View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release at 8 p.m. EDT
Friday, October 11, 1968




Monetary Policy and the Economy: 1967 and 1968

Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the

State University of New York at Binghamton
Binghamton, New York
October 11, 1968




Monetary Policy and the Economy: 1967-1968
Monetary policy and the economy sounds like a straight­
forward topic— and I wish it were— but it isn't.

What we mean by

the economy is fairly clear; it's the level of employment, the
standard of living, the rate of economic growth, the cost of living.
But what we mean by monetary policy is subject to considerable
dispute.
To one school of thought, monetary policy is measured by
the money supply— narrowly construed to include currency and demand
deposits held by private sectors of the economy, or perhaps more
broadly construed to include time and savings deposits at banks as
well.

When the money supply goes up more rapidly than it had been,

monetary policy is said to ease; and when it goes up less rapidly,
or declines, monetary policy is said to tighten.
To another school of thought, monetary policy is measured
by the cost and availability of credit.

To this school, policy is

tightening as interest rates rise, and is easing as interest rates
fall.
You can readily see that conflicts of interpretation can
and will develop.

There are times when both the money supply and

interest rates may be rising.

Is money then easy or tight?

Or

there may be times when both the money supply and interest rates
are falling.

Under those circumstances, the money supply school

will tell us money is becoming tighter, and the credit school will
tell us monetary policy is becoming easier.

These schools of

I am indebted to Stephen H. Axilrod, Adviser in the Board's Division
of Research and Statistics, for assistance in preparing these remarks

-2thought are not confined to academic circles— they now have
adherents in congressional and commercial banking circles.
receives regular attention in the daily financial press.
both are represented in the Federal Reserve System.

Each
Obviously

How do we

decide which is right?
Part of the problem is in the way the question is asked.
It does not really matter whether we can find an indicator, or set
of indicators, which will provide an unequivocal answer under all
circumstances to the question of whether monetary policy is becoming
easier or tighter.

What matters is whether financial conditions are

tight enough, or easy enough, to achieve a satisfactory level of
economic activity and growth.

The ultimate test of monetary policy

is not to be found in what happens to the money supply or to interest
rates, but in what happens to the economy— to prices, employment,
growth, and the balance of payments.

And the appropriate question

to ask of the monetary authority, or for the monetary authority to
ask itself, is what needs to be done in financial markets to attain
satisfactory and sustainable economic conditions.
The problem is elusive when looked at this way, not only
because of the variety of financial markets and assets and their
relation to economic activity, but also because many of the effects
of monetary policy are not transmitted instantaneously.

An economy

whose current performance is conforming to our goals is, in fact,
responding not only to current monetary actions but also to earlier
monetary maneuvers.




In a changing environment, with a variety of

-3fiscal and monetary mixes to point to in the recent past, there
is plenty of elbow room for diverse theories and judgments
associating or disassociating specific past actions with the
economy's current performance.

And, as is often the case where

variable leads and lags are involved and linkages are obscured,
the problem of identifying which is cause and which is effect also
becomes a source of disagreement.

We may be able to agree that

changes in interest rates, money holdings and credit flows, can
be affected by changes in the public's preferences for particular
financial assets.

And we may agree these monetary variables can

also be affected by the monetary authority's intervention whether
such intervention takes the form of altering the rate at which it
supplies reserves to the banking system or the conditions under
which the banking system can utilize these resources.

But in any

particular episode there can be substantial disagreement as to
the weight appropriately assigned to supply or to demand factors.
Sometimes these disagreements emerge as the issue of how
does the monetary authority know what it is doing, in contrast to
what is being done to it by market and economic forces.

This is

a real problem, which I would like to clarify by trying to flesh
it out through example and experience.
Relation Between Financial Markets and the Economy
When the monetary authority asks «hat has to be accomplished
in financial markets to keep the economy moving satisfactorily, it







-4must start with a knowledge of existing financial conditions and
how these affect, or are linked to, the spending of businesses
and consumers.

It must also start with a knowledge of the Federal

Government's spending and tax policy— that is, of fiscal policy.
Of course no knowledge is perfect, and the central bank, as well
as every other decision-making body, makes its judgments sur­
rounded by various uncertainties.

In the case of the central bank,

there are uncertainties as to how much private sectors will be
spending in the future; there are uncertainties about the nature
of the linkage between changes in certain financial conditions,
like mortgage interest rates, and related spending; and there are
uncertainties about how fiscal policy will evolve out of the
sometimes conflicting pulls of the Congress and the Administration.
Basic to monetary policy formulation, then, is a forecast
of economic activity, prices, and the balance of payments over a
period ahead, given existing financial conditions and prospects
for fiscal policy.

The likely course of the economy is not

dependent on existing financial conditions alone, but it is also
influenced in an important degree by past financial conditions.
And, finally, I might add that economic activity to some degree
has a momentum all its own, given some reasonable range of
financial conditions, with business investment, for example,
dependent on past sales to consumers or on defense orders, and
with price behavior dependent on wage developments and vice versa.




-5A good illustration of the linkage between credit markets
and spending, and one that has received considerable publicity in
recent years, is the relationship between building activity and
conditions in the mortgage market.

The mortgage market is subject

to a variety of influences from the supply side, the chief of which
are inflows to savings and loan associations and mutual savings
banks and yields available on other long-term investment instruments,
such as corporate stocks and bonds, which affect the willingness of
insurance companies, for instance, to make mortgages.

And since

home building requires a fairly long planning stage and start-up
time, it is mortgage market conditions over a past period of several
months which have an affect on tomorrow's building activity, although
expectations of this activity are generated by the mortgage commit­
ments made to builders, which show a much earlier response to inflows.
Another crucial area of the financial markets is the cost
and availability of credit to businesses and consumers from banks.
This depends on the extent to which banks can effectively compete
with other financial institutions for savings of individuals or
can offer time instruments at an interest rate that will attract
funds— from corporations or State and local governments— which
might otherwise flow into market securities, such as Treasury bills.
The ability of banks to make loans also depends on the public's
willingness to hold a portion of its assets in the form of demand
deposits; and this willingness in turn depends on the level of




-6interest rates, expectations about future interest rates, and
current transactions needs steaming from economic and financial
•activity.
Finally, and without attempting an all inclusive listing
of relevant credit areas, I should mention the cost of long-term
borrowing.

The current, and also expected, levels of long-term

interest rates affects the timing of capital market borrowing by
business corporations and State and local governments.

And it

also appears to have some influence on spending decisions, or on
the timing of long-term investment projects, particularly those
in which borrowing costs are a significant share of total costs,
such as for transportation and various kinds of public utilities.
How Does Money Fit In?
The main point I want to bring out by cataloguing relations
between credit and spending is to indicate that the great bulk of the
links between finance and spending do not involve money supply, as
such, but do involve the availability, terms, and cost of credit—
in short, how much you can borrow, when, and under what terms.
Thus, if the central bank wants to change existing financial
conditions because the economic outlook is weak and spending needs
to be encouraged, it will provide more reserves to the banking
system; and in so doing will act to push down interest rates generally,
increase the availability of lendable funds to banks, and make it
easier for other savings institutions to attract funds and channel
them into, for instance, the mortgage market.




-7You may then ask how does the money supply fit Into this
picture?

It fits in a number of ways, but let me highlight one.

Often an increase in money supply is the result of growth in income.
As income grows, people receive more cash and need more cash for
the enlarged volume of transactions, always recognizing that over
the longer run we are using technology in more and more ways to
economize on cash.

But if the money supply is growing much more

rapidly than income, this may indicate that the public is increasing
its liquidity, and are putting themselves in a position to spend more
in the future.

However, it is obvious— once so much is said--that

the money supply alone is not indicative of liquidity.

Funds held

in time.and savings deposits, saving shares, and short-term market
instruments are almost as liquid as cash, and can be readily spent
with no or little sacrifice in capital value.
Thus the money supply would appear to be one— but only one-element in the liquidity position of the public.

And if liquidity

is built up, it is possible for consumers, businesses, and State
and local governments to maintain spending in some degree when
credit is tight by drawing down their liquid assets.

Indeed, a

recent survey we made of the behavior of State and local government
units in periods of tight money indicates that large governmental
units in relatively liquid positions were not as pressed as others
to cancel contracts at the same time as they cancelled bond offerings,
because they could tide themselves over by drawing on liquidity.




-

8-

But liquidity, once used, ordinarily is later rebuilt,
so that it does not for long provide what some have called an
•escape from monetary policy.
as an escape.

Yet it should not even be considered

Rather, an erosion of liquidity— measured to include

all relevant assets and not just the money supply— is an aspect of
the process by which a monetary policy of.tightness works.

And a

rebuilding of liquidity is an aspect of monetary easing.
Sometimes, this rebuilding may take the form of demand
deposits and money supply; more often than not, however, it may take
the form of time deposits.
the most prominent form.

At other times, repayment of debt may be
And usually all this is going on simulta­

neously.
The point is:

money is only one form of asset, one form

in a spectrum of liquidity alternatives, and the amount outstanding
will vary over the short-run and long-run in response to shifting
public preferences for one asset as compared with another.

Honey,

therefore, is not a unique indicator of monetary policy, nor a
reliable guide in itself for policy.

It is one among the many

monetary variables to be evaluated in the context of over-all
financial and credit conditions appropriate to a satisfactory
economy.
Let me illustrate all this with the experience of 1967
and the first half of 1968.




-9Rebuilding Liquidity and Easing of Credit Markets: First Half of 1967
Events tumble one after another with such frequency in
today's world that calendar time itself appears to be accelerating.
So when I talk to you about the first half of 1967, which I propose
to do for a few minutes, you may feel that environment remote in
your recollection.

But what I am doing is reaching back to a period

when the economy was characterized by a fairly determined effort by
all sectors to rebuild liquidity.

An important aspect of the demand

for liquidity was a 6-1/2 per cent annual rate of expansion in the
money supply— a growth rate above what the economy had been accustomed
to, or demanded, in the preceding years of the 1960's.
This demand was, it would appear, a direct consequence of
the tightening of monetary policy that began at the end of 1965 and
culminated in the summer and early fall of 1966.

At its culmination,

market interest rates were high relative to maximum rates of interest
payable by banks and other savings institutions on time and savings
accounts or shares; and as a result these institutions were able to
attract only a rapidly diminishing share of the public's saving.
For example, in the second half of 1966, banks supplied no more than
about 15 per cent of the country's credit, whereas under less
stringent conditions in the 1960's they had supplied anywhere from
25 to 40 per cent.

And the share of credit supplied by nonbank

depository institutions also dropped below normal in the period.
The mortgage market was particularly hard pressed by the
reduced availability of funds from savings institutions.

And




-

construction began to drop

10-

off sharply, even though these

institutions dipped deeply into their liquidity positions to
keep mortgage commitments from falling even further.

And borrowers

who relied on banks found funds increasingly less accessible and
more costly.

This includes State and local governments, as well

as business and consumers, for banks are important buyers of State
and local government bond issues.

Under the circumstances, both

borrowers and banks reduced their liquidity to accommodate at
least part of the financing demands.
In the process, during the last half of 1966 the money
supply did not grow.

If the monetary authorities had thrown even

more reserves into the banking system at that time, so that credit
had been more available and interest rates lower, it is likely
that the money supply would have grown since the public would
have felt less need to squeeze its liquidity.

But then the

inflationary demands associated with the military build-up in
Vietnam would not have been dampened.

The annual rate of price

increase (measured by the GNP deflator) had been between 3 and
a little over 3-1/2 per cent since during 1966, and by the first
half of 1967 this dropped to about a 2-1/2 per cent annual rate.
The slowing of price rises in the first half of 1967
was accompanied by a considerable slowing in the rate of expansion
in over-all economic activity.

But to keep this slowing in growth

from tipping into recession it was necessary to accommodate the

-

11-

sharp rise in liquidity demands during the period.

Thus the

rapid money supply growth I mentioned earlier.
In addition to money growth, and probably more significant
for conditions in the first half of 1967, there was an 18 per cent
annual rate of growth in time and savings deposits of banks and an
approximately 10 per cent growth in shares and accounts at mutual
savings banks and savings and loan associations— all sharply higher
than in 1966.

As a result banks were able to advance about half of

the credit raised in the economy, and other savings institutions
about one-quarter.

The important fact is that the growth in savings

at institutions enabled them to rebuild liquidity, and enabled the
nonbank savings institution to make mortgage money much more readily
available— which led to increased construction expenditures and
helped forestall recessionary tendencies in the economy.
At the same time— with lower short-term market interest
rates— consumers and businesses were also able and willing to hold
more deposit-type claims.

Businesses took the opportunity to

restructure their balance sheet position.

They not only added to

liquid asset holdings by investing in negotiable time certificates
of deposit once banks were put in a position again to offer them
competitively, but businesses also issued long-term bonds in sharply
increasing volume.

This tendency continued throughout last year,

as corporations, partly in reaction to the tight money squeeze of
1966, made efforts to restructure their debt— that is, obtained
more long-term funds so as in some degree to reduce their dependence
on short-term borrowing in case money once again became tight.







-

12-

Thus, w e ‘
had In the first half of 1967, rapid growth
in money, even more rapid growth in interest-bearing claims on
banks and other financial institutions, declines in short-term
interest rates, and, for a time, reductions in long-term interest
rates— all manifestations of monetary ease.

But long-term yields

began to rise, and rose sharply, after the early months of the
year, and by early summer yields on corporate and U.S. Government
securities were above their peaks at the height of the 1966 period
of tightness.

Monetary variables began to give conflicting signals.

Financial conditions reflected the interaction of
institutional demands for liquidity, borrower expectations about
future interest rates, and credit demands being generated by the
then comparatively sluggish economic growth.

The suitability of

the financial conditions to the future economy could not be read
from the money supply itself— which reflected liquidity demands;
or from movements in long-term interest rates--which had a strong
expectational component; or from the declines in short-term
market interest rates alone— since they in part reflected the
Treasury's ability to repay debt in the spring.

Whether financial

conditions were suitable had to be read from the future course of
economic activity.

And as the first half of 1967 progressed, it

became apparent that the real rate of economic growth would be
picking up soon and that there were evident dangers of a
resurgence of inflationary pressures.

-13Tightening of Credit Markets: Second Half of 1967 and First Half of 1968
Thus, it became more and more apparent in the second half
of 1967 that public policy action was required to keep the economy
from overheating.

With no one sector of the private economy appearing

to be the unique source of potential excess demand pressures, and
with Government spending continuing to rise fairly sharply, most
economic analysts agreed on the need for additional fiscal restraintthrough tax increases that would moderate private spending across the
board and through reduced Government spending.

But while fiscal

restraint was developing, it was apparent that financial markets
needed to become less conducive to greater spending.
The Federal Reserve contributed to that end basically by
holding back on the funds it made available to the economy, and
making them most costly, relative to the total demands for credit
that were developing in the economy.

The evidence of such a policy

is to be seen from the following financial relationships: (1 ) net
funds raised in all credit markets during the one year period
ending with the second quarter of 1968, including large U.S.
Government credit demands stemming from the sizable budgetary
deficits, amounted to over $95 billion, as compared with only
about $60 billion (seasonally adjusted annual rate) in the first
half of 1967; (2) at the same time, growth in the total reserves
of the banking system slowed to about a 7 per cent rate from a
10-1/2 per cent annual rate in the first half of 1967, and these
reserves are the means by which the Federal Reserve can inject







-

14-

funds into or remove them from the economy; (3) the cost of
obtaining credit from the Federal Reserve rose from 4 per cent
'to 5-1/2 per cent; and (4) the maximum rate of interest that could
be offered on interest-bearing deposit accounts by banks and other
savings institutions limited their ability--as market interest
rates and credit demands rose— to attract•funds that could be
channeled to borrowers.
You can see that credit demands grew, but that the
availability of funds from the Federal Reserve slowed and their
cost became higher.

The interaction of such demand and supply

conditions led to a sharp rise of interest rates, but with the
extent of rise partly influenced by market fears during much of
the time that measures of fiscal restraint would not be finally
enacted.

Short-term market interest rates rose throughout the

period from mid-1967 through mid-1968, with the 3-month Treasury
bill rate rising about 2- 1/2 percentage points to a high of
almost 6 per cent, a level somewhat above the 1966 peak rate.
And long-term rates rose further to levels well above the
1966 peaks.
The rate of expansion in money supply during this period
did not, however, slow down significantly.

In the second half of

1967, money grew at about a 6 per cent annual rate, and in the
first half of 1968 at a 6- 1/2 per cent annual rate, not much
changed from the first half of 1967.

Since around mid-1968, the




-15money supply outstanding has shown little net change, partly
because the rate of economic expansion and associated transactions
demands have moderated, and also perhaps because liquidity priorities
have become less urgent.
The maintenance of money growth in the first half of 1968
when monetary policy was tightening seems attributable to a growing
transactions demand for cash, and to an unwillingness on the part
of businesses and consumers sharply to reduce their liquidity given
their experience of the recent past.

The transactions demand is

shown by the rise in the economy's real rate of growth to an almost
4 per cent annual rate in the second half of 1967 and to a very
rapid 6-1/2 per cent rate in the first half of 1968, and by the
10 per cent rise in the deposit turnover rate compared to little

change in the previous year.

In addition, there appeared to be some

expansion in demands for cash related to financial transactions,
with stock market volume expanding quite sharply in the spring of
1968.
While the bite of tighter monetary policy cannot be
measured directly by the money supply, it was clearly felt by
financial institutions.

Commercial banks became increasingly less

able to compete for time and savings deposits as market interest
rates rose.

By the first half of 1968 they could supply only

about one-fifth of the funds advanced in credit markets.

Other

savings institutions, too, found it increasingly difficult to
attract funds that they could lend.

And capital market investors

-16became less willing to place funds in new bond issues.

So, all

in all, it became more difficult and expensive for State and
local governments, consumers, builders, and other businesses to
borrow.
While it seems clear that monetary policy became tighter—
the money supply notwithstanding— whether policy, however, defined,
was tight enough is less easily answered.

Critics will point to

the acceleration of price increases to a 4 per cent annual rate,
and to a continued balance of payments deficit.

But price pressures

are in part both a reflection and a cause of wage pressures, and the
latter were quite strong during the past year.

And the timing of

fiscal policy in relation to monetary policy— the question of the
policy mix— will continue to be a matter of discussion, as will the
question of how pervasive an influence on the economy does monetary
policy have, or can reasonably be expected to have.
While this brief review of recent developments did not go
into such issues, I hope that some perspective has been provided on
the question of how best to measure, or guide, monetary policy.
Let me, at any rate, conclude by attempting to weave some of the
strands together.
Concluding Comment
(1)

Monetary policy cannot be gauged simply by whether

interest rates are higher or lower than at some other time, or
whether bank credit and money supply are rising faster or slower.
It has to be evaluated by whether existing and past financial




-17conditions are leading to a satisfactory economic performance.
And it will turn out that a satisfactory economic performanceone in which the economy is at a high level of economic activity
with reasonable stability in prices— will be consistent, at
different time periods, with varying rates of growth in money or
other liquid assets, with varying flows of credit through financial
institutions, and with varying levels of interest rates.

It will

depend on the asset preferences of the public, their liquidity needs,
the level and composition of credit demands, and the state of market
expectations.

This being so, no single financial measure

is an

adequate guide for, or indicator of, monetary policy.
(2) The measures of monetary policy will also depend on
institutional changes in the economy.

Changes in maximum rates of

interest payable by banks and savings institutions will obviously
affect the demand for money and the level of market interest rates
consistent with full employment.

The increased flexibility in

competing for savings, and improved liquidity position, of savings
institutions, were, for instance, factors that enabled market
interest rates to rise as much as they did during the monetary
restraint of the first half of 1968.
(3) While all financial variables reflect the interaction
of monetary policy and the public's credit demands and asset preferences,
certain variables at times are more crucial than others.

But these

are not necessarily those most directly controlled, or affected,




-18by monetary policy.

If, for instance, the central bank holds

back on total reserves so as to reduce growth in member bank
assets, and perhaps even in money supply, there will be extensive
ramifications in other markets as the public seeks to satisfy its
demands in ways other than through banks.

The key variable would

then be, not the one through which monetary policy acts (i.e., bank
reserves), but the one which has the most significant link to
spending.

In 1966, for example, it turned out to be the mortgage

market, given institutional factors at the time.
(4)
most critical.

Thus, it is the financial links to spending that are
And in that respect economists have left us little

choice but to evaluate the whole range of financial conditions,
since the number of links appears fairly large— and may only be
limited by the number of economists searching for links.

But the

search needs to go on, for it will not be until we fully understand
the relation between financial variables and spending that we can
with real assurance say monetary policy is easy enough or tight
enough.