View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on
Sunday, Oct. 26, 1969
at 12 Noon EST




Bank Lending Practices and Changes
in the Monetary Environment
Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Robert Morris Associates Conference
San Juan
October 27, 1969

Bank Lending Practices and Changes
in the Monetary Environment
In the past 15 years or so, the senior lending officers
of American banks have endured no less than four bouts with
monetary restraint.

Their reactions, as heard on Constitution

Avenue, have been indicative of extreme frustration and even agony.
This is understandable, because, while monetary restraint is not
their doing, almost without exception their institutions, their
industry, their leaders and spokesmen have, on each of these
occasions, supported Federal Reserve use of monetary restraint
to curb inflation and defend the stability of the dollar.
I assume that all of us accept the possibility of periodic
monetary restraint as a fact of life, but loan officers are asking
increasingly whether the banking industry can be successful as an
aggressive lender one year and indifferent or hostile to the credit
needs of the same customers in the next?

Others wonder if as loan

officers they must permit the productivity of their professional
careers to be retarded because of the changes in pace ensuing from
alternating periods of monetary ease and restraint.

The plight of

the industry and the loan officer is a real one, indeed, but your
customers stand to suffer still greater inconvenience and loss than
you do— if that is any consolation.

And if your inclination is to

blame it all on monetary policy perhaps you should reconsider that
judgment.
I am indebted to Joseph Burns, Economist in the Board's Division of
Research and Statistics, for assistance in preparing these remarks.




-2I have always thought a loan officer was paid to screen
and select loans--not to sell them--a view I am sure borrowers
i

generally have of lenders.

This view follows not merely from the

fact that institutions that invest other peoples' money must con­
stantly guard against lending exuberance when it can entail
undue risks.

In a prosperous and growing economy, it seems to me

that the conditions for access to credit, including its price, must
of necessity be used as selective deterrents simply to contain,
within supply constraints, the massive demands for credit that are
so pervasive in our economy.
Economic developments in the postwar years and especially
the 1960's have changed attitudes gradually but drastically with
regard to creditworthiness.

Fewer and fewer loan

officers give

much weight to the likelihood of a major economic recession.

The

past decade of expansion in markets, employment and earnings of
business and workers alike, has upgraded the performance and debt
service capacity of borrowers in all sectors of the economy.

While

we often view the larger and more pressing demands for credit as
the consequence of expanding capital requirements in our economy,
we could also view them as the creation of lending officers— for
it is the lending officers who have discovered that, given conventional
lending standards, the changes in economic environment through the
past decade have greatly extended the creditworthiness of consumers,
businesses and State and local governments.

It may be argued that

the latent demand for credit has been there all along but that it




-3-

is the steady and prolonged economic expansion of our times that
has made it an effective demand.
Since there has been no proportionally large flow of
funds to credit markets and institutions your job is becoming more
and more that of selecting the best credits and developing standards
or pricing policies to bring the flows of resources and the flood of
demands into approximate balance.
This is a point in time when I believe an inward look at
your own operations is more productive than venting frustration over
monetary policy.

Moreover, considering the commitment to price .

stability that all of us have, I believe we can and should develop
lending techniques that accommodate and even enhance the effective­
ness of monetary policy.

This responsibility rests most heavily on

those of us whose institutions deal in money or fixed money claims
rather than equity instruments— for here the essentiality to our
overall interest of a stable dollar is especially apparent and vital.
Let me now examine recent experience in matching up the
banking system's resources with the demands of its customers.
The Changing Economic Environment
The period from mid-1968 to date is illustrative of a
situation in which the flow of banking's resources shifted markedly
relative to the loan demands of its customers.

The supply of lendable

funds at banks was adequate to meet demands until late in 1968 because
of a corresponding rise in deposit resources.

In this period banks

extended more than 50 per cent of the total increase in net credit




-4extensions.

Total member bank deposits, for example— the bank

credit proxy— rose at an annual rate of more than 13 per cent
during the second half of 1968.

But in 1969, with loan demands

still strong, member bank deposits declined at an annual rate of
about 5.5 per cent over the first nine months of this year.
Banking's share of the increase in credit flows during the first
half of the year dropped to approximately 12 per cent and in the
third quarter it was significantly negative.'
Management of Liquidity Positions
The oldest and most conventional means by which banks
have reacted to a faltering supply of funds relative to demand is
through an adjustment in holdings of impersonal money market assets.
I refer to their impersonal character to imply a lack of customer
relationship or solicitousness which might serve as a deterrent to
the sale of such assets.

Of course, this is not entirely true even

for Treasury securities and Federal funds.

In any event, such assets

are frequently used as a buffer to insulate loan customers from un­
expected— and sometimes even expected— variations in flows of
loanable funds, or loan demands.

During periods of excess supplies

of funds, these balances usually are built up, and in periods of
excess demand they usually are drawn down.
During the latter half of 1968, commercial bank holdings
of securities rose by nearly $9 billion, on a seasonally adjusted
basis.




Moreover, the greater part of this increase represented

-5acquisitions of short-term securities.

Holdings of Treasury bills

at large banks more than doubled in this period and holdings of
short-term Treasury notes and bonds, as well as short-term municipal
obligations, rose sharply.

Very short-term loans such as those to

brokers and dealers and to other domestic banks also rose markedly,
though in part seasonally.

Nevertheless, the rise in most of these

items was larger than in comparable periods of recent years and the
nation's larger banks entered the period of monetary restraint with
a considerable quantity of liquid assets at their disposal, relative
to their liabilities.

The most immediate reaction on the part of banks to the
reduced availability of funds that set in towards year-end was the
liquidation of some of these holdings of liquid assets.

Holdings of

securities at all commercial banks, for example, fell by $8 billion
during .the first nine months of 1969, in spite of the fact that
banks underwrote several rather large Treasury financings during
this period, mostly after midyear.

Initially, this liquidation

consisted largely of U.S. Government securities.

But as time passed

and holdings of these securities began to reach minimum working
balances around midyear, banks also began to run off other securities
in volume.
At the large banks, holdings of Treasury bills were
reduced by nearly two-thirds during the first half of the year, but
have generally remained unchanged, on balance, at this low level
since that time.




On the other hand, holdings of short-term Treasury

-6notes and bonds and short-term municipal issues fell somewhat
more rapidly after midyear, after having declined only moderately
earlier in the year.

These banks also cut back on very short­

term loans such as those to brokers and dealers.

By midyear

liquidity positions of the larger banks had fallen below the
lowest point reached in the period of monetary restraint in late
1966, and remained at this low level in the ensuing months.
Management of Sources of Funds
The "in" thing now among intermediaries who must maneuver
to match resources and commitments is liability management.

Initially--

that is, in the early Sixties— in banks it took the form of inter­
mediation on a more diversified scale than had ever been tried by
the banking system.

The variegation in the transformation of short

debts— in the form of time and savings deposits— into long-term
loans and investments worked miracles for intermediaries and their
customers and no doubt made a major financial contribution to the
halcyon days of the early Sixties.

But in recent years intermediation

has turned into disintermediation as market interest rates rose so
sharply that the yields on long-term loans and investments with nonnegotiable interest terms were insufficient to cover the interest
cost on competitively priced short-term deposits

And to make

matters worse, the monetary authority used rate ceilings to limit the
banking system's access to time deposits even when it was, in a
market sense, prepared— and increasingly able— to pay a competitive
short price.




-7However, liability management is not, as we have been
learning, limited to deposit instruments.

It can be done with

other direct debts, such as Federal funds purchased or Euro-dollars
borrowed, or with contingent obligations arising out of agreements
to repurchase assets, or indirectly through sponsorship or guarantee
of the obligations of others.
In the sequence of events in 1968 and 1969, inter­
mediation, using large denomination CD's, added substantially to
resources of the larger banks in the second half of 1968.

But banks

could do little, given the rate ceilings in effect, to stem the CD
attrition that followed in 1969, and by the end of the third quarter
of this year the total of outstanding CD's at weekly reporting banks
was less than half that outstanding at the end of 1968.

And in spite

of heavy promotional campaigns by banks, consumer-type time and
savings deposits at large banks also began to decline in the spring.
Consequently, banks turned their efforts towards developing
new, or |»ore fully utilizing existing, nondeposit sources of funds.
For example, banks with foreign branches borrowed heavily in the
Euro-dollar market, pushing rates up sharply.
U.S

By the end of July,

head office liabilities to their foreign branches were in

excess of $14 billion, or more than double the amount outstanding
at the end of 1968.

Totals have changed little, on balance, since

that time, however, probably, in part, because of the increase in the
effective price for these funds that resulted from regulatory changes
introduced during the summer.




Moreover, banks in need of funds

-8increased their borrowing in the Federal funds market, and the
volume of these funds traded in New York, for example, rose from
a daily average of about $7 billion in the fourth quarter of
1968 to nearly $10 billion in the third quarter of 1969.

The

interest rate paid on Federal funds also rose fairly steadily from
around 6 per cent in the latter part of 1968 to more than 9 per cent
in recent months.
Banks without European branches or a Nassau shell— the
"poor man's London office"— borrowed Euro-dollar funds from brokers
and dealers or directly from foreign banks.

However, the volume of

funds borrowed in this manner has not been particularly large— about
$1.2 billion— and has shown no tendency to rise in recent months.
In addition, banks began to sell loans under repurchase agreements
in increasing amounts, until funds obtained from such sales were
made subject to reserve requirements and Regulation Q ceilings in
August.

By the end of September, outstanding funds obtained in this

manner had dropped back to only about $500 million.

Banks also gained

indirect access to the commercial paper market through the issuance of
such paper by their holding company or other affiliates.

By mid-

October the total of funds acquired in this manner was approaching
$3 billion.

Other somewhat more esoteric devices for acquiring non­

deposit funds also have been employed, including the sale of "ineligible"
bankers' acceptances and the placement of customers' paper subject to
payment guarantees through the bank's letter of credit.




-9Despite all of these liability management techniques,
total lendable funds of banks have fallen since the end of 1968,
as the growth in these sources of nondeposit funds has failed to
offset the decline in bank deposits.

Member bank deposits for the

year through September fell by about $12 billion, seasonally adjusted,
or by $16 billion unadjusted.

This compares with inflows of funds

from nondeposit sources of only slightly more than $11 billion.
Management of Lending Terms and Conditions
As I indicated earlier, banks might find monetary restraint
less frustrating if they could adopt or adjust their lending terms
and conditions to a more realistic evaluation of their own prospective
loan capacity in light of financial trends in the economy.

This

method of adjustment is much different in its implications from the
management of liquidity and liability positions.

Those techniques

attempt to alleviate an excess demand impasse by increasing the
supply of lendable funds, essentially at the expense of other potential
lenders in the economy.

Management of lending terms and conditions,

on the other hand, aims at constraining customers' demands for
accommodation to a level consistent with a projected flow of funds
from reasonably certain and stable sources.
The conventionally preferred way in which banks curtail
borrowing is by increasing the rate of interest charged customers
either explicitly or implicitly.
has risen sharply since late 1968.

The explicit cost of bank loans
The prime lending rate, for example,

has been raised five times since the end of November, from a level of




-106.25 per cent at that time to the current 8.50 per cent.

As we

all know, however, the true price of bank credit has risen con­
siderably more than would be indicated by this stated rate because
banks commonly have raised compensating balance requirements as
well as enforcing such requirements more strictly.
After taking these steps in 1969, many banking institutions
were still in an over-committed condition and have had to engage in
some form of nonprice rationing.
of creditworthiness.

Most have raised their standards

Preferential treatment is accorded to established

or local customers as opposed to new or non-local borrowers.

Customers'

deposit balances relative to their use of banking services in past
years has become an important measure of the relative profitability
of an account relationship and, therefore, a top criterion for loan
accommodation.
It is difficult to determine the relative importance of
these actions, i.e., the increase in effective lending rates or
the various forms of nonprice rationing, in contributing to the
observed slowing in the increase in bank loans.

The record shows

that the rate of growth in loans at all commercial banks has slowed
considerably since the end of May.

This slowing followed an increase

in the prime lending rate by a full percentage point to 8.50 per
cent early in June.

On the other hand, with liquidity positions

at extremely low levels and only limited success in obtaining
nondeposit sources of funds, banks may have begun to employ nonprice




-11rationing devices on a more serious basis at about that time.
Of course, some faltering in the underlying demand for bank loans-aside from that due to the increase in the lending rate— could have
been a factor, too.
Summary and Conclusions
What can we say about the relative merits of these three
means of adjustment to monetary restraint from the point of view
both of banks and of the monetary authority?
Recent experience emphasizes the need for a re-evaluation
of the various methods banks can use to adjust to monetary restraint.
What techniques are most effective and profitable for banks and also
consistent with the national interest?

While I would be the first

to admit that it is bankers who should do this re-evaluation, I
cannot resist the temptation to indicate the priorities and
possibilities as one would see

them from my position.

Of prime importance is the fact that banks should not
base their adjustments on the assumption that they can predict the
time, the duration and the intensity of monetary restraint.

Nor

should they assume that periods of monetary restraint will always
be relatively short-lived.

Changes in the structure of the economy,

the political environment, and in consumer, business and investor
expectations can alter both the intensity and duration of the
monetary action required to curb inflation.

The slower than antici­

pated response of the economy to monetary action in 1969 bears
ample witness to this statement.




The relatively taut and uncomfortable

-12position in which the banking system currently finds itself
reflects overcommitment based on the earlier expectation of
many bankers that this period of restraint would be over by now.
Even though "second guessing" the Fed is done with
confidence in some quarters I wouldn't recommend it or do it
myself, even as an insider, given the uncertainties in the timing
of responses to monetary actions.

The vagaries of the response of

economic activity to monetary restraint are simply too great.

But

if the urge to predict the speed of this response is irresistible,
it is better to err on the side of anticipating a long period of
restraint rather than a short one because the consequences of
conservatism will be less painful to the bank and probably to its
customers.

If restraint turns out to be short lived the worst that

can happen is that banks find they can make more loans and commit­
ments than they had initially expected.

It seems to me that this

is more consistent with an image of financial strength and sound­
ness than an obviously hectic scramble to obtain funds to meet an
over-extended position.

Some will say that a conservative assess­

ment of a liquidity squeeze will run the risk of antagonizing
customers unnecessarily, with the possible loss of accounts.

But

in a capital-short world toward which we seem to be heading customers
may think twice before deserting an institution whose assurances are
conservatively realistic.




-13-

How a firmer commitment policy ought best be implemented
would undoubtedly vary from bank to bank.

Some may wish to tie

their commitment policies to liquidity positions or projected
deposit flows, tightening policy as these become more adverse.
They may find it necessary to adjust their commitment policies in
light of estimation errors regarding movements in these variables
in the past.

Thus, if a banker finds he has underestimated deposit

outflows in recent months, it would seem prudent to tighten his
commitment policy to hedge against the possibility that he may
also be underestimating future deposit outflows.

Some sort of

public information campaign could make firmer commitment policies
somewhat easier to swallow from the borrower's point of view.

That

is, if these finner policies were couched in terms of a conscious
effort by banks to comply with the spirit of monetary restraint
in the fight against inflation, consumer resistance and alienation
to these policies might be minimized.
From the central bank's point of view the most orderly
and effective passing along of monetary restraint occurs if the
terms, availability, and price for new commitments are modified
as early as possible.

One might have expected that in 1969 banks

facing falling liquidity positions and the prospect of much reduced
inflows of funds would have curtailed commitment activity quite
early in the year.

However, such limited data as is available on

commitments suggests that this did not happen.




In fact, the dollar

-14-

volume of new commitments made in the May-July quarter--the latest
period for which data are available— still showed little tendency
to moderate.
Returning to other methods of adjustment, it seems clear
that dependence on liquidity and nondeposit sources of funds has
indeed become more risky and potentially unprofitable than formerly
appeared to be the case.

There certainly are limits to the

practicable swing in liquid asset holdings.

At one extreme, these

limits are set by the amount banks can afford to hold while taking
care of the normal needs of their loan customers.

At the other

extreme, there is some positive minimum working balance which banks
must prudently maintain.

Intermediate security holdings add some

flexibility to portfolio swings but if the initial yield prospects
are attractive the loss from liquidation may become prohibitive.
Nondeposit sources of funds have been imaginatively used—
in some cases, to the point of abuse— to provide significant
supplementary flows to meet excess demands at some banks.

But

the markets tapped by these devices are characterized by very
volatile supplies, which at critical times may prevent banks from
obtaining all of the funds they desire, except at extremely high
rates of interest and with negative margins.

Moreover, as recent

events have indicated, regulation of some nondeposit sources of
funds by the monetary authority— which I personally believe to have
been unnecessary— has limited the scope and flexibility for
defensive action by banks.




-15-

Given the shortcoming of the conventional means of adjust­
ment, it would seem reasonable from the banks' point of view to
increase reliance upon changes in lending terms and conditions
particularly with respect to policies concerning new commitments.
This would avoid a situation such as the current one, where liquidity
is cut to the bone, nondeposit sources of funds have been all but cut
off, and yet banks face a large overhang of unused commitments.

As

these commitments are drawn down in volume, banks are indeed placed
in an extremely uncomfortable— and probably profitless— position.
From the public point of view, more reliance on this
latter method of adjustment has great merit.

Clearly, a financial

crisis in the banking system is less likely during a period of
monetary restraint if banks manage their commitments so as to keep
them in line with their lendable funds.

Moreover; it is possible

that if banks began to ration credit earlier in a period of
monetary restraint, rather than waiting until liquidity and
liability positions forced them to do so, the degree and duration
of monetary restraint required to do the job might well be moderated.