View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on
Tuesday, Oct. 13, 1970
at 2 p.m. EDT




Federal Reserve Policy and the Liquidity Squeeze
Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Banking and Financial Research Committee Workshop
of
The American Bankers Association
Miami, Florida
October 13, 1970




Federal Reserve Policy and the Liquidity Squeeze
In the postwar years we have become conditioned to
expect that the sequel to periods of excessive economic activity
will be counter-acting policies of monetary restraint.

Such monetary

shifts may promptly induce precautionary cutbacks in commitments
and spending by some sectors of the economy, but the usual
sequence of events includes enforced reductions in the liquidity
positions of those sectors of the economy where an attempt is
made to continue "business as usual."

The period 1967-1970 is

illustrative; households cut back early on their spending and
commitments but financial institutions and businesses responded
to restraint only after their liquidity positions had been
significantly curtailed. In fact, the extent of the deterioration
in liquidity was much greater in these sectors than it had been
in comparable previous cyclical periods, partly because monetary
restraint was maintained for a longer period of time in order to
successfully combat inflationary pressures as well as expectations
of further inflation.
Not the least of the influences extending the period
of restraint was the credibility gap so prevalent for a time
in banking, business and investment circles.

Many believedthat

inflation could not be brought under control or that the Federal
Reserve would not persevere in its policies.

Another retarding

factor was the widespread attempt throughout the various sectors
of the economy to avoid the impact of public policies of restraint.




-2While these avoidance techniques took a variety of forms-some new and some old, as you know--they nevertheless quite
clearly represented judgments of both borrowers and lenders
as to how far and how long to run down liquidity positions
in order to finance an unabated level of activities and
commitments.
In the nonfinaneial corporate sector, liquidity—
conventionally measured by the ratio of cash and U. S. Govern­
ment security holdings to total current liabilities— has been
trending down throughout the postwar period, almost without
interruption.

This appears to reflect a deliberate policy on

the part of corporate treasurers to tap other sources of
liquidity or to seek greater profits from their cash positions,
even at the risk of greater exposure to liquidity risk.

In any

event, the erosion of conventional liquidity accelerated sharply
in 1969 and continued into at least the early part of 1970.
The limited availability and sharply higher cost of
credit in 1969-70, in conjunction with heavy capital spending
programs and enlarged working capital needs, virtually forced
corporate managements to further economize on liquid asset
holdings.

Doubt that a restrictive monetary posture would

persevere and euphoric attitudes about inflationary trends
seemed to generate a willingness to erode financial flexibility
much more than would have been viewed as prudent only a few
years ago.

Although there is really no way of knowing what




-3level of liquidity is critical for the corporate sector as
a whole, or for various industries and firms, the early 1970
liquidity position over-all did not, by historical standards,
leave much flexibility for an adverse change in economic
prospects.

The 1969-70 experience, mirroring the consequences

of a move toward more monetary stability, must be causing some
reappraisal of corporate liquidity requirements today.
Much earlier in the period of restraint, but in a
similar way, commercial banks with a much less plausible
credibility attitude considering their sophistication in
monetary matters had also constrained their flexibility by
very rapidly running off liquid asset holdings to meet deposit
drains, loan commitments, and other obligations.

By mid-1969,

the general level of liquidity in the banking system was below
that reached in 1966, the previous year of similar circumstances,
and it was still declining through the spring of this year.
Standard liquidity measures, however, do not reflect the degree
to which banks placed increased reliance on non-deposit sources
of funds and on foreign and domestic pools of relatively "hot"
money.

In the process, the rules of money position management

were changed, liquidity no longer depended on run-off flows or
on portfolios that could be sold outright but on what could be
contingently sold, transitorily borrowed or collaterally arranged.




-4Other financial sectors were not immune to the
liquidity squeeze.

Savings and loan associations and mutual

savings banks reduced liquid assets to meet outstanding mortgage
commitments when deposit inflows slowed, but mainly the savings
and loan associations borrowed heavily from the Federal Home
loan Bank System.

Life insurance companies experienced liquidity

pressures from a rapid expansion in policy loans, although their
relatively cautious commitment behavior earlier did not leave
them as exposed as was the case in 1966.
The liquidity position of the household sector— in
contrast to that of the corporate and financial sectors of the
economy— did not decline significantly during 1969 and has improved
appreciably this year.

In part, this performance is accounted for

by moderation in spending and the unusually high savings rate in
the economy during a period of strong gains in personal incomes.
The income side not only reflects maintenance of relatively high
levels of economic activity, but also large wage increases and
special income supplements including retroactive Social Security
benefits.

Households have acquired a large volume of liquid

assets, particularly claims at commercial banks and the nonbank
thrift institutions this year.

Moreover, growth in consumer

debt outstanding has been modest, as consumer willingness to
assume additional debt has eroded with the apparent increase
in uncertainty over the economic outlook.

Hence, the liquidity

squeeze evident in other sectors of the economy has not
occurred in the household sector.

-5-

With liquidity limited throughout the financial and
nonfinaneial business sectors, there was a danger that the slow­
down in economic activity that accompanied efforts to curb
inflation would be associated with relatively widespread liquidity
problems.

In light of the widespread and strongly held views of

many business managements as to the certainty of continued inflation,
liquidity problems for their concerns became more and more critical
as the economy cooled.

But it was essential that a widespread loss

of confidence due to general illiquidity be averted in the transi­
tion from a period of inflationary growth to one of non-inflationary
growth.
The Federal Reserve in 1970 acted in a variety of ways
to ensure that this could not happen.

As early as January, the

Federal Reserve Board, in coordination with the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation and the Federal Home Loan Bank Board,
moved to limit the pressures on depositary institutions by
raising the maximum rates payable on consumer-type claims at
commercial banks and on deposits at savings and loan associa­
tions and mutual savings banks.

By permitting these institutions

to better compete against the attractiveness of yields on market
securities, it was hoped that an improvement in their fund inflows







-6-

would strengthen liquidity positions and provide a framework for
an expansion in the commitment of funds to the mortgage market.
To a significant degree, this goal was achieved and the nonbank
savings institutions were insulated

from the liquidity squeeze

that emerged later.
As the outlook for corporate profits became more con­
sistent with an effective anti-inflationary policy, securities
markets came under unusual pressures in the spring.
began to rise and stock prices plunged.

Bond yields

While the disturbing

nature of domestic and international developments at the time
were no doubt deeply related to the crisis of confidence,
investors and lenders, nontheless, began to reflect more care­
fully upon the quality of various credits.
In this atmosphere, it was made clear that the Federal
Reserve's policy stance had been changed and that it was now
moving toward a resumption of moderate monetary growth.

The directive

to the Manager of the System Open Market Account was revised to be more
responsive to the change in attitudes and avert an all-out scramble
for funds.

Excessive pressures on financial markets were moderated

by the System's more liberal provision of reserves, without generating
sustained rapid growth in the monetary aggregates that would have
been inconsistent with longer run objectives.




-7The April-May period of unsettling events was followed
by the filing of bankruptcy proceedings by the Penn Central in
late June.

This event showed just how fragile confidence was

and called for immediate, convincing action by the central bank.
Interest rate ceilings on large denomination negotiable certi­
ficates of deposit

with maturities of less than 90 days were

suspended so as to enable banks to attract funds in volume, and
thereby accommodate the expected surge in loan demands by those
industrial and finance company borrowers who could not obtain
funds in the commercial paper market.

As it turned out, bank

credit demands by such borrowers amounted to more than $2-1/2
billion.
Not all of these funds were provided by sale of CD's.
Some came, temporarily, from a liberalization of Federal Reserve
discount policy that was designed to insure the availability of
funds to firms imperiled by temporary circumstances.

Borrowings

at the discount window rose 90 per cent as banks necessitously
turned to the lender of last resort or probed the extent of its
resolution.

System open market operations were geared to ensuring

that financial conditions remained stable and recognized that more
noney supply and bank credit growth might have to be permitted for
a time than would be desired over the longer run.

In addition, the

-8Federal Reserve prepared stand-by procedures to make credit
available to worthy borrowers facing unusual liquidity require­
ments that could not be met by obtaining funds from other
sources.

The last step proved to be superfluous.

The commercial

banking system, given the System assurances, dealt promptly and
expertly with emergency liquidity needs that had arisen.
It appears that we have successfully weathered the
liquidity squeeze and, barring any further disturbances to
financial and business confidence, can look forward to more
tranquil markets.

Some individual problems may still remain

to be worked out, but the risk of a cumulative general problem
of illiquidity seems behind us.

Indeed, short-term and long-term

interest rates have declined substantially on balance over the
past few months.

Major attention may now be devoted to the goal

of attaining stable economic growth without inflation.