.
I do not share the moral doubts about profits, provided
they were made legally and taxes were paid.
is what I consider relevant.

The efficiency test

Profitability, of course, is a test

of efficiency. When a business is profitable, there is a strong
presumption that it is efficiently managed, even though there could
be other reasons.
feature.

The profits test, moreover, has a self-implementing

A business that flunks it and keeps losing money simply

cannot stay in business.
Government is organized just the other way.

If you run

a tight ship in your department, if you keep down expenditures and
have some money left over from your budget, you may be told at the
next budget hearing that you had more money than you needed, and your
funds may be cut.

If you overspend, this may appear to demonstrate

the urgent need for the services your office is providing, and your
budget may be raised.

Since the government administrator cannot

make a profit, he may try to maximize something else -- his staff,
his power, his program.

I am not convinced that these incentives

are conducive to maximizing the public welfare.




10
The same can be said of the method by which the private
and the public sector respectively make their choices and decisions.
The private sector allows each person to equalize costs and benefits
at the margin by buying as much as he/she can afford of everything.
There are no confrontations of interests, no need for political
decisions, although the market system of course has its imperfections.
The political process, on the other hand, leaves the individual little
choice.

The minority must accept what the majority decides.

participants get exactly what they want.

Few

Continuous confrontation

by public voting does not make for social harmony.
A good case, therefore, seems to me to exist for allowing
as many of the economic choices that society must make to occur
through the anonymous market rather than the adversary proceedings
of the political process.

In a modern society, to be sure, many

services by their nature call for intervention of the public sector.
Without a law requiring everybody to get a minimum of education,
some people might never go to school.

Without a law requiring people

to pay for social security, part of the aged might end up destitute.
Many modern social needs, moreover, call for insurance, for instance
against illness and death of the family breadwinner.

But it is

important to note that while provision for such needs may require
some kind of government compulsion, and while many of the needs,
such as education and insurance, are of a collective character, the
services themselves need not necessarily be provided through the




:

11

public sector.

The private sector might do it more efficiently,

even though it may require public guidance.
as Milton

F~iedman,

Iw:>uld not go so far

who seems to have concluded that a government

that cannot deliver the mail has little prospect of delivering
anything else efficiently.

But I would urge that, before we plunge

for a broadening of public sector activities, we obtain a competing
bid from the private sector to see which can do the job more
efficiently.
Of late, some of the demands made on the public sector have
run into difficulties because the technology to meet them does not
seem to exist.

This has been the case, for instance, with programs

oriented to help disadvantaged children to read, and to train hardcore unemployed.

It turns out that while the money was appropriated

and the teaching and training programs were carried through, the
results were not what had been expected.
radically different from past patterns.

This is a new experience,
We have always been sure

that if the government wants to do something, such as building a
road, and the money is available, the road will be built and will
carry traffic.

But neither the government, nor possibly anybody in

the private sector, knows how to make good readers out of disadvantaged children, or how to turn all hard-core unemployed into
steady and efficient workers.
be developed

befor~

public funds appropriated for these purposes

can be usefully spent.




New teaching techniques may have to

12

All this suggests to me that the case for not letting
the public sector expand without restraint is strong.

In addition,

however, we must ask ourselves how much growth we want for both
the private and the public sector together.
no one would have raised that question.

Half a dozen years ago,

Continued growth, and its

desirability, would have been taken for granted.
become controversial.

Today growth has

The decision whether and how much the economy

should grow has become one of the fundamental issues of our time.
How Much Growth
The attack on growth has come from two directions.

There

are those who claim that continued growth threatens to exhaust our
resources.

Reserves of minerals, metals, clean air, clean water,

and even of land are being depleted, not enough food can be produced.
Catastrophe is said to threaten unless this process is brought to a
halt.

The second line of attack has argued ·that, whether continued

growth is possible or not, it is unworthy of human beings to concern
themselves exclusively with the accumulation of more and more
material things instead of devoting attention to the quality of life.
Young people have responded by adopting simple life styles, and by
disinteresting themselves in the functions of production and moneymaking.
first.




I find the second of these views more appealing than the
Nevertheless, I suspect that both are misguided.

.

-

13
The shortages of food, of many raw materials, and especially
of oil that we have just experienced at first sight seem to confirm
the fear that we are beginning to run out of resources.

In my

view, however, this interpretation of recent experience is a misconception.

If the markets are allowed to do their job, they will

meet the situation by producing more of the needed goods, by developing
substitutes, and by cutting down the demand.

.Higher prices for many

commodities may, of course, prove unavoidable.
process.

That is part of the

We will have shortages if we interfere with the pricing

system, by imposing ceilings, or by interfering with supplies.

The

rise in oil prices constitutes, of course, an interference with
supply on the part of the oil-exporting countries, undertaken for
the purpose of raising the price.

Other supply difficulties have

occurred because, usually with a good motive but not always with
good sense, we have sought to protect the environment without
properly calculating the time it would take for productive processes
to adjust.

We shall pay a price for all this, in a temporary slow-

down of growth and in a lot of turmoil throughout our markets.

But

I do not believe that anything has happened to reduce permanently
the prospect for economic growth, so far as the economist's eye can
see.




'.

, J

'

.

~

14
The view that our society is too materialistic, and that
man was made for better things than what can be sold by advertising,
I share.

I have little doubt that there are many people like myself

who would be quite willing to stabilize their standard of living
instead of working desperately to double it in each generation.
Unfortunately, the willingness to stabilize living standards is not
widely shared, with the exception of what I fear to have been a
rather passing phase in the attitudes of young upper middle class
people.

And the great majority who want to improve their lot are

perfectly right so long as incomes throughout the world are very
unequal, and so long as the great majority is exposed to the
demonstration effect of the living standards of the minority that
are far above their own.

This is true within each nation, whether

it be the United States or India.

Within each country the lower

income groups feel that they have a long distance to go before they
have enough.

The same is true also between countries, as the

developing countries observe the wealth of the developed and want
to reach the same levels.
I must confess that I can see no solution to this problem,
although time undoubtedly will supply one .
not the answer.

Massive redistribution is

The upper income brackets in any country, even

though they may be willing to forego the prospects of getting still
more, certainly are not disposed to accept substantially less than




15
they have.

You need only consider the enormous reduction in the

income levels of millions of Americans that would be required in
order to bring all incomes to the neighborhood of the national average.
The same is true when you consider the amounts that the United States
would have to distribute to the developing countries if per capita
income all over the world were to be equalized.

Nothing like that

is conceivable, nor in all probability would it be desirable.

As

Kenneth Boulding said in one of the earlier lectures in this series,
there can be too much of everything, even of equality.
Economic growth, therefore, will probably continue in the
foreseeable future.

Short-term limitations can be overcome.

Most

people as yet are not minded to be content with what they have.

If

that prediction is correct, it will be incumbent upon us to make sure
that the demand for "more" can be satisfied smoothly and without damaging
repercussions for the economy and for the environment.
we must meet certain prerequisites.
the natural resource problem.

To do this,

We must deal intelligently with

The price system, as I said before,

will do the job in most cases if it is not interfered with too
seriously.
They

Some of the resulting price movements may create burdens.

may also create large profits.

If we make it our principal

objective to avoid all burdens, and to prevent anybody from profiting
from the situation, we shall be blocking the machinery that alone can
provide what is needed.

The impulses that might drive us to such

actions are understandable and humane.
productive.




They are nonetheless counter-

16
In addition to the need to let the price system generate
resources, or economize their use, or provide substitutes, we shall
need capital equipment to generate larger output.

If this is to be

done in ways that economize natural resources and protect the
environment, the need for equipment will be even larger.
experience shows that we are substantially underequipped.

Our present
Many

industries have been suffering from capacity shortages, which have
been one of the reasons for rising prices.
Past investment in capacity has been inadequate.

For

instance, there has been no increase at all in the amounts invested
annually in the manufacturing industries, after making allowance
for higher equipment prices and for types of investment that serves
to protect the environment r ather than to increase output.

Owing to

the high rate of inflation, the depreciation allowances charged by
business for the purpose of replacing worn out equipment have become
inadequate.

We are now significantly underdepreciating our plant

and equipment.

Our financial resources for expanding the capital

stock are becoming further inadequate because the profits that
business believes itself to be retaining have been seriously overstated by the distortions of inflation.
If we want a high rate of investment, we need policies that
encourage saving on the part of households and business.
policies also that encourage investment of these savings.




We need
The United

17
States, at the household level, has never been a high saving economy.
Household savings have fluctuated, most of the time, in the range of
5-8 per cent of disposable income.

This contrasts with savings rates

of 12 per cent in Germany and 20 per cent in Japan.

Gross invest-

ment in the U.S., including corporations and government, has been
of the order of 17 per cent of GNP, compared with something like
25 per cent in Germany and as much as 40 per cent in Japan.

The

need to provide substitute sources of energy and to protect the
environment will call for larger investment.
But in addition to increased material resources, we need
the right kind of social attitudes.

We need an attitude that

regards production to meet human needs as a worthwhile activity
rather than as outmoded drudgery.

To contribute to the vast

processes of production is no unworthy endeavor.

No one who

decides to devote his life to the tasks of business need be ashamed
of that decision or to think less well of himself than if he/she
were planning to become a teacher, government administrator, or
scientist.

Everybody should feel free to do what he wants to do,

but in the end we should remember that we must all help to produce
GNP.




18

Inflation
I have argued that a return to fundamental values is
necessary in the areas of the price system, the size of the public
sector, and the level of productive investment.

In all of these

areas, we have experienced some softening of attitudes, and we are
today suffering the consequences.

Nothing so clearly shows the cost

of temporizing and compromising, of putting the short-run ahead of
the long, of r eaching for expedients rather than solutions, as does
the inflation from which we are suffering.

Prices are now rising

at rates which in the past were observed mainly in some Latin
American countries.

The incomes of the unorganized and of the

retired are eroded , savings accumulated over a lifetime lose their
value, and people no longer know how theycan protect their future.
We have reached these high rates of inflation because, in
successive business cycles, we have never had the will to put an
end to rising prices.

Thus, predictably, each time round things

have gotten worse.
We have a chance today to bring down inflation, first of
all because its commodity component, reflecting shortages of food,
raw materials, and the high price of oil, is likely to abate as
demand and supply come into better balance.

So far, the inflation

of commodity prices has not yet been built into wage increases.
American labor has shown remarkable restraint, reflecting presumably




19
the recognition that the cost-of-living increases due to shortages
cannot be made up, but can only be aggravated by an attempt to let
wages catch up.

But beyond a better demand-supply balance, we need

restraint in our fiscal and monetary policies.

High interest rates,

which so many feel so severely today, will come down for good only
if inflation lets up.

Measures that would continue or aggravate

the inflation, such as a tax cut, would also give us greater problems
with interest rates.
The International Outlook
The United States, of course, is not the only country
suffering from inflation.

The problem is worldwide.

But inflation

proceeds at very different rates in different countries.
to be expected, once the process gets going.

That is

The only rate of price

change at which one might expect most of the major countries to move
in step is a rate of zero.
Differential rates of price increase have contributed
materially to the breakdown of the international monetary order and
have prevented the restoration of an organized system.

With prices

rising at different rates everywhere, the competitiveness of producers
in international trade becomes uncertain.
develop in trade balances.
capital.

These induce speculative movements of

Under such conditions, a system of fixed exchange rates

cannot survive.




Large deficits and surpluses

20
Some economists regard the present condition of floating
rates as an ideal solution that ought to be made permanent.

I regard

it as simply another expedient that the world is employing because
the strength is lacking for a more fundamental solution.

Most

countries do indeed want to return to a system in which exchange
rates are stable, although they may have to be adjusted from time
to time.

But the domestic problems created by inflation, along with

other causes, prevent countries from making commitments about exchange
rates.

Thus you find a major currency like the Deutschemark fluctuating

against the dollar by something like 20 per cent in the course of one
year, moving unpredictably in both directions.
Because the world has experienced a great boom, the uncertainties created by unstable exchange rates have had no adverse
effects upon trade.

No major country has found it necessary to

protect its producers against foreign competition made more severe
by depreciation of foreign currencies.

No major country has felt it

necessary to depreciate its own currency merely in order to give
its producers a competitive edge.

For the time being, in fact,

countries have shown an interest in keeping _their exchange rates
high because that means cheaper imports and less inflation.

But

the time could come when at least some countries might see their
interest lying in a different direction. Then international trade
might begin to suffer from the prevailing currency instability.
Trade controls would threaten.




21
One of the consequences of universal currency instability
is a growing preoccupation of countries with their own domestic
'

'

affairs.

The world is

becom~ng

more inward looking.

International

economic cooperation, which was one of the success stories of the ·
post World War II period, is becoming more difficult.

Efforts to'

reconstruct the world's monetary system have made it clear that no
country is in a mood to take forward looking action .if this should
involve serious risks in the imtnediate future.

In the field of

international trad,e relations, and of aid to .d eveloping countrj.es, _
we see a similar weakening of the will to take farsighted action.
International turbulence has gone hand in hand with a .
decline in the international role of the United States.

In all

probability, the turbulence, and the inability to rise above it,
are in good part a
after World War

co~sequence

of our declining role.

Not long

ii, during the early 1950's, the American GNP

amounted to more than half of the GNP of tpe free world.

The · United

States carried an economic weight in the world that enabled it to
I

exert unquestioned leadership.
create a

syst~m

of stable

We employed that leadership to

e ~change

rates, of increasingly freer

trade, and increasingly freer international investment.
world benefited from this system.




All the

22
Today the U.S. is no longer the giant among nations, as a
book written by Peter Kenen then proclaimed.

The Common Market is

in the process of coalescing, although with many setbacks.

Europe

has not become a political reality, but economically it carries a
weight in the world comparable to that of the United States.
meanwhile has been taking giant strides.

Japan

American per capita income,

once far ahead of every other country, is about to be caught up
with by several European countries.

All this explains why it has

been impossible for the United States to maintain in the world that
degree of consensus and common purpose that would be necessary to
restore the international economic order.
recover that capability.

The U.S. is unlikely to

Hereafter, it will have to be cooperation

rather than leadership if a common purpose is to prevail.
How Much Change?
I have tried to show how, in various fields of economic
policy, and in different parts of the world, the relentless pursuit
of expediency threatens to undermine the enduring fabric of the
economic system.

I have said that we must strive to conserve that

fabric even at some short-run cost.

You will understand, of course,

that for elected politicians it is not easy to follow this kind of
advice.

Their horizon is necessarily short

next election.




often not ·beyond the

Economic measures that do not pay off by then are

23
not very helpful to the politician.

As Secretary of the Treasury

George P. Shultz has said, the economist's lag may be the politician's
catastrophe.
Nor can one blame the politicians for this attitude.

After

all, they do in the main what their constituents tell them to do.
If the constituents had told them to preserve the price system,
restrain the public sector, encourage saving and investment, stop
inflation, and bring order back to the international economy, they
would probably have done so.

The means are at hand.

That the means

are not being used is in the first instance the fault of the voter,
not of the politician or government official.
But in a deeper sense I suspect that the fault is not
even that of the voter.

The average voter, after all, does not

have an easy time tracing long-term consequences to their short-run
causes.

Economists have struggled with these problems for centuries.

Economics, to be sure, is a fallible science.
can be upset by unfavorable circumstances.
can be challenged by value judgments.

Many of its propositions

Many reconmendations

Nevertheless, on the major

cause-and-effect sequences there is no disagreement.

Few economists

will tell you that price fixing will increase supplies.

Not many

believe that printing more money will bring down prices.

Hardly

anyone thinks that economic nationalism will increase tha universal
welfare.




Thus, if economists nevertheless advise the

pu~lic

and

24

the politicians to engage in practices of this sort, it is usually
because they, too, are willing to sacrifice the long run to the short.
In technical jargon, many economists, like most politicians, have a
high time preference.
It should be one of the functions of economists precisely
to bring better balance into this state of affairs.

If the public

and the politicians are inclined to stress short-run expediency,
economists ought to throw their weight on the side of long-run
principle.

They should do this precisely because it is difficult

for public and politicians to evaluate the long-run consequences
of their short-run expedients.

That is what I have been trying to

do here tonight.
I would not want to leave with you the impression, however,
that I think the future bleak because I find some things to criticize
in the present.

I am confident about the future of our economic order,

partly because I believe that in the long run the good sense of
people asserts itself and sets about to right matters, once a
problem has been recognized as serious.

I feel confident about

our economic order also because that order in the past has proved
remarkably resilient and durable.
Our economic order has changed over time, to be sure, but
it has not changed very much.

Where it had suffered a major ·break-

down, as during the depression of the 1930's, it has come back and




I

25
continued to perform pretty much as it did in the past.

Evidently

there are strong recuperative powers and stabilizing mechanisms
built into the system.

How else would one explain that the rate

of growth of the economy has hovered very stably in the range of 2-3
per cent per capita for many decades, leaving aside the effects of
economic fluctuations?

How else to explain the inglorious fact

of the extraordinary stability of our income distribution, in the
face of constant efforts to even it up?

How else can one account

for facts such as that over the last 50 or even 100 years the
structure of our banking system has not changed very perceptibly,
or that the relations between business and labor are still basically
governed by a law originally passed in 1947?
Some people see change wherever they look, and change
certainly is more interesting to write and talk about than is
stability.

I tend instead to see fashions, not to say fads, which

quickly take hold of the public
quickly to their successor.
of the last 25 years.

imagination and yield just as

That certainly has been . the history

Looking ahead from 1948, few people probably

would have believed that the U.S. woulrl change as little as it has.
There are another 25 years or so to the end of the century.
We cannot be sure that developments will not speed up over this time.
Henry Adams probably was not the first to express the view that
history tends to accelerate.




Technology certainly has not disavowed

26

him.

During the last decade, moreover, our rate of social change

does seem to have accelerated.

Beginning with civil rights and the

war on poverty, we have gone through a number of social movements
that have followed quickly one after the other.

But it is precisely

this rapid rotation of what might have been major national initiatives
that leads me to the conclusion that while intellectual fashions
change, the underlying system is stable.

I do not know whether, if

by the year 2000 you find the old system still pretty much in effect,
you ought to be pleased or not.




But you ought not be surprised.