View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220

TELEPHONE 566-2041

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Expected at 10:00 a.m.
July 22, 1980

STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE G. WILLIAM MILLER
SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS
U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:

Thank you for inviting me to present the Administration’s
views on the important subject of tax policy.
The question is
whether a tax reduction package should be enacted in the near
future, and if so when and with what characteristics and of what
magnitude.
The issues involved are complex and require careful study
and deliberation.
There are many criteria against which alternate
courses of tax action should be evaluated.
The timing and scale
of any tax reduction are particularly critical in view of inflationary
expectations and budgetary realities—and the impact of these
factors on domestic and international financial markets.

It is the considered judgment of the Administration that the
Congress should not seek to enact tax cutting legislation prior
to the national election.
During 1981, properly targeted tax cuts directed at strength­
ening the productive foundations of the economy may well prove to
be desirable.
If designed with care and deliberation as part of an
overall economic program, such action may well improve our economic
performance over the next several years.
But hasty tax cutting now could be counterproductive.
One
proximate cause of the current recession was the fever of inflationary
expectations early this year which brought serious disarray into
the financial markets and resulted in severe credit constraints
on businesses, farmers, and families.
Following strong initiatives
undertaken by the Administration last March after extensive consul­
tations with Congress, both inflation rates and interest rates
have come down dramatically.
These trends, aided by responsible
budgetary actions by the Congress, are laying a foundation for
recovery.
Taking premature action which might be perceived as
undermining fiscal responsibility could well interrupt or reverse
those trends and thus complicate the recovery.

M-599


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

In addition, the brief and busy legislative session remaining
before the election is not likely to provide the time or climate
for properly analyzing the kind of structural and well-focused
tax and other economic measures essential to the long-term health
of the economy.
Our joint responsibility is to secure a robust,
non-inflationary path of growth for the economy over the years
ahead.
This objective is not served by rushing forward at this
time with large injections of purchasing power or undigested
plans for transforming the revenue side of the fiscal accounts.

Acting after the election rather than in haste over the
coming weeks would also allow us to gain a much better understanding
of the economy’s evolution into recovery, a much better view of
trends and decisions on federal spending, and a firmer consensus
on other economic measures needed to improve the economy’s perform­
ance over the new decade.

Nevertheless, the opportunity to examine in depth the important
issues before this Committee is greatly appreciated.
In order to
do so, it is proposed to review long- and short-term economic
developments, to suggest appropriate criteria against which to
evaluate any future tax program, and to outline some of the major •
choices in establishing tax policy.
NEED FOR LONGER-RUN PERSPECTIVE

There'is a natural tendency to place emphasis on short-term
economic policy even though the underlying problems are long-term
in nature.
The adverse trends in inflation and productivity which
we are experiencing did not occur overnight.
They have been
developing for at least the last fifteen years.
Therefore, we
need to give serious attention to the origin of these and other
economic problems as a basis for dealing with them effectively.

The 1950’s and the early 1960’s were a period of strong U.S.
economic performance in both domestic and international markets.
Throughout much of the period, U.S. productive strength was unques­
tioned and the dollar was strong.
It has become a more difficult
world during the 1970’s and early 1980’s.
Inflation has become a
clear and present danger.
Energy prices have been pushed up
very sharply by the oil exporting countries.
The international
financial system has been placed under great strain.
International
trade has become increasingly competitive, and domestic industries
sometimes bear a heavy burden of adjustment.
We face a range of
complex economic problems at home and abroad.
There are no simple
solutions, no easy ways out.
These problems can be mastered —
but only if we face them squarely and resolutely, eschewing easy
answers based purely on hope or rhetoric.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3
Significant gains have been made in the last few years.
There is an increasing realization throughout the country that
many of our economic problems are structural in nature and long­
standing in origin.
The energy problem is being attacked now in
a coordinated way for the first time.
Fiscal and monetary policies
are being formulated with greater discipline to bring inflation
under control.
New approaches are being explored to reinvigorate
the industrial sector of our economy.
Substantial progress has
been made in reducing the burden of government regulation on the
private economy.
At the present, a great deal of attention is properly being
focused on the economic downturn.
There have been six previous
periods of contraction since World War II and on average they
have lasted a little less than one year.
The weight of informed
economic opinion—inside and outside of government—is that
the current period of contraction will end late this year or
early next, and will not be as deep as in 1973-75.

The current recession was not deliberately sought.
It has
inevitably caused real suffering, which we are acting to mitigate.
The downturn, also inevitably, will result in some reduction in
the rate of inflation.
Recovery must proceed without reigniting
inflationary forces.
As we contemplate recovery over the coming year, economic
policies should therefore be shaped in the interest of longer-run
stability.
The economy needs to perform much more strongly in
the future in the key areas of capital formation, productivity
growth, and international competitiveness, so that employment gains
can be sustained, without generating new waves of inflation.
That will not be accomplished by a hasty, across-the-board tax
cut.
Any tax program to reinforce recovery should be carefully
constructed to be consistent with overall economic objectives.
/
If our difficulties were simple or of recent origin, the
straightforward countercyclical use of fiscal policy might
meet the needs of the situation.
But our problems are deepseated. They have developed over a long period of time.
Simply
pumping purchasing power into the economy will not raise the
capital-labor ratio, increase the rate of growth of potential
output or improve U.S. competitive ability in foreign markets.
The range of policy options that we should have under active
consideration can best be appreciated by reviewing the general
trend of economic events that forms the background to the current
situation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

4

THE POST WAR ERA, 1945-65
The roots of our current economic problems go back several
decades.
During the 1950's our economy performed significantly
below its potential.
As a result, in the early 1960's we were
able to improve our economic performance by exploiting
under­
utilized resources.
We did not have to face difficult trade-offs,
but were able to have more of everything by running the economy
closer to capacity.
Our current problems began after the mid-1960's
when we tried to continue this approach long after we were running
up against economic limits.
Policies of economic stimulus began
to be reflected primarily in rising prices, not in rising output.

In the first twenty years of the postwar era, the U.S. inter­
national payments position was strong and we were able to assist
in the rebuilding of war-ravaged foreign economies.
Thereafter,
we have been faced intermittently with balance of payments difficul­
ties in an intensely competitive international economic environment.
In the earlier period, energy was cheap and readily available.
As a result, U.S. production methods and patterns of consumption
were heavily conditioned by low relative prices of energy.
Subsequently, a difficult and painful adjustment has had to be
made in an environment of energy scarcity.

Relatively Stable Prices.
During the period from 1947 to
1965, the GNP deflator rose at a 2.3 percent annual rate and the
consumer price index at a 1.9 percent annual rate.
There was a
sharp run-up of prices at the time of the Korean War, but relative
stability in the price level was characteristic of much of the
rest of the time.
During the same 1947 to 1965 period, compensation
per hour (wages plus fringes) in the private business sector rose at
an average of 5.1 percent annually, but there was a strong 3.2
percent annual rate of increase in productivity, which held the
rise in unit labor costs to a relatively modest 1.8 percent
annual rate of increase.
This was about in line with the rise
in the price level.
Cost-push factors were no particular problem
and inflation was held fairly well in check.
Longer-term price movements over this period masked some
shorter-term swings.
For example, the period 1955 through 1957
was one of moderately accelerating inflation and relatively high
rates of resource utilization.
The capacity utilization rate in
manufacturing was pushed into the range generally associated with
accelerating rates of inflation.
Considerable concern was expressed
at the time over the threat of inflation.
However, the ensuing
period from 1957-1963 was one of relatively low resource utilization
and decelerating inflation.
The manufacturing utilization rate
dropped to 80 percent and the rate of unemployment averaged 6


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

- 5

percent during those years.
As a result, the annual rate of
increase in the GNP deflator fell back to 1-1/2 percent, about
one-half of the rate experienced in the 1955-57 period.
The
following two years, 1964 and 1965, saw a transition to a fully
utilized economy, and by the mid-1960’s the postwar period of
relatively low rates of inflation was drawing to a close.

Strong Growth in Productivity.
The early postwar decades
featured a return to the fairly steady rates of growth in produc­
tivity which had been characteristic of much of U.S. 19th and
early 20th century economic experience.
Between 1947 and 1965,
output per hour in the private business sector rose at a 3.2
percent annual rate, or at a 2.6 percent annual rate with agricul­
ture excluded.
Real nonresidential fixed investment averaged in
the 9 to 10 percent range as a percentage of GNP throughout the
period.
There was a relatively strong rate of growth in the
stock of capital employed in the private business sector, about
3-1/2 percent per year on a gross basis and more than 4-1/2
percent per year on a net basis (after allowance for capital
replacement).
These rates of growth in the capital stock were
substantially higher than have been achieved in subsequent periods.
The civilian labor force grew at a relatively modest rate by
current standards, only 1.2 percent annually over the years from
1947 to 1965.
The combination of a rapid rate of growth in the
capital stock and a relatively slow rate of growth in the labor
force meant that the capital-labor ratio showed strong gains during
the first two postwar decades, rising at a 3 percent annual rate
on a net basis over the 1947-1965 period.

There is general agreement that the growth in economy-wide
productivity reflects many influences.
However, there has been a
close association in the postwar period between the capital-labor
ratio and the rate of growth in productivity.
The more rapid
application of capital into the productive process means that labor
works on the average with more and better tools of production.
This generally results in improved productive performance.
By the early 1960*s, there was some expression of concern
that the U.S. rate of investment was beginning to lag, particularly
in relation to that of some other major industrial countries.
Through much of the early postwar period, however, the capital
stock had expanded steadily and the rate of growth in productivity
was relatively satisfactory.
Difficulties in this crucial area
only surfaced in unmistakable fashion during the 1970's.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

Cheap and Readily Available Energy.
In the early postwar
period, domestic energy production was able to supply the needs
of the economy at relatively stable and even falling prices.
Total energy consumption rose at about a 3% annual rate and the
ratio of energy per unit of GNP drifted down slightly.
Gasoline,
heating oil, and electricity prices rose less rapidly than the
consumer price index, thereby encouraging energy consumption
rather than conservation.
Natural gas prices rose faster than
the consumer price index, but on a heat-content basis, natural
gas use rose faster then heating oil throughout the period.
The
average price of electricity dropped and electricity consumption
expanded.

The average fuel costs to the electrical generation industry
can be used as a proxy for industrial energy prices.
Between
1950 and 1965, coal costs decreased 9 percent in current dollars
and fuel oil costs rose only 5 percent.
Natural gas costs on a
heat-content basis were less than oil, and less than, or about the
same as, coal throughout the period.
In the 1950's, natural gas
was still largely an unwanted by-product of oil production and
exploration.
Between 1950 and 1965, crude oil reserves grew from 25.3
billion barrels to 31.4 billion barrels.
Quotas limited the
importation of foreign oils, which undersold domestic production.
Nevertheless, imports of petroleum grew from 550,000 barrels per
day in 1950 to 2.3 million barrels per day in 1965.
Natural gas
reserves grew from 185 trillion cubic feet in 1950 to 287 trillion
cubic feet in 1965, and natural gas distribution systems and
consumption expanded rapidly during the period.
Coal production
was limited only by demand.
In general, the energy situation in the early postwar period
was conducive to rapid economic growth and relatively low energy
prices encouraged its consumption.
Supplies of energy increased
rapidly and there were periods of overproduction and falling
prices.
No serious constraints to growth had emerged by the
raid-1960’s, although it was becoming apparent by then that the
long period of cheap and abundant U.S. crude oil resources was
coming to an end.

Strong Dollar Internationally.
In the immediate postwar
period, the dollar reigned supreme.
This was the era of "dollar
shortage" during which foreign countries resorted extensively to
capital and exchange controls to protect their currencies.
Full
currency convertibility was only established for the European
countries in the late 1950’s.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

7

The U.S. balance of payments situation was very strong from
1946 to 1949 with a merchandise trade surplus averaging about $7
billion a year and a favorable balance on current account averaging
nearly $4-1/2 billion, even after massive unilateral transfers to
enable other countries to rebuild their devastated economies.
Prom 1950 to 1959, the merchandise trade surplus averaged only
about $3 billion a year, and the favorable balance on current
account averaged less than $1 billion annually.
Subsequently,
in the 1960 to 1965 period, the U.S. payments position swung back
in the direction of improvement with an average annual trade
surplus of nearly $5-1/2 billion and a favorable balance on
current account of nearly $4-1/2 billion annually.
By the end
of this period, some signs of strain began to emerge, but chiefly
on capital account where low U.S. interest rates and freely
accessible capital markets encouraged a high rate of U.S. lending
to foreign borrowers.
Exchange rate adjustments throughout the first two postwar
decades were on the initiative of foreign countries against the
dollar, which remained at the center of the international financial
system in a fixed relationship with gold.
Following the
reestablishment of currency convertibility in the late 1950’s,
the dollar appreciated gradually against other major currencies
until the late 1960's and early 1970's.
By 1965, although some
signs of balance of payments strain were emerging, the dollar
remained the anchor of the world monetary system.

Rising Standard of Living.
Economic expansion yielded
sizable gains during the first twenty years after World War II,
despite interruptions to growth during four recessions.
From 1947
to 1965, real gross national product rose at about a 3.9 percent
annual rate.
Real disposable personal income •(personal income
after taxes and corrected for inflation) rose at about a 3.7
percent annual rate, and at nearly a 2 percent annual rate on a
per capita basis.
Median family income in real terms was more
than 60 percent higher by 1965 than it had been in 1947.
The combination of strong economic growth, rapid rates of
increase in the private capital stock and rising productivity
contributed to gains in real income.
Energy supplies were adequate
and a reasonable degree of success in containing inflation kept
the dollar strong at home and abroad.

THE ERA OF TRANSITION, 1965-1976

The transition to more difficult times began after 1965 when
production was expanded for a war effort without cutting back in
other areas.
Indeed, a sizeable—although long overdue—expansion
of domestic social programs was undertaken at about the same time.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

8
In the early 1970’s, new demands were placed on the economy for
environmental quality without making trade-offs to give up some­
thing else.
There was a continued belief that we could have
more of everything when this was no longer possible.
The oil
boycott and oil price shock added to the difficulties.
Inflation
was the inevitable result.
An ill-fated effort to apply mandatory
wage—price controls in the early 1970's only worsened the underlying
situation.
Partly as a consequence of domestic inflation, the dollar
weakened in foreign exchange markets and came under speculative
attack.
The dollar was devalued twice in the early 1970's, and
then was permitted to float, more or less freely, against major
currencies.
In late 1973 the OPEC oil embargo and subsequent
cartel pricing signalled the end of an era of inexpensive energy
and placed this country in a position of dangerous dependence on
uncertain sources of foreign supply.

The 1965-1976 period was a rude awakening to economic reality.
New demands were added onto the economy faster than the capacity
to satisfy them was expanded.
More and more was demanded from
the economy and by the end of the period the capacity to produce
in the future had been eroded substantially.

Deteriorating Price Situation.
The period from 1965 to 1970
was one of excessively high rates of resource utilization.
The
rate of unemployment averaged below 4 percent and demand pressures
were more or less chronic during most of the period.
Inflation
as measured by both the GNP deflator and the consumer price index
averaged over 4 percent, more than double the rate in the first
half of the 1960's.
During the period from 1970 to 1975, the
after effects of excess demand pressures from the late 1960’s
combined with a series of shocks, including the OPEC boost in oil
prices, to produce additional acceleration in inflation.
Inflation
as measured by both the GNP deflator and the consumer price index
averaged about 6-1/2 percent during the 1970-76 period and peaked
in the double-digit range prior to the 1974-75 contraction.
Compensation per hour (wages plus fringes) in the private
business sector moved up to a 7.6 percent rate of increase in the
1965-1976 period, some 2-1/2 percentage points above the 19471965 average rate of increase.
In addition, the rate of growth
in productivity fell off by more than a full percentage point to
a 1.9 percent rate of growth between 1965 and 1976.
As a result,
labor costs per unit of output rose at a 5.6 percent annual rate
in the 1965-1976 period, nearly 4 percentage points above the
increase between 1947-1965.
Cost-push pressures became firmly
imbedded in the wage-price structure by the mid-1970's, making
the permanent reduction of the rate of inflation a difficult
task.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

9

Declining Rate of Growth in Productivity.
During the 1965-76
period, the strong rate of productivity growth established in the
first two postwar decades began to taper off.
Output per hour in
the private business sector grew at a 1.9 percent annual rate, or
1.6 percent with agriculture excluded.
This represented a signifi
cant decline from the 3.2 percent, or 2.6 percent rate with
agriculture excluded, recorded between 1947 and 1965.
Growth in the civilian labor force picked up speed, rising
2.2 percent annually in the 1965-1976 period in contrast to 1.2
percent between 1947 and 1965.
Growth in the stock of private
business capital was relatively well maintained, although showing
some retardation in growth on a net basis and after exclusion of
pollution abatement expenditures.
As a result primarily of the
more rapid rate of growth in the labor force, the capital-labor
ratio grew much more slowly in the 1965-1976 period than it had
in the first two postwar decades.

It is not possible to identify the exact point at which the
U.S. rate of productivity growth began to decline.
Some of the
slowdown may have arisen gradually over time.
Some may have
been occasioned by the sharp rise in energy prices after 1973.
It is clear that the rate of growth in productivity had slowed
drastically by the close of the 1965-1976 period.
Energy Shock.
In 1973, events in international oil markets,
in particular the oil embargo, pushed world oil prices far above
those for domestic controlled oil.
The resulting shock to the
U.S. was substantial since imports and consumption of oil had
been rising rapidly while domestic production of oil and gas had
been declining after 1970.
Prom 1965 to 1973, total U.S. energy consumption grew at a
4.4 percent annual rate, compared with a 3.1 percent annual rate
during the previous fifteen years.
The energy to GNP ratio rose
to a peak by 1970.
Motor gasoline consumption was stimulated by
the completion of thousands of miles of interstate highways,
increased motor car ownership, and rising personal income.

Supply problems began to appear in the energy field in the
early 1970's.
The use of coal was inhibited by environmental
regulations and other factors.
Natural gas deliveries could not
keep up with demand and reserves began to top out in 1972.
Domestic crude oil production peaked in 1970 and reserves would
have fallen appreciably by 1975 except for the discovery of the
Alaskan North Slope fields.
Domestic oil production could no
longer expand to meet demand and imports filled the gap.
Imports
increased from 2.3 million barrels per day in 1965 to 6 million
barrels by 1973 and then dropped slightly by 1975.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

10

The OPEC oil embargo hit with particular force because of
the growing dependence of the U.S. economy on oil imports.
Imported oil prices rose from $2.14 per barrel in 1966 to
$3.37 per barrel in 1973.
Following the embargo in the winter of
1973-74, imported oil shot up to $11.45 per barrel in 1975.
Gasoline prices rose 83 percent and heating oil prices by
144 percent in the 1965-1975 period, compared to a 71 percent
rise in the consumer price index.
Most of the oil price increases
were in the last two years of the period when gasoline prices
increased by 27 percent and heating oil prices by 71 percent.
Natural gas prices increased by 66 percent between 1965 and 1975,
with a 33 percent increase between 1973 and 1975.
Industrial energy prices rose much faster than consumer prices
during the 1965-1975 period.
o

Coal prices advanced 254 percent, with a 106 percent increase
between 1973 and 1975.

o

Natural gas prices for industrial use increased 201
percent, with a 113 percent increase between 1973 and
1975.

o

Fuel oil prices advanced 509 percent, with a 195 percent
jump between 1973 and 1975.

A Weakening Dollar.
The 1965-1975 period was one of inten­
sifying pressure on the U.S. dollar.
At the beginning of the period,
the U.S. was running a surplus of about $5 billion both on merchandise
trade and on current account.
By the early 1970’s, both of these
surpluses had been wiped out and the international competitive
position of the dollar was severely impaired.
The international
financial system was fundamentally changed in August 1971 when
the United States announced suspension of the convertibility
into gold of dollars held by foreign monetary authorities.
Following this action, major exchange rate alignments, coupled
with devaluation of the dollar in terras of gold, were negotiated
in December 1971 and February 1973.
Subsequently, the international
monetary system moved to a regime of managed floating.

Between 1969 and 1974, the U.S. dollar depreciated about 16
percent on a trade weighted basis against the currencies of other
major industrial nations.
Cyclical improvement in the U.S.
balance of payments and other factors led to some temporary
strengthening of the dollar and by 1976 the trade weighted depreciation
was about 10 percent relative to the base rates of May 1970.
By
the end of the 1965-75 period, the U.S. trade account had moved


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

11
back into a $9.billion surplus and the current account was in
surplus by 518 billion. Exchange rate adjustments and temporary
cyclical factors were largely responsible for the improvement.
However, the longer run balance of payments outlook was clouded
by the existence of a rapidly rising bill for oil imports.
Standard of Living Continues to Rise.
Despite the sharp
adjustments occurring after the raid-1960's, standards of living
continued to rise.
In the 1965-1976 period, real GNP rose at a
2*9 percent annual rate, a little below the postwar average rate
of increase.
Real disposable income rose at a 3.5 percent annual
rate and at about a 2.5 percent annual rate on a per-capita basis.
However, constraints on growth were much more evident at the end
of the period than at the beginning, and the rate of inflation had
accelerated.
A sharp decline was developing in the rate of growth
in productivity which would limit the potential for future gains.

RECENT ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE, 1976-1980

By the last half of the 1970's, the Nation faced a watershed
in its economic history.
The world economy was changing at a
revolutionary pace.
The adverse trends which had developed with
respect to inflation, productivity growth, and international
competitiveness moved to center stage in the Nation’s discussions
of economic policy.
The Nation responded to these challenges by
moving to break important deadlocks in a number of important areas
of economic management.
This process has involved painful choices.
Changing the
Nation's course on matters of such fundamental economic importance
as energy policy and control of federal spending could not"be
accomplished overnight or without intensive debate.
We have
not succeeded completely on every fronts there remains a significant
agenda of unfinished business.
But in many key areas of economic
policy, a new strategic consensus has been forged, laying the
basis for improving our basic economic performance over the next
decade.
Some of the key areas in which progress has been made include:

o Fiscal prudence:
The Administration and Congress have
made the containment of domestic spending growth a major
priority of economic policy.
Working together, we have
strengthened budget procedures and discipline and provided
for rigorous annual review of "off budget" items through
the new Credit Budget.
Real growth in non-defense spending
has been dramatically reduced from the high rates registered
over the previous decade.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

12

o Domestic monetary policy:
The Federal Reserve Board
has improved its control over the long-term growth of
monetary aggregates as a means for bringing down the
inflation rate.
o Wage-price policy:
The Administration has disavowed
mandatory controls and has instead developed a structure
of voluntary wage-price standards.
Econometric tests
indicate that the inflation rate is now 1 to 1.5 percentage
points lower than it would have been without the program.

o Energy policy:
Programs for implementing the phase-out of price controls on crude oil and new natural gas are now in
place.
Massive new initiatives have been adopted to develop
alternate energy sources and spur conservation of oil.
The
new Synthetic Fuel Corporation will help create a huge, new
industry of energy supply, drawing upon the Nation’s
abundant coal and shale oil resources.
o Deregulation:
Regulations have been substantially reduced
with respect to airlines, trucking and financial institutions.
Large portions of the U.S. economy have been returned to the
discipline and opportunities of competitive market forces.

While considerable progress has been made, in many areas
continuing efforts will be required over a number of years.
Future
policies must place great stress on controlling inflation and
stimulating productivity.
In reviewing the record of recent
years, it is important to recognize accomplishments, but even
more important the need for continued progress.

Real Growth.
Substantial gains have been made in recent
years in terms of real growth.
From the trough quarter of
economic activity early in 1975 through the first quarter of 1979,
real GNP grew at an annual rate of 5.1 percent.
From the end of
1976 through the first quarter of 1979, that growth rate was 4.8%.
In the next four quarters, real growth slowed to about a 1 percent
annual rate, and in the second quarter of this year real growth
declined sharply—at an 9.1 percent annual rate according to
the preliminary estimates released recently.
However, even
sfter this decline, real GNP is about 20 percent above the early
1975 low.
2

This is a strong performance by past standards, but it obviously
reflects cyclical gains to a considerable extent.
Real growth
since the last cyclical peak in the fourth quarter of 1973 has
been about 2—1/2 percent annual rate.
This corresponds more
closely to estimates of the economy's current trend rate of potential


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

13

economic growth.
Potential growth has been estimated by CEA
as having been about 3 percent between 1973 and 1978 and likely
to fall to a 2-1/2 percent annual rate between 1979 and 1982.
This stands in marked contrast to an annual trend rate in potential
of about 4-1/2 percent from 1947 to 1953, and about 3-1/2 percent
from 1953 to the early 1970‘s.
Aside from cyclical movements,
the real progress of the economy is inevitably limited to its
trend potential.

Tax cuts designed simply for fiscal stimulus do little to
enhance the economy’s potential to produce goods and services.
Attention needs to be directed toward tax policies to promote
long-term growth potential, i.e., to raise the economy’s ability to
produce goods and services.
The lesson of the recent expansion
is that the economy encounters real barriers to expansion, reflected
in an acceleration of inflation, long before unemployment can be
reduced to desirable levels.
Efforts should therefore be directed
at the supply side of the economy, including selective programs
to attack structural unemployment.
Productivity and Investment.
Productivity fell off sharply
in the 1973-75 recession, and then made a strong cyclical recovery
in 1975 and 1976.
During 1977 and 1978 productivity increased by
an average of only 1 percent per year.
Over the past year, pro­
ductivity has actually declined by about 1-1/2 percent.
During
the early stages of a recovery, growth in output tends to exceed
increases in labor input by wide margins, but productivity gains
tend to slow rather markedly as the expansion ages.
The more
disturbing feature of productivity experience is the apparent
lower trend since the late 1960's.
Between 1948 and 1968, pro­
ductivity in the private nonfarm business sector of the economy
rose 2.6% per year; between 1968 and 1973 that growth slowed to
1.7% per year; and during the 1973 to early 1980 period growth
slowed still further to less than 1/2 of one percent.
The causes of the apparent secular decline in productivity
are still the subject of academic inquiry and difference of
opinion.
Some of the more important causes of the slower trend
growth in productivity that have been advanced are;
o

Demographic factors have been important since the mid-1960’s,
as the proportion of new, young and inexperienced workers
in the labor force increased.

o

An increasing proportion of capital investment has been
diverted in recent years to meeting government regulations
directed at improving the health and safety of workers
and the environment.
Labor resources have also been
diverted.
While these are essential efforts they do not
contribute directly to measured output in productivity.
These programs will continue but are unlikely to increase
at the rates of the recent past.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

14

o

A variety of other factors— such as the increase in
energy prices and a decline in worker motivation—have also
frequently been cited as adverse influences.

o

In the opinion of many observers, the most important
single factor has been a dramatic slowdown in the rate
of growth of the capital-labor ratio.
More capital per
worker generally contributes to higher productivity, and
the sharp fall in that ratio is a matter of real concern.
In the 1976-79 period, the ratio of the capital stock to
the civilian labor force edged up only slightly on a
gross basis and actually fell on a net basis.
This
stands in marked contrast to average gains in the net
capital-labor ratio of 3 percent annually from 1945 to
1965 and nearly 2 percent annually from 1965 to 1976.

It must be emphasized that business fixed investment has made
a strong cyclical recovery in recent years.
The problem is to
assure that these are sufficient incentives to boost the amount
of capital investment in the permanent fashion that is required
to raise productivity and the trend rate of potential growth.
That should be one of the major objectives of tax and other
policies over the years ahead.

Employment.
Growth in employment has been a major achievement
of the Carter Administration.
Since late 1976, civilian employment
has increased by nearly 11 million persons, even after allowance
for the cyclical employment declines of recent months.
The ratio
of employment to working age population has reached record levels,
although receding from its peak in recent months.
On the other
hand, the rate of unemployment has remained higher than desirable,
reaching a low for the expansion in the 5-1/2 to 6 percent range,
before rising rapidly in recent months.
The rise in the unemployment
rate in the current contraction has been heavily concentrated among
blue collar jobs which are predominantly held by adult men.
This
cyclical rise in the unemployment rate will be reduced when the
economy turns up again.
However, more remains to be done in
combatting structural unemployment if the average level of unemploy­
ment over the cycle is to be reduced to more acceptable levels.
The largest employment gains have been made by women and minority
groups.
Employment of adult women has increased by nearly 16 percent
since late 1976, compared to about 5-1/2 percent for adult men.
Employment of blacks and other minority groups has increased by 12
percent compared to a 9 percent rise for all groups.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

15

Employment gains are an important measure of the performance
of the economy.
However, it is also crucial that productivity
advance rapidly so that increased employment will mean rising
standards of living.
Energy.
Considerable progress has been made in reducing the
Nation's reliance on insecure sources of foreign oil.
Programs now
in place should yield increasing returns in the period ahead.
Already some tangible signs of progress can be seen.
Between 1975
and 1979, total energy consumption grew at a 2.4% annual rate,
slower than at any time during the previous 25 years.
The energy/GNP
ratio dropped steadily during the 1975-1979 period, and indications
are that the ratio will drop further in 1980.
Gasoline consumption
peaked in 1978 at 7.4 million barrels per day and dropped to 7.0
million in 1979.
In 1980, gasoline consumption could drop to
about 6-1/2 million barrels per day if present trends continue.
Domestic energy supply has increased over the period.
Crude
oil production edged up to 8.53 million barrels per day from 8.38
million barrels per day in 1975.
Much of the increase was due to
the exploration.of the Alaskan North Slope fields beginning in 1977.
Oil production in 1980 is expected to increase due to more Alaskan
production and in response to the phasing out of crude oil price
controls.
Natural gas production stayed relatively flat during the
1975-1979 period rather than continuing the decreases exhibited
in the preceding years.
Production in 1979 exceeded 1978 levels.
Coal is making a comeback, with 1979 production 18 percent above
1975, and 1980 production running well above 1979 to this point.

The heavy impact of rising oil prices on the domestic economy
and U.S. balance of payments has continued throughout the period.
The price of imported oil (f.a.s.) rose by 63 percent from*$11.45
per barrel in 1975 to $18.67 per barrel in 1979.
The price of
imported oil in 1980 will be $31.50 to $32 per barrel or about 70
percent higher than in 1979.
Net oil imports rose from 5.9
million barrels per day in 1975 to 7.9 million barrels per day
in 1979, with a peak of 8.6 million barrels per day in 1977.
So
far this year net imports are about 14 percent below the levels
of last year.
In general, the trends toward slower growth in
energy consumption, increased domestic production, and reduced
imports are all in the right direction.
Recent experience demonstrates that higher energy prices
significantly reduce energy demand.
There is no realistic
alternative to reliance on the price system to insure that scarce
energy resources are employed most efficiently, and that adequate
incentives are offered for future domestic energy production and
conservation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

16

Inflation.
The most discouraging feature of recent economic
performance was the acceleration of inflation in the late stages
of the current expansion.
The worst of the inflationary fever
has now been broken, by the policy measures taken at mid-March
and by the onset of recession.
The task that lies ahead is to
insure that the next period of economic expansion does not simply
ratchet the rate of inflation to still higher levels, but instead
that recent progress can be continued in a methodical trend toward
genuine price stability.

Between 1976 and 1979 on the basis of annual averages, the
GNP deflator rose at a 7.4 percent annual rate and the consumer
price index at an 8.4 percent annual rate.
These compare with
5-1/2 percent annual rates of increase in the 1965 to 1976 period.
More recently, rates of inflation have reached even higher levels,
before turning down.
Over the past six months or so, consumer
prices have risen at about a 15 percent annual rate, producer
prices at about a 12-1/2 percent annual rate, and the GNP deflator
at about 10.
As a result of recent inflationary pressures and workers’
attempt to maintain real incomes, compensation per hour (wages
plus fringes) has been boosted to the 9 to 10 percent range.
Because productivity growth has been negative, unit labor costs
have been rising in the 11 to 12 percent range for the past year
and a half.

Those who favor an across-the-board tax reduction to stimulate
the economy should ponder the implications in terras of inflation.
Over the past 15 years, every period of economic expansion has
driven the rate of inflation to new heights at the top of the
cycle.
The ensuing periods of contraction have temporarily
lowered the rate of inflation, but each time the rate of inflation
at the trough has been higher than before.
The International Position of the Dollar.
A major objective
of the Administration's international monetary policy has been
the maintenance of global confidence in a sound and stable dollar.
The program to strengthen the dollar, initiated by President Carter
in November 1978, represented a watershed in the U.S. exchange market
policy.
This program combined domestic measures to improve the
U.S. balance of payments—by curbing inflation and reducing
dependence on imported oil—with more active intervention in the
foreign exchange market to maintain orderly conditions.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

17

The November 1978 program demonstrated a clear-cut U.S.
commitment to a sound dollar and stability in exchange markets.
Since that program, the dollar has increased in value on average
in terms of other major currencies.
The U.S. balance of payments
has, moreover, scored major gains, despite large increases in
oil prices and consequently in oil import costs.

It must be recognized, however, that the strength of the
dollar depends, in the last analysis, upon our demonstrated
ability to keep the domestic economy strong and to reverse the
inflationary trend of the past 15 years.
CURRENT ECONOMIC SITUATION AND THE BUDGET REVISIONS

Change in Economic Assumptions.
At the turn of the year when
the January Budget estimates were being completed, the economy was
continuing to show far more strength than most economists had
expected.
In fact, some additional momentum appeared to develop late
in 1979. A mild recession was generally expected, based on the
downturn already underway in housing and the prospect that consumers
would slow their rate of spending.
The timing of a recession
was uncertain, however, and few signs of an imminent downturn were,
in evidence.
Retail sales, production and employment all rose in
January.
The economic climate shifted rapidly through early March.
The shift was triggered by a number of factors.
The long projected
recession failed to materialize.
As evidence began to build that
the first quarter would show positive real growth and January
retail sales turned in an especially strong showing, some economic
and financial market participants began to question whether a reces­
sion was really in prospect.
Because of heightened international
tensions, financial raairkets began to anticipate an increased
defense effort, in consequence much larger budget deficits,
more inflation, and higher interest rates.
There was an upsurge
of speculative activity in commodity markets which was both a
cause and a result of shifting anticipations as to the future
course of inflation.
Rapidly rising energy prices plus rising
mortgage interest rates helped cause the CPI to shoot up by 1.4%
(18% annual rate) in each of the first three months of the year.
These developments combined to generate a dramatic shift in
inflationary expectations.
Businesses began to post price increases
in anticipation of higher rates of inflation and the fear that wageprice controls would be imposed.
Excluding food and energy, producer
prices jumped at a 15% annual rate in the first three months of
the year at the finished goods level and a 17% rate for semi-finished
goods.
Interest rates began to shoot upward.
Yields on commercial
paper, which had averaged about 13% in December, were well above
16% in early March.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

18

The intensified anti-inflation package announced on March 14
was designed to reverse these developments.
Its principal components
were increased fiscal discipline, including a reduction of some
$17 billion from FY-1981 planned outlays, a program of credit
restraint, and structural reforms directed at improving the
longer-term performance of the economy.
The package also included
proposals in the energy area and steps to strengthen the wage-price
guideline program.

The program, along with actions taken by the Federal Reserve,
reversed the inflationary psychology.
Interest rates continued
to rise into early April, but then declined dramatically.
Commercial
paper rates moved above 17-1/2% in early April, but subsequently
fell to the 8% range.
By early June, commitment rates for conventional
home mortgages had fallen 300 basis points from the 16-1/2% of
early April to 13-1/2%.
The Treasury bill rate temporarily fell
below 7 percent in contrast to an early peak near 16 percent.
From its peak of 20 percent, the prime rate has fallen back near
11 percent.
These interest rate declines are laying the
foundation for the recovery of the economy.
Meanwhile, the greater than expected strength in activity
early in the year led most economists to mark up their projections
of real activity, at least for 1980.
However, as figures became
available for March, April, and May, it became evident that demand
and production had been dropping rapidly.
New car sales plunged
(from a 10.8 million annual rate in the first quarter to a 7.7
million rate in the second), total retail sales took a record
drop, industrial production fell by 4-1/2% between February and
May, and orders placed with manufacturers of durable goods plummeted
by 17% from January to May.

Again, forecasts for 1980 were revised to incorporate these
new realities.
The tabulation below shows the shifting consensus
forecast of about 40 top private business economists.*
Forecasted 1980 Changes in Real Gross National Product

Forecast date
January
March
July

4th to 4th
year to year
(---------------- percent---------------------)
-1.0
-1.0
-0.4
+0.1
-3.3
-1.4

*Blue Chip Economic Indicators, Capital Publications Inc.,
various issues.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

19

The economic path underlying the Mid-Session Review of the
Budget registers the downturn in activity that is now underway and
parallels the change in assessment of near-term economic events
that has taken place among private economists.
Real GNP is now
projected to decline by 3.1% between the fourth quarter of 1979
and the fourth quarter of 1980, with the steepest part of that
decline in the second quarter of this year.
The economy is
expected to move downward still further in the second half, but
at a more moderate rate, with the slide perhaps bottoming out
late in the year.

The projected course of the economy would carry the unemployment
rate up to the 8.5% range by the turn of the year, and the very
moderate recovery of real GNP and employment thereafter would do
little to bring the unemployment rate down over 1981.
As measured
by the GNP deflator, inflation is projected to moderate from 10.1%
for this year to 9.7% in 1981, both measured fourth quarter to
fourth quarter.
It is important to emphasize the great uncertainty associated
with all of these projections.
Throughout this year, economic
forecasts from virtually all sources have undergone major revisions
on nearly a monthly basis.

Nevertheless, it is clear that the projected course of economic
performance is not satisfactory.
As the recovery develops, policy
steps to improve the economy’s performance, both in 1981 and for
the longer term, may well be appropriate.
The Administration
is reviewing the various possibilities and welcomes the opportunity
to consult with the Congress about them.
However, the steps need not and should not be taken in haste.
The economy’s structural problems require carefully designed
structural answers.

Turning to the nearer terra, we expect that the natural forces
of recovery will begin to manifest 'themselves.
The consensus expectation of economists, inside and outside
of government, is that the upturn will occur late this year or
early next.
This would conform in a rough way to the postwar
cyclical pattern.
The average duration of periods of contraction
in the six previous postwar recessions has been 11 months, although
1973-75 was longer, and the peak of the recent expansion has now
been dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research as having
occurred in January 1980.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

20

A recent survey* of 40 private economists at major banks,
corporations, and private research organizations sees successively
smaller declines in real GNP during the third and fourth quarters
of this year and a return to positive growth early next year.
This is the generally expected pattern.
It may not occur exactly
as predicted.
Economic forecasting is a very imperfect art.
The
important poi«nt is that the official forecast accords reasonably
with the consensus of private forecasts and constitutes a realistic
appraisal of the near-term outlook.
Recent readings on the economy suggest that the decline is
still continuing, but not at the accelerated pace of the early
part of the second quarter.
The economy is still moving downward,
the third quarter will almost certainly register another decline
in real GNP.
However, there are signs that the rate of decline
has slowed markedly.
— Retail sales scored a 1.5% increase in June.
Excluding
autos, sales rose slightly more than inflation.

— New car sales in early July bounced up from their
depressed second-quarter, pace (though we should
not attach too much significance to this rise until
confirmed by additional data).

— Seasonally adjusted initial claims for insured unemployment
have fallen back in early July from their earlier peaks.
— Housing starts and permits rose strongly in June, reversing
the trend of earlier months.
Housing activity appears to
be benefiting already from the interest rate declines
in recent months.

— Businesses have been making a determined effort to keep
inventories under control.
The decline in business
inventory holdings in May indicates some success in
these efforts, lean inventory positions would imply that
when demand turns up, production would shortly follow.

— Demands for short-term business credit show signs
of renewed strength.

*Blue Chip Economic Indicators, Capital Publications Inc.,
July 10, 1980, Vol. 5, No. 7, esp. p. 3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

21

The Revised Budget Estimates.
The Mid-Session Review shows
substantial changes in budget estimates.
The basic numbers are
presented in the table below.

Receipts
Outlays
Deficit,
current
estimate
Budget
authority

BUDGET TOTALS '
(in billions of dollars)
1979
_______ 1980 Estimate
Actual
Jan.
March
July

19 81 Estimate
Jan.
March
July

465.9
493.7

523.8
563.6

532.4
568.9

517.9
578.8

600.0
615.8

628.0
611.5

604.0
633.8

-27.7

-39.8

-36.5

-60.9

-15.8

16.5

-29.8

556.7

654.0

665.8

653.7

696.1

691.3

707.2

The 1980 deficit is now estimated to be $60.9 billion, up from
$36.5 billion in March.
Outlays are currently estimated at
$578.8 billion and receipts at $517.9 billion.
The current
estimate for 1981 is for a deficit of $29.8 billion, rather than
the $16.5 billion surplus estimated in March.
Outlays are currently
estimated at $633.8 billion and receipts at $604.0 billion.
Both the increase in the 1980 deficit and the shift from surplus
to deficit in 1981 are mainly the result of changes in the economic
situation, though the estimates also reflect legislative events,
higher spending on defense and emergency relief programs, and
some minor technical changes.
The 1980 deficit is now estimated to be $24.4 billion
higher than in March.
Of this amount, about two-thirds, or
$16.6 billion is due to the change in economic conditions.
Receipts are down nearly $11 billion and outlays up $7 billion
for this reason alone.
Policy changes and Congressional action
have reduced receipts by $4 billion in 1980 and $8.4 billion in
1981, and are partially offset by technical re-estimates and
other factors.
In addition to the effect of changed economic
conditions, outlays are running somewhat higher because of defense
outlays and increases for disaster relief, alien assistance, and
other unavoidable events.

The larger budget deficits do not reflect an upsurge in
discretionary federal spending.
Congressional responses to the
President’s proposal for spending restraint have been constructive.
While there are some differences in program priorities, the
Congressional budget efforts to this point are generally consistent
with the policy of fiscal stringency proposed by the President.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

22
Financing the Deficit.
Policy steps over the next 13 months
could of course alter the economic and budgetary projections
released this week.
We have, however, analyzed the financing
requirements implicit in these projections.
The Treasury’s FY 1980 and FY 1981 financing requirements,
while increased from the levels projected in mid-March, are not
expected to strain the credit markets.
Private demands for
credit will likely be more than correspondingly reduced as a
result of continued weakness in economic activity for the remainder
of 1980.
Even with the Treasury’s increased borrowing in the months
ahead, the ratio of public holdings of Treasury securities to GNP
is not likely to rise much above the current level of about 26
percent.
In FY 1976, when a budget deficit of over $66 billion
was financed, this ratio rose to nearly 30 percent.
Looking ahead to FY 1981, our borrowing needs will probably
be heaviest in the first two quarters of the fiscal year.
The
use of a wide variety of borrowing options currently available
to the Treasury should minimize any undesirable impact of this
increased financing.

The recovery in the economy is expected to begin late this
year or early in 1981, but in the absence of other actions the
upturn is projected to be relatively slow.
Private credit demands
are typically slow to rise in the initial stages of an upturn,
and the expected moderation in the rate of recovery may further
hold down private borrowing.
Financing policy is not greatly challenged when the automatic
stabilizers in the economy tend to result in deficits in periods
of slack economic activity.
But the string of deficits experienced
in the postwar period in boom years as well as in periods of
slack, has imposed an added burden on the performance of the
economy and its financial markets.
If the monetary authorities
finance such untimely deficits, excessive growth of credit is
generated, and an inflationary atmosphere is created.
If, on
the other hand, the monetary authorities decline to make credit
available to finance the deficit, the available pool of savings
and capital formation and productivity suffer.
The solution must
be a move toward budget balance over the course of the cycle.
Sizable surpluses in periods of prosperity may well be desirable,
particularly if tax and other policies are successful in promoting
more robust private investment performance.
We are making progress
toward such a long-term fiscal policy, but continuing efforts are
required.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

23
TAX POLICY AND AN APPROPRIATE FISCAL STRATEGY
In turning now to the issue of appropriate fiscal policy
under present circumstances, several basic considerations should
be kept in mind.

First, Congress has been making progress in restraining the
rate of growth in expenditures.
This basic fiscal discipline
must be maintained.
Too often in the past, expenditure control
has been a short-term enterprise which was soon abandoned.
Now
that the painful decisions have been made, we should follow
through in a clear demonstration that a new fiscal course is
being followed.
Failure to do so runs the risk of dissipating
all the gains that have been made to this point.
Domestic financial
markets are functioning smoothly at home and the dollar is showing
encouraging stability abroad.
Both domestic and international
financial stability require that we continue to pursue a responsible
fiscal course.
Second, it is difficult to predict the exact course that
the economy will follow.
Interest rates have fallen much more
sharply than most observers expected.
This could induce an
earlier upturn in credit sensitive sectors of the economy.
If
the economy were to rebound more quickly than expected, fiscally
stimulatory actions might prejudice our progress in bringing down
inflation.

The Venice Economic Summit reinforced our view that relaxation
of demand management policy in the major world economies would
be premature.
The Venice communique clearly stated that "the
reduction of inflation is our immediate top priority... Determined
fiscal and monetary restraint is required to break inflationary
expectations."
Global inflation rates are still unacceptably
high and we have not yet succeeded in reducing inflationary
expectations.
Too early a retreat from restraint, might re-ignite
inflationary expectations and erase the hard-won gains we have
just begun to make.

Third, the kind of future tax program that should be developed,
with full consultation between the Administration and the Congress,
will necessarily involve some complex issues and controversial
decisions.
There are enough choices and technical problems in
depreciation reform alone to consume more legislative time than is
now remaining before scheduled adjournment.
Even proposals that
start with apparently simple formulas would not be easy to enact
into law, especially in a politically-charged environment.
The
only program that is simple enough — slashing rates according
to a formula — would be counterproductive.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

24
Fourth, it would be unwise to .try to complete a large tax
cut program in this session of Congress.
The effort to do so
would be caught up in all of the political cross-currents of an
election year.
It would be subject to the full weight of
pressure from every faction that has an interest in special
relief.
If any agreement were to emerge from this environment,
it would very likely be a melange of special interest provisions
— just the opposite of what is needed.

A tax program may well be appropriate for next year.
Anticipating this possibility, now is a good time to set out
criteria and to begin to consider the outlines of such a
program.

Criteria for a tax reduction program
Accord with fiscal discipline and spending restraint.
A
tax program should be considered in the context of the restraint
demonstrated on the spending side.
Any tax reduction agenda
must consider the revenue effects for at least five years, not
just for the first year.
This budget planning should be based
on reasonable projections for expenditures and economic
conditions, including realistic economic responses to any tax
changes.
They should not be based on hopes, wishes, or magic
formulas•

Combat inflation.
An anti-inflation tax program should
have at least two main attributes.
First, in the short run it
should not create excessive additional demand pressures or
rekindle inflationary expectations.
Second, it should help
encourage investment and, thereby, improve productivity and
reduce unit labor costs.
If, at the same time, the program
could directly contribute to cost reduction, that would be an
added plus.
Maintain confidence in financial and foreign exchange
market.
In recent months, the program of fiscal restraint has
gone a long way to reassure investors at home and abroad that
the long upward trend of inflation has been broken.
It is
important that any major fiscal program be perceived as
one that maintains a steady course.
Deliberate development of a
program aimed at long-run objectives can reinforce this
perception.
In contrast, an abrupt shift toward stimulus could
disturb financial and currency markets, complicating the
recovery.
Focus on improving productivity growth and international
competitiveness.
We must give more attention to the supply side
of the economy.
The realization of our public and private goals
— a strong defense, expanding employment, growth in real income


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

25
and opportunity, energy independence, and improved international
accounts — depends on increasing the rate of investment to
modernize the capital stock and increase capital per worker.
This requires that tax incentives be concentrated on capital
expansion, not dissipated in special interest provisions that
only move capital from place to place.

Promote the most effective use of available resources.
It
is not enough to expand the size of the capital stock and
increase jobs.
The jobs and capital should go where they will
have the highest payoff. This is the least costly way to
achieve real economic expansion.

The best judge of the prospective payoff is not the
government; it is private markets. Reducing taxes where they
interfere the most and avoiding the creation of new tax dis­
tortions are the keys to the effective allocation of jobs and
capital.

Preserve the progressivity of the tax structure. Inflation
and reduced energy"supplies have further restricted the choices
for families with modest incomes. The payroll tax also takes a
disproportionate share from wage earning families of low and
moderate income. Although "bracket creep" has occurred for
every class, those with lower incomes are least able to absorb
or avoid the higher rates. Any plan for reducing individual tax
rates must carefully consider the effects on the progressivity
of the system.

Reflect close consultation with Congress. The criteria
offered here indicate priorities and suggest an agenda, but
there are large choices within them concerning methods and
degrees of emphasis. The Administration wishes to work out
these choices in close consultation with this and other
committees and with individual members of Congress. Your
knowledge and experience are vital to the process of
constructing an effective program.
MAJOR TAX POLICY CHOICES

The principal objectives of economic policy and the current
structure* of the tax system indicate that any future tax changes
should be pointed in two major directions. The first would be
to reduce the burden of taxes on households and on labor costs.
The second would be to provide incentives for productive
business investment. A strong case can be made for a number of
tax policy.options. Putting a tax program together, however,
involves choice. Revenue simply is not available to make all
the changes everyone would like.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

26

Reducing the tax burden on labor income
The taxation of wage earners is mainly determined by the
structure of individual income tax rates and the rate of payroll
taxes for social security.
The purpose of the graduated rate
structure in the income tax is to apportion the tax burden
equitably among households of differing means.
A by-product of
this structure is automatic tax increases resulting from
year-to-year increases in money incomes.
This tendency — often
called "bracket creep" — has led Congress to make periodic
adjustments, especially in periods of inflation.

Over the period from 1969 to 1979 legislated adjustments to
the rate schedule produced nearly the same effect as indexing
for middle-income families.
A family of four of. median income
($24,400 at 1980 levels) would have paid income tax of 10.0
percent in 1969 and 10.4 percent in 1979, if its income had just
kept pace with inflation over those years.
However, rapidly
increasing money wages continue and more households have begun
to encounter the steeper portions of the rate schedule that was
enacted in 1978.
Consequently, the same family of median income
will pay 11.4 percent in federal personal income taxes for 1980
and 12.1 percent in 1981.
Increasing individual tax rates and, particularly, the
higher rates that apply to any additions to family income are
felt especially by families with two wage earners.
Consid­
eration should be given to the marriage penalty in connection
with individual rate adjustment.
The other main element in the taxation of labor income —
the payroll tax — has been increased steadily to provide
funding for increasing real benefit levels to a growing popu­
lation of social security recipients.
In combination, the
income and payroll taxes add substantially to the differential
between the cost of labor to businesses, on the one hand, and
the after-tax pay of workers, on the other.
At current rates of
income and payroll taxes, an employer must pay $1.52 in wages
and payroll tax to add $1.00 to the after-tax pay of an employee
in a median income family.
This represents a combined marginal
tax rate on labor income of 34.1 percent.

Scheduled increases in the payroll taxes will increase
these marginal rates of tax by nearly a percentage point in
1981, considering the increases for both employer and employee.
In seeking equitable ways to reduce the taxation of labor


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

27

income, attention should be given to the added burden on labor
costs from payroll tax increases and also to the funding needs
of the Social Security system.

One approach to this problem is the proposal put forward by
Congressman Gephardt.
Under this plan, individuals and
businessmen would be permitted an income tax credit for a
portion of social security taxes paid.
The credit could be
refunded to employers and employees who owe no income tax
liability.
This method would offset the increase in payroll
taxes without interfering with funding for the social security
system.
Other approaches to the increasing burden on wages also
deserve exploration.
A result similar to the Gephardt plan may
be attained by matching individual income tax cuts to the
payroll tax increases, for example.
However, direct reduction
of the payroll tax should not be considered except in the
context of a comprehensive analysis of trust fund financing
issues.

Tax treatment of saving
Taxation of income from ownership of property has also
generally been increasing.
This is partly because the average
individual saver who receives interest, dividend, rental or
business income has also moved up into higher income tax
brackets.
Another reason is that inflation leads to over­
statement of business profits.
But these increases are by no
means uniform.
The many sources of property income are subject
to a great variety of tax treatments.
For example, income from
corporate equity may be fully subject to corporate taxes and
also subject to individual taxes when distributed as dividends
to shareholders.
At the other extreme, the first $400 of
interest income, interest from municipal bonds, earnings on
individual retirement accounts, and vested pension funds are all
effectively tax exempt.
Still other kinds of property income,
such as from real estate, minerals, and appreciation of
corporate stock are only partially subject to tax.

While many of the savings incentive provisions adopted
piecemeal over the years may have been intended to increase
availability of capital, some are'extremely inefficient and may
even be counterproductive.
The ability of taxpayers to switch
their assets from one form
to another, or to borrow in order to
invest in a tax-preferred asset, has reduced, if not eliminated,
the ability of many of these provisions to increase overall
savings.
Revenues lost because of tax preferences for certain
types of income require increases in rates of taxation on all
taxable income.
The approach of providing "saving incentives"


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

28

to certain narrowly defined uses of funds or special kinds of
investments should be rejected in favor of more direct, broad
based and efficient incentives for investment.
Another important result of the uneven treatment of pro­
perty income is to divert saving and investment away from*the
relatively high-taxed.industrial sector.
Industrial corpora­
tions and public utilities are those most likely to bear the
full corporate income tax and produce taxable dividends.
They
also are hardest hit by the erosion of depreciation allowances
resulting from inflation.
This causes depreciation—-a major
cost of using capital goods—to be understated and inflates
taxable profits.

Depreciation reform
Among choices for encouraging capital investment and
raising productivity, acceleration of depreciation allowances
offers the greatest potential for success.
In general, such a
provision would reduce the tax bite on the return to successful
investment and also enable higher returns to be paid to direct
or indirect suppliers of capital, whether they are lenders,
shareholders, members of pension funds, or depositors in
financial institutions.
As compared with tax breaks to
particular types of saving, the benefits of accelerated
depreciation are more directly tied to productive investment and
less.susceptible to "gaming" by simultaneous borrowing and
lending transaction and other shifts in individual portfolios.

The particular program for accelerating depreciation that
emerges
should avoid the kinds of problems that afflict the
10-5-3 proposal.
That proposal would quickly become very
expensive.
It is uneven and haphazard in the way it spreads
benefits among types of assets and industrial sectors.
Its
transition phase is needlessly complicated and may promote
investment delays.

Most proposals to accelerate depreciation for newly
acquired assets will generate revenue losses that grow more
rapidly than the economy for several years.
Careful budget
planning is required, therefore, for any depreciation program.
The reason for this increasing cost is that each year's
investment adds increased depreciation deductions on top of the
higher deductions still being taken on investments made before.
The 10-5-3 proposal exaggerates this pattern by specifying a
phased reduction in lives over the first 5 years.
For example,
in the first year machinery and equipment would be written off
in no more than 9 years, the next year in 8 years, and so on
down to 5.
This may entice the Congress by offering a very low


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

29

downpayment.
But the revenue cost under this approach would
grow about twelve-fold in the first five years, from less than
$5 billion to nearly $60 billion.
The 10-5-3 proposal becomes so expensive because it would
eventually allow the same combination of deductions and
investment credits for nearly all classes of machinery and
equipment.
These allowances would be more generous than those
for even the shortest write-off periods in present law.
This
approach greatly increases the value of deductions for
long-lived kinds of equipment such as those used in power plants
and ship building.
In contrast, the increased allowances for
equipment that wears out rapidly or becomes quickly obsolete
(such as tools used in metal fabricating and electronics) would
be relatively small.
For owners of commercial and industrial
buildings the value of additional tax saving is, in turn, much
larger than the average increase for investors in machinery and
equipment.
Thus, the 10-5-3 formula indiscriminately favors the
movement of capital to structures as well as to long-lived
equipment, a pattern not clearly related to any criteria for
cost effectiveness in adding to productivity or other economic
goals.

The Administration will support at the appropriate time a
more even-handed approach to accelerating depreciation
allowances.
A connection should be retained between deductions
for depreciation and the actual depreciation experience for
assets used in different kinds of production activities.
Such
an approach would be superior to 10-5-3 in a number of important
respects:
o

It would flatten out the trend in revenue losses,
roviding the tax reductions earlier and having much
ess impact on future budget options.

P
o

It would not require the kind of phased introduction
scheme that imposes additional accounting burdens and
weakens the investment incentives at the time they are
most needed.

o

It would introduce less distortion into the pattern of
investment incentives.
Additional capital made
available by the promise of increased returns and by
prudent budget policy would be generally attracted to
industries with profitable investment opportunities not
directed to particular kinds of property.

A capital recovery system that involves simpler accounting,
greater certainty, and reduced administrative complexity can be
designed without the cost or distortions of 10-5-3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

30

CONCLUSIONS

During the next five years, the U.S. must take the steps
required to build a strong foundation for superior economic
performance and increased economic security. We must show the
discipline to make the sacrifices needed to strengthen our
economy for the long run, while at the same time providing
assistance to those most adversely affected by short-run
economic disruption.

The U.S. stands at the threshold of a new economic era.
What we do over the next five years will determine whether this
new era brings an unparalleled standard of economic well being
or a slow drift to mediocrity. To make the most of this
opportunity, we must not only build on past gains, but also be
willing to reverse past errors. Many of the economic problems
now facing us stem from an unwillingness, stretching back at
least 15 years, to confront directly difficult trade-offs and
choices. Hard choices must be made if the U.S. economy is to
thrive in an increasingly competitive world.

There are four major objectives for economic policy for the
next five years: First, to improve our economy’s productive
capacity so we can enjoy stronger growth in real incomes.
Second, to return to longer run price stability, which will
permit us not merely to reach a high employment level but to
sustain it. Third, to enhance our competitive position
internationally. And, fourth, to reduce our vulnerability to
externally generated shocks, such as energy interruptions.

A tax program, properly timed, and consistent with the
criteria outlined above can make a significant contribution to
attaining these objectives. If we move in that direction
patiently and responsibly, we will be able to improve greatly
our economic outlook for the balance of this century.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

/

Department of theTREfi
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220

TELEPHONE 566-2041

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Expected at 10:00 a.m.
July 22, 1980

STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE G. WILLIAM MILLER
SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS
U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:

Thank you for inviting me to present the Administration's
views on the important subject of tax policy.
The question is
whether a tax reduction package should be enacted in the near
future, and if so when and with what characteristics and of what
magnitude.
The issues involved are complex and require careful study
and deliberation.
There are many criteria against which alternate
courses of tax action should be evaluated.
The timing and scale
of any tax reduction are particularly critical in view of inflationary
expectations and budgetary realities—and the impact of these
factors on domestic and international financial markets.
It is the considered judgment of the Administration that the
Congress should not seek to enact tax cutting legislation prior
to the national election.
During 1981, properly targeted tax cuts directed at strength­
ening the productive foundations of the economy may well prove to
be desirable.
If designed with care and deliberation as part of an
overall economic program, such action may well improve our economic
performance over the next several years.
But hasty tax cutting now could be counterproductive.
One
proximate cause of the current recession was the fever of inflationary
expectations early this year which brought serious disarray into
the financial markets and resulted in severe credit constraints
on businesses, farmers, and families.
Following strong initiatives
undertaken by the Administration last March after extensive consul­
tations with Congress, both inflation rates and interest rates
have come down dramatically.
These trends, aided by responsible
budgetary actions by the Congress, are laying a foundation for
recovery.
Taking premature action which might be perceived as
undermining fiscal responsibility could well interrupt or reverse
those trends and thus complicate the recovery.

M-599


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

In addition, the brief and busy legislative session remaining
before the election is not likely to provide the time or climate
for properly analyzing the kind of structural and well-focused
tax and other economic measures essential to the long-term health
of the economy.
Our joint responsibility is to secure a robust,
non-inflationary path of growth for the economy over the years
ahead.
This objective is not served by rushing forward at this
time with large injections of purchasing power or undigested
plans for transforming the revenue side of the fiscal accounts.
Acting after the election rather than in haste over the
coming weeks would also allow us to gain a much better understanding
of the economy’s evolution into recovery, a much better view of
trends and decisions on federal spending, and a firmer consensus
on other economic measures needed to improve the economy’s perform­
ance over the new decade.

Nevertheless, the opportunity to examine in depth the important
issues before this Committee is greatly appreciated.
In order to
do so, it is proposed to review long- and short-term economic
developments, to suggest appropriate criteria against which to
evaluate any future tax program, and to outline some of the major .
choices in establishing tax policy.
NEED FOR LONGER-RUN PERSPECTIVE

There is a natural tendency to place emphasis on short-term
economic policy even though the underlying problems are long-term
in nature.
The adverse trends in inflation and productivity which
we are experiencing did not occur overnight.
They have been
developing for at least the last fifteen years.
Therefore, we
need to give serious attention to the origin of these and other
economic problems as a basis for dealing with them effectively.

The 1950’s and the early 1960's were a period of strong U.S.
economic performance in both domestic and international markets.
Throughout much of the period, U.S. productive strength was unques­
tioned and the dollar was strong.
It has become a more difficult
world during the 1970's and early 1980's.
Inflation has become a
clear and present danger.
Energy prices have been pushed up
very sharply by the oil exporting countries.
The international
financial system has been placed under great strain.
International
trade has become increasingly competitive, and domestic industries
sometimes bear a heavy burden of adjustment.
We face a range of
complex economic problems at home and abroad.
There are no simple
solutions, no easy ways out.
These problems can be mastered —
but only if we face them squarely and resolutely, eschewing easy
answers based purely on hope or rhetoric.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3

Significant gains have been made in the last few years.
There is an increasing realization throughout the country that
many of our economic problems are structural in nature and long­
standing in origin.
The energy problem is being attacked now in
a coordinated way for the first time.
Fiscal and monetary policies
are being formulated with greater discipline to bring inflation
under control.
New approaches are being explored to reinvigorate
the industrial sector of our economy.
Substantial progress has
been made in reducing the burden of government regulation on the
private economy.

At the present, a great deal of attention is properly being
focused on the economic downturn.
There have been six previous
periods of contraction since World War II and on average they
have lasted a little less than one year.
The weight of informed
economic opinion—inside and outside of government—is that
the current period of contraction will end late this year or
early next, and will not be as deep as in 1973-75.
The current recession was not deliberately sought.
It has
inevitably caused real suffering, which we are acting to mitigate.
The downturn, also inevitably, will result in some reduction in
the rate of inflation.
Recovery must proceed without reigniting
inflationary forces.
As we contemplate recovery over the coming year, economic
policies should therefore be shaped in the interest of longer-run
stability.
The economy needs to perform much more strongly in
the future in the key areas of capital formation, productivity
growth, and international competitiveness, so that employment gains
can be sustained, without generating new waves of inflation.
That will not be accomplished by a hasty, across-the-board tax
cut.
Any tax program to reinforce recovery should be carefully
constructed to be consistent with overall economic objectives.
If our difficulties were simple or of recent origin, the
straightforward countercyclical use of fiscal policy might
meet the needs of the situation.
But our problems are deepseated. They have developed over a long period of time.
Simply
pumping purchasing power into the economy will not raise the
capital-labor ratio, increase the rate of growth of potential
output or improve U.S. competitive ability in foreign markets.

The range of policy options that we should have under active
consideration can best be appreciated by reviewing the general
trend of economic events that forms the background to the current
situation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

4

THE POST WAR ERA, 1945-65
The roots of our current economic problems go back several
decades.
During the 1950*s our economy performed significantly
below its potential.
As a result, in the early 1960’s we were
able to improve our economic performance by exploiting
under­
utilized resources.
We did not have to face difficult trade-offs,
but were able to have more of everything by running the economy
closer to capacity.
Our current problems began after the mid-1960's
when we tried to continue this approach long after we were running
up against economic limits.
Policies of economic stimulus began
to be reflected primarily in rising prices, not in rising output.

In the first twenty years of the postwar era, the U.S. inter­
national payments position was strong and we were able to assist
in the rebuilding of war-ravaged foreign economies.
Thereafter,
we have been faced intermittently with balance of payments difficul­
ties in an intensely competitive international economic environment.
In the earlier period, energy was cheap and readily available.
As a result, U.S. production methods and patterns of consumption
were heavily conditioned by low relative prices of energy.
Subsequently, a difficult and painful adjustment has had to be
made in an environment of energy scarcity.

Relatively Stable Prices.
During the period from 1947 to
1965, the GNP deflator rose at a 2.3 percent annual rate and the
consumer price index at a 1.9 percent annual rate.
There was a
sharp run-up of prices at the time of the Korean War, but relative
stability in the price level was characteristic of much of the
rest of the time.
During the same 1947 to 1965 period, compensation
per hour (wages plus fringes) in the private business sector rose at
an average of 5.1 percent annually, but there was a strong 3.2
percent annual rate of increase in productivity, which held the
rise in unit labor costs to a relatively modest 1.8 percent
annual rate of increase.
This was about in line with the rise
in the price level.
Cost-push factors were no particular problem
and inflation was held fairly well in check.
Longer-term price movements over this period masked some
shorter-term swings.
For example, the period 1955 through 1957
was one of moderately accelerating inflation and relatively high
rates of resource utilization.
The capacity utilization rate in
manufacturing was pushed into the range generally associated with
accelerating rates of inflation.
Considerable concern was expressed
at the time over the threat of inflation.
However, the ensuing
period from 1957-1963 was one of relatively low resource utilization
and decelerating inflation.
The manufacturing utilization rate
dropped to 80 percent and the rate of unemployment averaged 6


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

5

percent during those years.
As a result, the annual rate of
increase in the GNP deflator fell back to 1-1/2 percent, about
one-half of the rate experienced in the 1955-57 period.
The
following two years, 1964 and 1965, saw a transition to a fully
utilized economy, and by the mid-1960's the postwar period of
relatively low rates of inflation was drawing to a close.
Strong Growth in Productivity.
The early postwar decades
featured a return to the fairly steady rates of growth in produc­
tivity which had been characteristic of much of U.S. 19th and
early 20th century economic experience.
Between 1947 and 1965,
output per hour in the private business sector rose at a 3.2
percent annual rate, or at a 2.6 percent annual rate with agricul­
ture excluded.
Real nonresidential fixed investment averaged in
the 9 to 10 percent range as a percentage of GNP throughout the
period.
There was a relatively strong rate of growth in the
stock of capital employed in the private business sector, about
3-1/2 percent per year on a gross basis and more than 4-1/2
percent per year on a net basis (after allowance for capital
replacement).
These rates of growth in the capital stock were
substantially higher than have been achieved in subsequent periods.

The civilian labor force grew at a relatively modest rate by
current standards, only 1.2 percent annually over the years from
1947 to 1965.
The combination of a rapid rate of growth in the
capital stock and a relatively slow rate of growth in the labor
force meant that the capital-labor ratio showed strong gains during
the first two postwar decades, rising at a 3 percent annual rate
on a net basis over the 1947-1965 period.

There is general agreement that the growth in economy-wide
productivity reflects many influences.
However, there has been a
close association in the postwar period between the capital-labor
ratio and the rate of growth in productivity.
The more rapid
application of capital into the productive process means that labor
works on the average with more and better tools of production.
This generally results in improved productive performance.
By the early 1960’s, there was some expression of concern
that the U.S. rate of investment was beginning to lag, particularly
in relation to that of some other major industrial countries.
Through much of the early postwar period, however, the capital
stock had expanded steadily and the rate of growth in productivity
was relatively satisfactory.
Difficulties in this crucial area
only surfaced in unmistakable fashion during the 1970’s.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

Cheap and Readily Available Energy.
In the early postwar
period, domestic energy production was able to supply the needs
of the economy at relatively stable and even falling prices.
Total energy consumption rose at about a 3% annual rate and the
ratio of energy per unit of GNP drifted down slightly.
Gasoline,
heating oil, and electricity prices rose less rapidly than the
consumer price index, thereby encouraging energy consumption
rather than conservation.
Natural gas prices rose faster than
the consumer price index, but on a heat-content basis, natural
gas use rose faster then heating oil throughout the period.
The
average price of electricity dropped and electricity consumption
expanded.

The average fuel costs to the electrical generation industry
can be used as a proxy for industrial energy prices.
Between
1950 and 1965, coal costs decreased 9 percent in current dollars
and fuel oil costs rose only 5 percent.
Natural gas costs on a
heat-content basis were less than oil, and less than, or about the
same as, coal throughout the period.
In the 1950's, natural gas
was still largely an unwanted by-product of oil production and
exploration.
Between 1950 and 1965, crude oil reserves grew from 25.3
billion barrels to 31.4 billion barrels.
Quotas limited the
importation of foreign oils, which undersold domestic production.
Nevertheless, imports of petroleum grew from 550,000 barrels per
day in 1950 to 2.3 million barrels per day in 1965.
Natural gas
reserves grew from 185 trillion cubic feet in 1950 to 287 trillion
cubic feet in 1965, and natural gas distribution systems and
consumption expanded rapidly during the period.
Coal production
was limited only by demand.

In general, the energy situation in the early postwar period
was conducive to rapid economic growth and relatively low energy
prices encouraged its consumption.
Supplies of energy increased
rapidly and there were periods of overproduction and falling
prices.
No serious constraints to growth had emerged by the
raid-1960's, although it was becoming apparent by then that the
long period of cheap and abundant U.S. crude oil resources was
coming to an end.
Strong Dollar Internationally.
In the immediate postwar
period, the dollar reigned supreme.
This was the era of "dollar
shortage" during which foreign countries resorted extensively to
capital and exchange controls to protect their currencies.
Full
currency convertibility was only established for the European
countries in the late 1950's.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

7

The U.S. balance of payments situation was very strong from
1946 to 1949 with a merchandise trade surplus averaging about $7
billion a year and a favorable balance on current account averaging
nearly $4-1/2 billion, even after massive unilateral transfers to
enable other countries to rebuild their devastated economies.
From 1950 to 1959, the merchandise trade surplus averaged only
about $3 billion a year, and the favorable balance on current
account averaged less than $1 billion annually.
Subsequently,
in the 1960 to 1965 period, the U.S. payments position swung back
in the direction of improvement with an average annual trade
surplus of nearly $5-1/2 billion and a favorable balance on
current account of nearly $4-1/2 billion annually.
By the end
of this period, some signs of strain began to emerge, but chiefly
on capital account where low U.S. interest rates and freely
accessible capital markets encouraged a high rate of U.S. lending
to foreign borrowers.
Exchange rate adjustments throughout the first two postwar
decades were on the initiative of foreign countries against the
dollar, which remained at the center of the international financial
system in a fixed relationship with gold.
Following the
reestablishment of currency convertibility in the late 1950's,
the dollar appreciated gradually against other major currencies
until the late 1960's and early 1970's.
By 1965, although some
signs of balance of payments strain were emerging, the dollar
remained the anchor of the world monetary system.

Rising Standard of Living.
Economic expansion yielded
sizable gains during the first twenty years after World War II,
despite interruptions to growth during four recessions.
From 1947
to 1965, real gross national product rose at about a 3.9 percent
annual rate.
Real disposable personal income (personal income
after taxes and corrected for inflation) rose at about a 3.7
percent annual rate, and at nearly a 2 percent annual rate on a
per capita basis.
Median family income in real terras was more
than 60 percent higher by 1965 than it had been in 1947.

The combination of strong economic growth, rapid rates of
increase in the private capital stock and rising productivity
contributed to gains in real income.
Energy supplies were adequate
and a reasonable degree of success in containing inflation kept
the dollar strong at home and abroad.
THE ERA OF TRANSITION, 1965-1976

The transition to more difficult times began after 1965 when
production was expanded for a war effort without cutting back in
other areas.
Indeed, a sizeable—although long overdue—expansion
of domestic social programs was undertaken at about the same time.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

8
In the early 1970’s, new demands were placed on the economy for
environmental quality without making trade-offs to -give up some­
thing else.
There was a continued belief that we could have
more of everything when this was no longer possible.
The oil
boycott and oil price shock added to the difficulties.
Inflation
was the inevitable result.
An ill-fated effort to apply mandatory
wage-price controls in the early 1970’s only worsened the underlying
situation.
Partly as a consequence of domestic inflation, the dollar
weakened in foreign exchange markets and came under speculative
attack.
The dollar was devalued twice in the early 1970’s, and
then was permitted to float, more or less freely, against major
currencies.
In late 1973 the OPEC oil embargo and subsequent
cartel pricing signalled the end of an era of inexpensive energy
and placed this country in a position of dangerous dependence on
uncertain sources of foreign supply.

The 1965-1976 period was a rude awakening to economic reality.
New demands were added onto the economy faster than the capacity
to satisfy them was expanded.
More and more was demanded from
the economy and by the end of the period the capacity to produce
in the future had been eroded substantially.
Deteriorating Price Situation.
The period from 1965 to 1970
was one of excessively high rates of resource utilization.
The
rate of unemployment averaged below 4 percent and demand pressures
were more or less chronic during most of the period.
Inflation
as measured by both the GN? deflator and the consumer price index
averaged over 4 percent, more than double the rate in the first
half of the 1960’s.
During the period from 1970 to 1975, the
after effects of excess demand pressures from the late 1960's
combined with a series of shocks, including the OPEC boost in oil
prices, to produce additional acceleration in inflation.
Inflation
as measured by both the GNP deflator and the consumer price index
averaged about 6-1/2 percent during the 1970-76 period and peaked
in the double-digit range prior to the 1974-75 contraction.

Compensation per hour (wages plus fringes) in the private
business sector moved up to a 7.6 percent rate of increase in the
1965-1976 period, some 2-1/2 percentage points above the 19471965 average rate of increase.
In addition, the rate of growth
in productivity fell off by more than a full percentage point to
a 1.9 percent rate of growth between 1965 and 1976.
As a result,
labor costs per unit of output rose at a 5.6 percent annual rate
in the 1965-1976 period, nearly 4 percentage points above the
increase between 1947-1965.
Cost-push pressures became firmly
imbedded in the wage-price structure by the raid-1970’s, making
the permanent reduction of the rate of inflation a difficult
task.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

9

Declining Rate of Growth in Productivity.
During the 1965-76
period, the strong rate of productivity growth established in the
first two postwar decades began to taper off.
Output per hour in
the private business sector grew at a 1.9 percent annual rate, or
1.6 percent with agriculture excluded.
This represented a signifi
cant decline from the 3.2 percent, or 2.6 percent rate with
agriculture excluded, recorded between 1947 and 1965.

Growth in the civilian labor force picked up speed, rising
2.2 percent annually in the 1965-1976 period in contrast to 1.2
percent between 1947 and 1965.
Growth in the stock of private
business capital was relatively well maintained, although showing
some retardation in growth on a net basis and after exclusion of
pollution abatement expenditures.
As a result primarily of the
more rapid rate of growth in the labor force, the capital-labor
ratio grew much more slowly in the 1965-1976 period than it had
in the first two postwar decades.

It is not possible to identify the exact point at which the
U.S. rate of productivity growth began to decline.
Some of the
slowdown may have arisen gradually over time.
Some may have
been occasioned by the sharp rise in energy prices after 1973.
It is clear that the rate of growth in productivity had slowed
drastically by the close of the 1965-1976 period.

Energy Shock.
In 1973, events in international oil markets,
in particular the oil embargo, pushed world oil prices far above
those for domestic controlled oil.
The resulting shock to the
U.S. was substantial since imports and consumption of oil had
been rising rapidly while domestic production of oil and gas had
been declining after 1970.
From 1965 to 1973, total U.S. energy consumption grew at a
4.4 percent annual rate, compared with a 3.1 percent annual rate
during the previous fifteen years.
The energy to GNP ratio rose
to a peak by 1970.
Motor gasoline consumption was stimulated by
the completion of thousands of miles of interstate highways,
increased motor car ownership, and rising personal income.

Supply problems began to appear in the energy field in the
early 1970’s.
The use of coal was inhibited by environmental
regulations and other factors.
Natural gas deliveries could not
keep up with demand and reserves began to top out in 1972.
Domestic crude oil production peaked in 1970 and reserves would
have fallen appreciably by 1975 except for the discovery of the
Alaskan North Slope fields.
Domestic oil production could no
longer expand to meet demand and imports filled the gap.
Imports
increased from 2.3 million barrels per day in 1965 to 6 million
barrels by 1973 and then dropped slightly by 1975.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

10
The OPEC oil embargo hit with particular force because of
the growing dependence of the U.S. economy on oil imports.
Imported oil prices rose from $2.14 per barrel in 1966 to
$3.37 per barrel in 1973.
Following the embargo in the winter of
1973-74, imported oil shot up to $11.45 per barrel in 1975.
Gasoline prices rose 83 percent and heating oil prices by
144 percent in the 1965-1975 period, compared to a 71 percent
rise in the consumer price index.
Most of the oil price increases
were in the last two years of the period when gasoline prices
increased by 27 percent and heating oil prices by 71 percent.
Natural gas prices increased by 66 percent between 1965 and 1975,
with a 33 percent increase between 1973 and 1975.

Industrial energy prices rose much faster than consumer prices
during the 1965-1975 period.
o

Coal prices advanced 254 percent, with a 106 percent increase
between 1973 and 1975.

o

Natural gas prices for industrial use increased 201
percent, with a 113 percent increase between 1973 and
1975.

o

Fuel oil prices advanced 509 percent, with a 195 percent
jump between 1973 and 1975.

A Weakening Dollar.
The 1965-1975 period was one of inten­
sifying pressure on the U.S. dollar.
At the beginning of the period,
the U.S. was running a surplus of about $5 billion both on merchandise
trade and on current account.
By the early 1970's, both of these
surpluses had been wiped out and the international competitive
position of the dollar was severely impaired.
The international
financial system was fundamentally changed in August 1971 when
the United States announced suspension of the convertibility
into gold of dollars held by foreign monetary authorities.
Following this action, major exchange rate alignments, coupled
with devaluation of the dollar in terms of gold, were negotiated
in December 1971 and February 1973.
Subsequently, the international
monetary system moved to a regime of managed floating.
Between 1969 and 1974, the U.S. dollar depreciated about 16
percent on a trade weighted basis against the currencies of other
major industrial nations.
Cyclical improvement in the U.S.
balance of payments and other factors led to some temporary
strengthening of the dollar and by 1976 the trade weighted depreciation
was about 10 percent relative to the base rates of May 1970.
By
the end of the 1965-75 period, the U.S. trade account had moved


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

11
back into a $9.billion surplus and the current account was in
surplus by $18 billion. Exchange rate adjustments and temporary
cyclical factors were largely responsible for the improvement.
However, the longer run balance of payments outlook was clouded
by the existence of a rapidly rising bill for oil imports.

Standard of Living Continues to Rise.
Despite the sharp
adjustments occurring after the mid-1960's, standards of living
continued to rise.
In the 1965-1976 period, real GNP rose at a
2.9 percent annual rate, a little below the postwar average rate
of increase.
Real disposable income rose at a 3.5 percent annual
rate and at about a 2.5 percent annual rate on a per-capita basis.
However, constraints on growth were much more evident at the end
of the period than at the beginning, and the rate of inflation had
accelerated.
A sharp decline was developing in the rate of growth
in productivity which would limit the potential for future gains.
RECENT ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE, 1976-1980
By the last half of the 1970’s, the Nation faced a watershed
in its economic history.
The world economy was changing at a
revolutionary pace.
The adverse trends which had developed with
respect to inflation, productivity growth, and international
competitiveness moved to center stage in the Nation’s discussions
of economic policy.
The Nation responded to these challenges by
moving to break important deadlocks in a number of important areas
of economic management.
This process has involved painful choices.
Changing the
Nation's course on matters of such fundamental economic importance
as energy policy and control of federal spending could not be
accomplished overnight or without intensive debate.
We have
not succeeded completely on every front: there remains a significant
agenda of unfinished business.
But in many key areas of economic
policy, a new strategic consensus has been forged, laying the
basis for improving our basic economic performance over the next
decade.
Some of the key areas in which progress has been made include:

o Fiscal prudence:
The Administration and Congress have
made the containment of domestic spending growth a major
priority of economic policy.
Working together, we have
strengthened budget procedures and discipline and provided
for rigorous annual review of "off budget" items through
the new Credit Budget.
Real growth in non-defense spending
has been dramatically reduced from the high rates registered
over the previous decade.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

12

o Domestic monetary policy:
The Federal Reserve 3oard
has improved its control over the long-term growth of
monetary aggregates as a means for bringing down the
inflation rate.
o Wage-price policy:
The Administration has disavowed
mandatory controls and has instead developed a structure
of voluntary wage-price standards.
Econometric tests
indicate that the inflation rate is now 1 to 1.5 percentage
points lower than it would have been without the program.
o Energy policy:
Programs for implementing the phase-out .
of price controls on crude oil and new natural gas are now in
place.
Massive new initiatives have been adopted to develop
alternate energy sources and spur conservation of oil.
The
new Synthetic Fuel Corporation will help create a huge, new
industry of energy supply, drawing upon the Nation's
abundant coal and shale oil resources.
o Deregulation:
Regulations have been substantially reduced
with respect to airlines, trucking and financial institutions.
Large portions of the U.S. economy have been returned to the
discipline and opportunities of competitive market forces.

While considerable progress has been made, in many areas
continuing efforts will be required over a number of years.
Future
policies must place great stress on controlling inflation and
stimulating productivity.
In reviewing the record of recent
years, it is important to recognize accomplishments, but even
more important the need for continued progress.
Real Growth.
Substantial gains have been made in recent
years in terras of real growth.
From the trough quarter of
economic activity early in 1975 through the first quarter of 1979,
real GNP grew at an annual rate of 5.1 percent.
From the end of
1976 through the first quarter of 1979, that growth rate was 4.8%.
In the next four quarters, real growth slowed to about a 1 percent
annual rate, and in the second quarter of this year real growth
declined sharply—at an 9.1 percent annual rate according to
the preliminary estimates released recently.
However, even
after this decline, real GNP is about 20 percent above the early
1975 low.
2

This is a strong performance by past standards, but it obviously
reflects cyclical gains to a considerable extent.
Real growth
since the last cyclical peak in the fourth quarter of 1973 has
been about 2-1/2 percent annual rate.
This corresponds more
closely to estimates of the economy's current trend rate of potential


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

13

economic growth.
Potential growth has been estimated by CEA
as having been about 3 percent between 1973 and 1978 and likely
to fall to a 2-1/2 percent annual rate between 1979 and 1982.
This stands in marked contrast to an annual trend rate in potential
of about 4-1/2 percent from 1947 to 1953, and about 3-1/2 percent
from 1953 to the early 1970's.
Aside from cyclical movements,
the real progress of the economy is inevitably limited to its
trend potential.

Tax cuts designed simply for fiscal stimulus do little to
enhance the economy's potential to produce goods and services.
Attention needs to be directed toward tax policies to promote
long-term growth potential, i.e., to raise the economy's ability to
produce goods and services.
The lesson of the recent expansion
is that the economy encounters real barriers to expansion, reflected
in an acceleration of inflation, long before unemployment can be
reduced to desirable levels.
Efforts should therefore be directed
at the supply side of the economy, including selective programs
to attack structural unemployment.
Productivity and Investment.
Productivity fell off sharply
in the 1973-75 recession, and then made a strong cyclical recovery
in 1975 and 1976.
During 1977 and 1978 productivity increased by
an average of only 1 percent per year.
Over the past year, pro­
ductivity has actually declined by about 1-1/2 percent.
During
the early stages of a recovery, growth in output tends to exceed
increases in labor input by wide margins, but productivity gains
tend to slow rather markedly as the expansion ages.
The more
disturbing feature of productivity experience is the apparent
lower trend since the late 1960's.
3etween 1948 and 1968, pro­
ductivity in the private nonfarm business sector of the economy
rose 2.6% per year; between 1968 and 1973 that growth slowed to
1.7% per year; and during the 1973 to early 1980 period growth
slowed still further to less than 1/2 of one percent.
The causes of the apparent secular decline in productivity
are still the subject of academic inquiry and difference of
opinion.
Some of the more important causes of the slower trend
growth in productivity that have been advanced are:
o

o

Demographic factors have been important since the raid-1960's,
as the proportion of new, young and inexperienced workers
in the labor force increased.
•
An increasing proportion of capital investment has been
diverted in recent years to meeting government regulations
directed at improving the health and safety of workers
and the environment.
Labor resources have also been
diverted.
While these are essential efforts they do not
contribute directly to measured output in productivity.
These programs will continue but are unlikely to increase
at the rates of the recent past.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

14

o

A variety of other factors— such as the increase in
energy prices and a decline in worker motivation—have also
frequently been cited as adverse influences.

o

In the opinion of many observers, the most important
single factor has been a dramatic slowdown in the rate
of growth of the capital-labor ratio.
More capital per
worker generally contributes to higher productivity, and
the sharp fall in that ratio is a matter of real concern.
In the 1976-79 period, the ratio of the capital stock to
the civilian labor force edged up only slightly on a
gross basis and actually fell on a net basis.
This
stands in marked contrast to average gains in the net
capital-labor ratio of 3 percent annually from 1945 to
1965 and nearly 2 percent annually from 1965 to 1976.

It must be emphasized that business fixed investment has made
a strong cyclical recovery in recent years.
The problem is to
assure that these are sufficient incentives to boost the amount
of capital investment in the permanent fashion that is required
to raise productivity and the trend rate of potential growth.
That should be one of the major objectives of tax and other
policies over the years ahead.
Employment.
Growth in employment has been a major achievement
of the Carter Administration.
Since late 1976, civilian employment
has increased by nearly 11 million persons, even after allowance
for the cyclical employment declines of recent months.
The ratio
of employment to working age population has reached record levels,
although receding from its peak in recent months.
On the other
hand, the rate of unemployment has remained higher than desirable,
reaching a low for the expansion in the 5-1/2 to 6 percent range,
before rising rapidly in recent months.
The rise in the unemployment
rate in the current contraction has been heavily concentrated among
blue collar jobs which are predominantly held by adult men.
This
cyclical rise in the unemployment rate will be reduced when the
economy turns up again.
However, more remains to be done in
combatting structural unemployment if the average level of unemploy­
ment over the cycle is to be reduced to more acceptable levels.
The largest employment gains have been made by women and minority
groups.
Employment of adult women has increased by nearly 16 percent
since late 1976, compared to about 5-1/2 percent for adult men.
Employment of blacks and other minority groups has increased by 12
percent compared to a 9 percent rise for all groups.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

15

Employment gains are an important measure of the performance
of the economy.
However, it is also crucial that productivity
advance rapidly so that increased employment will mean rising
standards of living.
Energy.
Considerable progress has been made in reducing the
Nation's reliance on insecure sources of foreign oil.
Programs now
in place should yield increasing returns in the period ahead.
Already some tangible signs of progress can be seen.
Between 1975
and 1979, total energy consumption grew at a 2.4% annual rate,
slower than at any time during the previous 25 years.
The energy/GNP
ratio dropped steadily during the 1975-1979 period, and indications
are that the ratio will drop further in 1980.
Gasoline consumption
peaked in 1978 at 7.4 million barrels per day and dropped to 7.0
million in 1979.
In 1980, gasoline consumption could drop to
about 6-1/2 million barrels per day if present trends continue.

Domestic energy supply has increased over the period.
Crude
oil production edged up to 8.53 million barrels per day from 8.38
million barrels per day in 1975.
Much of the increase was due to
the exploration of the Alaskan North Slope fields beginning in 1977.
Oil production in 1980 is expected to increase due to more Alaskan
production and in response to the phasing out of crude oil price
controls.
Natural gas production stayed relatively flat during the
1975-1979 period rather than continuing the decreases exhibited
in the preceding years.
Production in 1979 exceeded 1978 levels.
Coal is making a comeback, with 1979 production 18 percent above
1975, and 1980 production running well above 1979 to this point.

The heavy impact of rising oil prices on the domestic economy
and U.S. balance of payments has continued throughout the period.
The price of imported oil (f.a.s.) rose by 63 percent from $11.45
per barrel in 1975 to $18.67 per barrel in 1979.
The price of
imported oil in 1980 will be $31.50 to $32 per barrel or about 70
percent higher than in 1979.
Net oil imports rose from 5.9
million barrels per day in 1975 to 7.9 million barrels per day
in 1979, with a peak of 8.6 million barrels per day in 1977.
So
far this year net imports are about 14 percent below the levels
of last year.
In general, the trends toward slower growth in
energy consumption, increased domestic production, and reduced
imports are all in the right direction.

Recent experience demonstrates that higher energy prices
significantly reduce energy demand.
There is no realistic
alternative to reliance on the price system to insure t;hat scarce
energy resources are employed most efficiently, and that adequate
incentives are offered for future domestic energy production and
conservation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

16

Inflation.
The raost discouraging feature of recent economic
performance was the acceleration of inflation in the late stages
of the current expansion.
The worst of the inflationary fever
has now been broken, by the policy measures taken at mid-March
and by the onset of recession.
The task that lies ahead is to
insure that the next period of economic expansion does not simply
ratchet the rate of inflation to still higher levels, but instead
that recent progress can be continued in a methodical trend toward
genuine price stability.

Between 1976 and 1979 on the basis of annual averages, the
GNP deflator rose at a 7.4 percent annual rate and the consumer
price index at an 8.4 percent annual rate.
These compare with
5-1/2 percent annual rates of increase in the 1965 to 1976 period.
More recently, rates of inflation have reached even higher levels,
before turning down.
Over the past six months or so, consumer
prices have risen at about a 15 percent annual rate, producer
prices at about a 12-1/2 percent annual rate, and the GNP deflator
at about 10.
As a result of recent inflationary pressures and workers’
attempt to maintain real incomes, compensation per hour (wages
plus fringes) has been boosted to the 9 to 10 percent range.
Because productivity growth has been negative, unit labor costs
have been rising in the 11 to 12 percent range for the past year
and a half.

Those who favor an across-the-board tax reduction to stimulate
the economy should ponder the implications in terras of inflation.
Over the past 15 years, every period of economic expansion has
driven the rate of inflation to new heights at the top of the
cycle.
The ensuing periods of contraction have temporarily
lowered the rate of inflation, but each time the rate of inflation
at the trough has been higher than before.
The International Position of the Dollar.
A major objective
of the Administration's international monetary policy has been
the maintenance of global confidence in a sound and stable dollar.
The program to strengthen the dollar, initiated by President Carter
in November 1978, represented a watershed in the U.S. exchange market
policy.
This program combined domestic measures to improve the
U.S. balance of payments—by curbing inflation and reducing
dependence on imported oil—with more active intervention in the
foreign exchange market to maintain orderly conditions.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

17

The November 1978 program demonstrated a clear-cut U.S.
commitment to a sound dollar and stability in exchange markets.
Since that program, the dollar has increased in value on average
in terms of other major currencies.
The U.S. balance of payments
has, moreover, scored major gains, despite large increases in
oil prices and consequently in oil import costs.

It must be recognized, however, that the strength of the
dollar depends, in the last analysis, upon our demonstrated
ability to keep the domestic economy strong and to reverse the
inflationary trend of the past 15 years.
CURRENT ECONOMIC SITUATION AND THE BUDGET REVISIONS

Change in Economic Assumptions.
At the turn of the year when
the January Budget estimates were being completed, the economy was
continuing to show far more strength than most economists had
expected.
In fact, some additional momentum appeared to develop late
in 1979. A mild recession was generally expected, based on the
downturn already underway in housing and the prospect that consumers
would slow their rate of spending.
The timing of a recession
was uncertain, however, and few signs of an imminent downturn were,
in evidence.
Retail sales, production and employment all rose in
January.
The economic climate shifted rapidly through early March.
The shift was triggered by a number of factors.
The long projected
recession failed to materialize.
As evidence began to build that
the first quarter would show positive real growth and January
retail sales turned in an especially strong showing, some economic
and financial market participants began to question whether a reces­
sion was really in prospect.
Because of heightened international
tensions, financial markets began to anticipate an increased
defense effort, in consequence much larger budget deficits,
more inflation, and higher interest rates.
There was an upsurge
of speculative activity in commodity markets which was both a
cause and a result of shifting anticipations as to the future
course of inflation.
Rapidly rising energy prices plus rising
mortgage interest rates helped cause the CPI to shoot up by 1.4%
(18% annual rate) in each of the first three months of the year.

These developments combined to generate a dramatic shift in
inflationary expectations.
Businesses began to post price increases
in anticipation of higher rates of inflation and the fear that wageprice controls would be imposed.
Excluding food and energy, producer
prices jumped at a 15% annual rate in the first three months of
the year at the finished goods level and a 17% rate for semi-finished
goods.
Interest rates began to shoot upward.
Yields on commercial
paper, which had averaged about 13% in December, were well above
16% in early March.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

18

The intensified anti-inflation package announced on March 14
was designed to reverse these developments.
Its principal components
were increased fiscal discipline, including a reduction of some
$17 billion from FY-1981 planned outlays, a program of credit
restraint, and structural reforms directed at improving the
longer-term performance of the economy.
The package also included
proposals in the energy area and steps to strengthen the wage-price
guideline program.
The program, along with actions taken by the Federal Reserve,
reversed the inflationary psychology.
Interest rates continued
to rise into early April, but then declined dramatically.
Commercial
paper rates moved above 17-1/2% in early April, but subsequently
fell to the 8% range.
By early June, commitment rates for conventional
home mortgages had fallen 300 basis points from the 16-1/2% of
early April to 13-1/2%.
The Treasury bill rate temporarily fell
below 7 percent in contrast to an early peak near 16 percent.
From its peak of 20 percent, the prime rate has fallen back near
11 percent.
These interest rate declines are laying the
foundation for the recovery of the economy.

Meanwhile, the greater than expected strength in activity
early in the year led most economists to mark up their projections
of real activity, at least for 1980.
However, as figures became
available for March, April, and May, it became evident that demand
and production had been dropping rapidly.
New car sales plunged
(from a 10.8 million annual rate in the first quarter to a 7.7
million rate in the second), total retail sales took a record
drop, industrial production fell by 4-1/2% between February and
May, and orders placed with manufacturers of durable goods plummeted
by 17% from January to May.

Again, forecasts for 1980 were revised to incorporate these
new realities.
The tabulation below shows the shifting consensus
forecast of about 40 top private business economists.*

Forecasted 1980 Changes in Real Gross National Product
•

Forecast date
January
March
July

4th to 4th
year to year
(---------------- percent--------------------- )
-1.0
-1.0
-0.4
+0.1
-1.4
-3.3

*Blue Chip Economic Indicators, Capital Publications Inc.,
various issues.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

19

The economic path underlying the Mid-Session Review of the
3udget registers the downturn in activity that is now underway and
parallels the change in assessment of near-terra economic events
that has taken place among private economists.
Real GNP is now
projected to decline by 3.1% between the fourth quarter of 1979
and the fourth quarter of 1980, with the steepest part of that
decline in the second quarter of this year.
The economy is
expected to move downward still further in the second half, but
at a more moderate rate, with the slide perhaps bottoming out
late in the year.
t
The projected course of the economy would carry the unemployment
rate up to the 8.5% range by the turn of the year, and the very
moderate recovery of real GNP and employment thereafter would do
little to bring the unemployment rate down over 1981.
As measured
by the GNP deflator, inflation is projected to moderate from 10.1%
for this year to 9.7% in 1981, both measured fourth quarter to
fourth quarter.

It is important to emphasize the great uncertainty associated
with all of these projections.
Throughout this year, economic
forecasts from virtually all sources have undergone major revisions
on nearly a monthly basis.
Nevertheless, it is clear that the projected course of economic
performance is not satisfactory.
As the recovery develops, policy
steps to improve the economy’s performance, both in 1981 and for
the longer term, may well be appropriate.
The Administration
is reviewing the various possibilities and welcomes the opportunity
to consult with the Congress about them.
However, the steps need not and should not be taken in haste.
The economy’s structural problems require carefully designed
structural answers.

Turning to the nearer term, we expect that the natural forces
of recovery will begin to manifest 'themselves.

The consensus expectation of economists, inside and outside
of government, is that the upturn will occur late this year or
early next.
This would conform in a rough way to the postwar
cyclical pattern.
The average duration of periods of contraction
in the six previous postwar recessions has been 11 months, although
1973-75 was longer, and the peak of the recent expansion has now
been dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research as having
occurred in January 1980.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

20

A recent survey* of 40 private economists at major banks,
corporations, and private research organizations sees successively
smaller declines in real GNP during the third and fourth quarters
of this year and a return to positive growth early next year.
This is the generally expected pattern.
It may not occur exactly
as predicted.
Economic forecasting is a very imperfect art.
The
important poi-nt is that the official forecast accords reasonably
with the consensus of private forecasts and constitutes a realistic
appraisal of the near-term outlook.

Recent readings on the economy suggest that the decline is
still continuing, but not at the accelerated pace of the early
part of the second quarter.
The economy is still moving downward,
the third quarter will almost certainly register another decline
in real GNP.
However, there are signs that the rate of decline
has slowed markedly.
— Retail sales scored a 1.5% increase in June.
Excluding
autos, sales rose slightly more than inflation.

— New car sales in early July bounced up from their
depressed second-quarter, pace (though we should
not attach too much significance to this rise until
confirmed by additional data).

— Seasonally adjusted initial claims for insured unemployment
have fallen back in early July from their earlier peaks.
— Housing starts and permits rose strongly in June, reversing
the trend of earlier months.
Housing activity appears to
be benefiting already from the interest rate declines
in recent months.
— Businesses have been making a determined effort to keep
inventories under control.
The decline in business
inventory holdings in May indicates some success in
these efforts, lean inventory positions would imply that
when demand turns up, production would shortly follow.

— Demands for short-term business credit show signs
of renewed strength.

*Blue Chip Economic Indicators, Capital Publications Inc.,
July 10, 1980, Vol. 5, No. 7, esp. p. 3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

21
The Revised Budget Estimates.
The Mid-Session Review shows
substantial changes in budget estimates.
The basic numbers are
presented in the table below.

Receipts
Outlays
Deficit,
current
estimate
Budget
authority

BUDGET TOTALS '
(in billions of dollars)
1979
_______ 1980 Estimate
Actual
Jan.
March
July

19 81 Estimate
Jan.
March
July

465.9
493.7

523.8
563.6

532.4
568.9

517.9
578.8

600.0
615.8

628.0
611.5

604.0
633.8

-27.7

-39.8

-36.5

-60.9

-15.8

16.5

-29.8

556.7

654.0

665.8

653.7

696.1

691.3

707.2

The 1980 deficit is now estimated to be $60.9 billion, up from
$36.5 billion in March.
Outlays are currently estimated at
$578.8 billion and receipts at $517.9 billion.
The current
estimate for 1981 is for a deficit of $29.8 billion, rather than
the $16.5 billion surplus estimated in March.
Outlays are currently
estimated at $633.8 billion and receipts at $604.0 billion.
Both the increase in the 1980 deficit and the shift from surplus
to deficit in 1981 are mainly the result of changes in the economic
situation, though the estimates also reflect legislative events,
higher spending on defense and emergency relief programs, and
some minor technical changes.

The 1980 deficit is now estimated to be $24.4 billion
higher than in March.
Of this amount, about two-thirds, or
$16.6 billion is due to the change in economic conditions.
Receipts are down nearly $11 billion and outlays up $7 billion
for this reason alone.
Policy changes and Congressional action
have reduced receipts by $4 billion in 1980 and $8.4 billion in
1981, and are partially offset by technical re-estimates and
other factors.
In addition to the effect of changed economic
conditions, outlays are running somewhat higher because of defense
outlays and increases for disaster relief, alien assistance, and
other unavoidable events.

The larger budget deficits do not reflect an upsurge in
discretionary federal spending.
Congressional responses to the
President's proposal for spending restraint have been constructive.
While there are some differences in program priorities, the
Congressional budget efforts to this point are generally consistent
with the policy of fiscal stringency proposed by the President.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

22
Financing the Deficit.
Policy steps over the next 13 months
could of course alter the economic and budgetary projections
released this week.
We have, however, analyzed the financing
requirements implicit in these projections.

The Treasury’s FY 1980 and FY 1981 financing requirements,
while increased from the levels projected in mid-March, are not
expected to strain the credit markets.
Private demands for
credit will likely be more than correspondingly reduced as a
result of continued weakness in economic activity for the remainder
of 1980.
Even with the Treasury's increased borrowing in the months
ahead, the ratio of public holdings of Treasury securities to GNP
is not likely to rise much above the current level of about 26
percent.
In FY 1976, when a budget deficit of over $66 billion
was financed, this ratio rose to nearly 30 percent.

Looking ahead to FY 1981, our borrowing needs will probably
be heaviest in the first two quarters of the fiscal year.
The
use of a wide variety of borrowing options currently available
to the Treasury should minimize any undesirable impact of this
increased financing.

The recovery in the economy is expected to begin late .this
year or early in 1981, but in the absence of other actions the
upturn is projected to be relatively slow.
Private credit demands
are typically slow to rise in the initial stages of an upturn,
and the expected moderation in the rate of recovery may further
hold down private borrowing.
Financing policy is not greatly challenged when the automatic
stabilizers in the economy tend to result in deficits in periods
of slack economic activity.
But the string of deficits experienced
in the postwar period in boom years as well as in periods of
slack, has imposed an added burden on the performance of the
economy and its financial markets.
If the monetary authorities
finance such untimely deficits, excessive growth of credit is
generated, and an inflationary atmosphere is created.
If, on
the other hand, the monetary authorities decline to make credit
available to finance the deficit, the available pool of savings
and capital formation and productivity suffer.
The solution must
be a move toward budget balance over the course of the cycle.
Sizable surpluses in periods of prosperity may well be desirable,
particularly if tax and other policies are successful in promoting
more robust private investment performance.
We are making progress
toward such a long-term fiscal policy, but continuing efforts are
required.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

23
TAX POLICY AND AN APPROPRIATE FISCAL STRATEGY
In turning now to the issue of appropriate fiscal policy
under present circumstances, several basic considerations should
be kept in mind.

First, Congress has been making progress in restraining the
rate of growth in expenditures.
This basic fiscal discipline
must be maintained.
Too often in the past, expenditure control
has been a short-term enterprise which was soon abandoned.
Now
that the painful decisions have been made, we should follow
through in a clear demonstration that a new fiscal course is
being followed.
Failure to do so runs the risk of dissipating
all the gains that have been made to this point.
Domestic financial
markets are functioning smoothly at home and the dollar is showing
encouraging stability abroad.
Both domestic and international
financial stability require that we continue to pursue a responsible
fiscal course.
Second, it is difficult to predict the exact course that
the economy will follow.
Interest rates have fallen much more
sharply than most observers expected.
This could induce an
earlier upturn in credit sensitive sectors of the economy.
If
the economy were to rebound more quickly than expected, fiscally
stimulatory actions might prejudice our progress in bringing down
inflation.
The Venice Economic Summit reinforced our view that relaxation
of demand management policy in the major world economies would
be premature.
The Venice communique clearly stated that "the
reduction of inflation is our immediate top priority... Determined
fiscal and monetary restraint is required to break inflationary
expectations."
Global inflation rates are still unacceptably
high and we have not yet succeeded in reducing inflationary
expectations.
Too early a retreat from restraint, might re-ignite
inflationary expectations and erase the hard-won gains we have
just begun to make.

Third, the kind of future tax program that should be developed,
with full consultation between the Administration and the Congress,
will necessarily involve some complex issues and controversial
decisions.
There are enough choices and technical problems in
depreciation reform alone to consume more legislative time than is
now remaining before scheduled adjournment.
Even proposals that
start with apparently simple formulas would not be easy to enact
into law, especially in a politically-charged environment.
The
only program that is simple enough — slashing rates according
to a formula — would be counterproductive.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

24

Fourth, it would be unwise to .try to complete a large tax
cut program in this session of Congress.
The effort to do so
would be caught up in all of the political cross-currents of an
election year.
It would be subject to the full weight of
pressure from every faction that has an interest in special
relief.
If any agreement were to emerge from this environment,
it would very likely be a melange of special interest provisions
— just the opposite of what is needed.

A tax program may well be appropriate for next year.
Anticipating this possibility, now is a good time to-set out
criteria and to begin to consider the outlines of such a
program.

Criteria for a tax reduction program
Accord with fiscal discipline and spending restraint.
A
tax program should be considered in the context of the restraint
demonstrated on the spending side.
Any tax reduction agenda
must consider the revenue effects for at least five years, not
just for the first year.
This budget planning should be based
on reasonable projections for expenditures and economic
conditions, including realistic economic responses to any tax
changes.
They should not be based on hopes, wishes, or magic
formulas.

Combat inflation.
An anti-inflation tax program should
have at least two main attributes.
First, in the short run it
should not create excessive additional demand pressures or
rekindle inflationary expectations.
Second, it should help
encourage investment and, thereby, improve productivity and
reduce unit labor costs.
If, at the same time, the program
could directly contribute to cost reduction, that would be an
added plus.

Maintain confidence in financial and foreign exchange
market.In recent months, the program of fiscal restraint has
gone a long way to reassure investors at home and abroad that
the long upward trend of inflation has been broken.
It is
important that any major fiscal program be perceived as
one that maintains a steady course.
Deliberate development of a
program aimed at long-run objectives can reinforce this
perception.
In contrast, an abrupt shift toward stimulus could
disturb financial and currency markets, complicating the
recovery.
Focus on improving productivity growth and international
competitiveness.
We must give more attention to the supply side
of the economy.
The realization of our public and private goals
— a strong defense, expanding employment, growth in real income


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

25

and opportunity, energy independence, and improved international
accounts — depends on increasing the rate of investment to
modernize the capital stock and increase capital per worker.
This requires that tax incentives be concentrated on capital
expansion, not dissipated in special interest provisions that
only move capital from place to place.
Promote the most effective use of available resources.
It
is not enough to expand the size of the capital stock and
increase jobs.
The jobs and capital should go where they will
have the highest payoff.
This is the least costly way to
achieve real economic expansion.
The best judge of the prospective payoff is not the
government; it is private markets.
Reducing taxes where they
interfere the most and avoiding the creation of new tax dis­
tortions are the keys to the effective allocation of jobs and
capital.

Preserve the progressivity of the tax structure.
Inflation
and reduced energy*supplies have further restricted the choices
for families with modest incomes.
The payroll tax also takes a
disproportionate share from wage earning families of low and
moderate income.
Although "bracket creep" has occurred for
every class, those with lower incomes are least able to absorb
or avoid the higher rates.
Any plan for reducing individual tax
rates must carefully consider the effects on the progressivity
of the system.
Reflect close consultation with Congress.
The criteria
offered here indicate priorities and suggest an agenda, but
there are large choices within them concerning methods and
degrees of emphasis.
The Administration wishes to work out
these choices in close consultation with this and other
committees and with individual members of Congress.
Your
knowledge and experience are vital to the process of
constructing an effective program.

MAJOR TAX POLICY CHOICES

The principal objectives of economic policy and the current
structure' of the tax system indicate that any future tax changes
should be pointed in two major directions.
The first would be
to reduce the burden of taxes on households and on labor costs.
The second would be to provide incentives for productive
business investment.
A strong case can be made for a number of
tax policy.options.
Putting a tax program together, however,
involves choice.
Revenue simply is not available to make all
the changes everyone would like.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

26

Reducing the tax burden on labor income
The taxation of wage earners is mainly determined by the
structure of individual income tax rates and the rate of payroll
taxes for social security.
The purpose of the graduated rate
structure in the income tax is to apportion the tax burden
equitably among households of differing means.
A by-product of
this structure is automatic tax increases resulting from
year-to-year increases in money incomes.
This tendency — often
called "bracket creep" — has led Congress to make periodic
adjustments, especially in periods of inflation.

Over the period from 1969 to 1979 legislated adjustments to
the rate schedule produced nearly the same effect as indexing
for middle-income families.
A family of four of. median income
($24,400 at 1980 levels) would have paid income tax of 10.0
percent in 1969 and 10.4 percent in 1979, if its income had just
kept pace with inflation over those years.
However, rapidly
increasing money wages continue and more households have begun
to encounter the steeper portions of the rate schedule that was
enacted in 1978.
Consequently, the same family of median income
will pay 11.4 percent in federal personal income taxes for 1980
and 12.1 percent in 1981.
Increasing individual tax rates and, particularly, the
higher rates that apply to any additions to family income are
felt especially by families with two wage earners.
Consid­
eration should be given to the marriage penalty in connection
with individual rate adjustment.

The other main element in the taxation of labor income —
the payroll tax — has been increased steadily to provide
funding for increasing real benefit levels to a growing popu­
lation of social security recipients.
In combination, the
income and payroll taxes add substantially to the differential
between the cost of labor to businesses, on the one hand, and
the after-tax pay of workers, on the other.
At current rates of
income and payroll taxes, an employer must pay $1.52 in wages
and payroll tax to add $1.00 to the after-tax pay of an employee
in a median income family.
This represents a combined marginal
tax rate on labor income of 34.1 percent.

Scheduled increases in the payroll taxes will increase
these marginal rates of tax by nearly a percentage point in
1981, considering the increases for both employer and employee.
In seeking equitable ways to reduce the taxation of labor


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

27

income, attention should be given to the added burden on labor
costs from payroll tax increases and also to the funding needs
of the Social Security system.
One approach to this problem is the proposal put forward by
Congressman Gephardt.
Under this plan, individuals and
businessmen would be permitted an income tax credit for a
portion of social security taxes paid.
The credit could be
refunded to employers and employees who owe no income tax
liability.
This method would offset the increase in payroll
taxes without interfering with funding for the social security
system.
Other approaches to the increasing burden on wages also
deserve exploration.
A result similar to the Gephardt plan may
be attained by matching individual ' income tax cuts to the
payroll tax increases, for example.
However, direct reduction
of the payroll tax should not be considered except in the
context of a comprehensive analysis of trust fund financing
issues.

Tax treatment of saving

Taxation of income from ownership of property has also
generally been increasing.
This is partly because the average
individual saver who receives interest, dividend, rental or
business income has also moved up into higher income tax
brackets.
Another reason is that inflation leads to over­
statement of business profits.
But these increases are by no
means uniform.
The many sources of property income are subject
to a great variety of tax treatments.
For example, income from
corporate equity may be fully subject to corporate taxes and
also subject to individual taxes when distributed as dividends
to shareholders.
At the other extreme, the first $400 of
interest income, interest from municipal bonds, earnings on
individual retirement accounts, and vested pension funds are all
effectively tax exempt.
Still other kinds of property income,
such as from real estate, minerals, and appreciation of
corporate stock are only partially subject to tax.
While many of the savings incentive provisions adopted
piecemeal over the years may have been intended to increase
availability of capital, some are>extremely inefficient and may
even be counterproductive.
The ability of taxpayers to switch
their assets from one form
to another, or to borrow in order to
invest in a tax-preferred asset, has reduced, if not eliminated,
the ability of many of these provisions to increase overall
savings.
Revenues lost because of tax preferences for certain
types of income require increases in rates of taxation on all
taxable income.
The approach of providing "saving incentives"


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

28

to certain narrowly defined uses of funds or special kinds of
investments should be rejected in favor of more direct, broad
based and efficient incentives for investment.
Another important result of the uneven treatment of pro­
perty income is to divert saving and investment away from the
relatively high-taxed industrial sector.
Industrial corpora­
tions and public utilities are those most likely to bear the
full corporate income tax and produce taxable dividends.
They
also are hardest hit by the erosion of depreciation allowances
resulting from inflation.
This causes depreciation--a major
cost of using capital goods—to be understated and inflates
taxable profits.
Depreciation reform
Among choices for encouraging capital investment and
raising productivity, acceleration of depreciation allowances
offers the greatest potential for success.
In general, such a
provision would reduce the tax bite on the return to successful
investment and also enable higher returns to be paid to direct
or indirect suppliers of capital, whether they are lenders,
shareholders, members of pension funds, or depositors in
financial institutions.
As compared with tax breaks to
particular types of saving, the benefits of accelerated
depreciation are more directly tied to productive investment and
less susceptible to "gaming" by simultaneous borrowing and
lending transaction and other shifts in individual portfolios.

The particular program for accelerating depreciation that
emerges
should avoid the kinds of problems that afflict the
10-5-3 proposal.
That proposal would quickly become very
expensive.
It is uneven and haphazard in the way it spreads
benefits among types of assets and industrial sectors.
Its
transition phase is needlessly complicated and may promote
investment delays.
Most proposals to accelerate depreciation for newly
acquired assets will generate revenue losses that grow more
rapidly than the economy for several years.
Careful budget
planning is required, therefore, for any depreciation program.
The reason for this increasing cost is that each year’s
investment adds increased depreciation deductions on top of the
higher deductions still being taken on investments made before.
The 10-5-3 proposal exaggerates this pattern by specifying a
phased reduction in lives over the first 5 years.
For example,
in the first year machinery and equipment would be written off
in no more than 9 years, the next year in 8 years, and so on
down to 5.
This may entice the Congress by offering a very low


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

29

downpayment.
But the revenue cost under this approach would
grow about twelve-fold in the first five years, from less than
$5 billion to nearly $60 billion.
The 10-5-3 proposal becomes so expensive because it would
eventually allow the same combination of deductions and
investment credits for nearly all classes of machinery and
equipment.
These allowances would be more generous than those
for even the shortest write-off periods in present law.
This
approach greatly increases the value of deductions for
long-lived kinds of equipment such as those used in power plants
and ship building.
In contrast, the increased allowances for
equipment that wears out rapidly or becomes quickly obsolete
(such as tools used in metal fabricating and electronics) would
be relatively small.
For owners of commercial and industrial
buildings the value of additional tax saving is, in turn, much
larger than the average increase for investors in machinery and
equipment.
Thus, the 10-5-3 formula indiscriminately favors the
movement of capital to structures as well as to long-lived
equipment, a pattern not clearly related to any criteria for
cost effectiveness in adding to productivity or other economic
goals.

The Administration will support at the appropriate time a
more even-handed approach to accelerating depreciation
allowances.
A connection should be retained between deductions
for depreciation and the actual depreciation experience for
assets used in different kinds of production activities.
Such
an approach would be superior to 10-5-3 in a number of important
respects:
o

It would flatten out the trend in revenue losses,
oroviding the tax reductions earlier and having much
less impact on future budget options.

o

It would not require the kind of phased introduction
scheme that imposes additional accounting burdens and
weakens the investment incentives at the time they are
most needed.

o

It would introduce less distortion into the pattern of
investment incentives.
Additional capital made
available by the promise of increased returns and by
prudent budget policy would be generally attracted to
industries with profitable investment opportunities not
directed to particular kinds of property.

A capital recovery system that involves simpler accounting,
greater certainty, and reduced administrative complexity can be
designed without the cost or distortions of 10-5-3.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

30

CONCLUSIONS
During the next five years, the U.S. must take the steps
required to build a strong foundation for superior economic
performance and increased economic security.
We must show the
discipline to make the sacrifices needed to strengthen our
economy for the long run, while at the same time providing
assistance to those most adversely affected by short-run
economic disruption.

The U.S. stands at the threshold of a new economic era.
What we do over the next five years will determine whether this
new era brings an unparalleled standard of economic well being
or a slow drift to mediocrity.
To make the most of this
opportunity, we must not only build on past gains, but also be
willing to reverse past errors.
Many of the economic problems
now facing us stem from an unwillingness, stretching back at
least 15 years, to confront directly difficult trade-offs and
choices.
Hard choices must be made if the U.S. economy is to
thrive in an increasingly competitive world.
There are four major objectives for economic policy for the
next five years:
First, to improve our economy’s productive
capacity so we can enjoy stronger growth in real incomes.
Second, to return to longer run price stability, which will
permit us not merely to reach a high employment level but to
sustain it.
Third, to enhance our competitive position
internationally.
And, fourth, to reduce our vulnerability to
externally generated shocks, such as energy interruptions.
A tax program, properly timed, and consistent with the
criteria outlined above can make a significant contribution to
attaining these objectives.
If we move in that direction
patiently and responsibly, we will be able to improve greatly
our economic outlook for the balance of this century.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

tO:

Secretary Miller

Department
of the Treasury

Office
y/>! /to of tt^o Secretary

room:

date:.

Attached is
witness list for Ways^an^^
Means hearings (the benaue rx
witness list is not finalized.)

You might note that
"The advisability of enactment of a tax
cut this year to be effective in 1981.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Assistant Secretary

Legislative Affairs
Gene E. Godley

room 3134
phone 566-2037

Friday, July 18, 1980
r *

TENTATIVE
LIST OF WITNESSES
TO APPEAR BEFORE
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS
ON
ON THE ADVISABILITY OF ENACTMENT OF A TAX CUT THIS YEAR TO BE EFFECTIVE IN 1981

TUESDAY, JULY 22, 1980 - BEGINNING AT 10:00 A.M. - FIRST DAY

ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING
Department of the Treasury:

The Honorable G. William Miller, Secretary

WEDNESDAY, JULY 23, 1980 - BEGINNING AT 10:00 A.M, - SECOND DAY

ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING
Charles A. Vanik, M.C. (Ohio)
Sam Gibbons, M.C. (Florida)

Richard A. Gephardt, M.C. (Missouri)

Neal Smith, M.C. (Iowa)
Chairman, Committee on Small Business
Jack Kemp, M.C. (New York)

Stewart B. McKinney, M.C. (Connecticut)

Steven D. Symms, M.C. (Idaho)
Millicent Fenwick, M.C. (New Jersey)
Floyd J. Fithian, M.C.

Andrew Maguire, M.C.

------

(Indiana)

(New Jersey)

Henry J. Nowak, M.C. (New York)
Chairman, Subcommittee on Access to Equity Capital In Business Opportunities
Committee on Small Business
Virginia Smith, M.C.

(Nebraska)

Stanley N. Lundine, M.C. (New York)
Robert K. Dornan, M.C.
Don Albosta, M.C.

(California)

(Michigan)

Toby Roth, M.C. (Wisconsin)

Thomas E. Petri, M.C. (Wisconsin)
***

THURSDAY, JULY 24, 1980 - BEGINNING;AT 10:00 A.M. - THIRD DAY
ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING - INVITED WITNESSES
The Honorable Arthur Burns, former Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board

The Honorable Henry Fowler, former Secretary of the Treasury
BEGINNING AT 2:30 P.M.
The Honorable Paul A. Volcker, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

***

page 2
z

FRIDAVZJULY 25, 19SQ - BEGINNING AT 10:00 A.M. - FOURTH DAY
ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING
INVITED PANEL:

Irving Shapiro, Chairman of the Board, E. I. Dupont deNemours and Company
The Honorable W. Michael Blumenthal, Vice Chairman of the Board, Burroughs Corporation
(formerly Secretary of the Treasury)

Donald T. Regan, Chairman of the Board, Merrill Lynch and Company, Inc.
Donald V. Seibert, Chairman of the Board, J. C. Penney Company, Inc.

***

MONDAY, JULY 28,

19S0 - BEGINNING AT

10:00 A.M.

- FIFTH DAY

ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING

INVITED PANEL OF ECONOMISTS:
Rudy Oswald, Chief Economist, American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial
Organizations (AFL-CIO)

Barry Bosworth, Staff Member, Brookings Institution
(formerly Director of the Council on Wage and Price Stability)
Dr. Martin Feldstein, Professor of Economics, Harvard University
President, National Bureau of Economic Research
Dr. Otto Eckstein, President, Data Resources, Inc.

TUESDAY, JULY 29,

1980 - BEGINNING AT 10:00 A.M. - SIXTH DAY

ROOM 1100 LONGWORTH HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING
American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations (AFL-CIO)
Lane Kirkland, President
.t JJ.

GENERAL PANEL * 1:

Chamber of Commerce of the United States:

Edwin S. Cohen, Chairman, Taxation Committee
accompanied by Richard W. Rahn, Vice President
and Chief Economist

Committee for Effective Capital Recovery:

George Strichman, Chairman of the Board,
Colt Industries

National Association of Manufacturers:

Committee for Economic Development:

Thomas J. McHugh, Chairman, Taxation Committee
(Vice President, Taxes, Kraft, Inc.)

Kenneth McLennan, Vice President and Director of
Industrial Studies

National Mass Retailing Institute: ’David Godfrey, Chairman
■kk *

United Automobile Workers:


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Dougin- Fraser, President

page 3

TUESDAY, JULY 29, 19SO - CONTINUED
GENERAL PANEL #2 (SMALL BUSINESS):

National Federation of Independent Business:

James D. "Mike” McKevitt, Director,
Federal Legislation

National Association of Small Business Investment Companies: Arthur D. Little,
Chairman of Narragansett Capital Corporation,
Providence, Rhode Island
Committee for Small Business Exports:

Richard C. Fenton, President
(President, Fenton International, Inc., Aspen, CO)

American Association of Minority Enterprise Small Business Investment Companies(MESBICS):
Patrick 0. Burns, Member of the Board of Directors(President, Minority Equity
Capital Corporation, NY, NY)
Smaller Manufacturers Council:

Frank Fairbanks, Chairman, Government Relations Committee

GENERAL PANEL #3:
American Council for Capital Formation:

Dr. Charls E. Walker, Chairman

Public Citizens’Tax Reform Research Group:

Arthur Andersen and Company:

Price Waterhouse and Company:
The Tax Council:

Robert S. McIntyre, Director

William C. Penick, Managing Director for Tax Policy
Peter J. Hart, National Director of Tax Policy

William Nolan, Chairman of the Board of Directors
(Vice President, AMAX, Inc.)

International Association of Bridge, Structural and Ornamental Iron Workers:
John Lyons, General President

***
GENERAL PANEL f-4:

National Tax Limitation Committee:

Louis K. Uhler, President

Paul Craig Roberts, Washington, D. C.
Lawrence Kudlow, New York, New York
David Ranson, Cambridge, Massachusetts

Council for a Competitive Economy:

Richard W. Wilcke, President

National Associated Businessmen, Inc.:

Arthur Roth, Chairman
*****

THESE HEARINGS WILL CONTINUE ON JULY 30,31, AUGUST 1 AND RESUME ON AUGUST 18.
WITNESS LIST FOR THE BALANCE OF THE HEARING WILL BE ISSUED EARLY NEXT WEEK.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

THE