View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
Expected at 10:00 A.M. EST
December 1, 1981

STATEMENT
BY
FREDERICK H. SCHULTZ, VICE CHAIRMAN
BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
BEFORE THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON AGRICULTURE AND TRANSPORTATION
OF THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
DECEMBER 1, 1981

I

am pleased to have the opportunity to participate this morning in

your hearings on the Importance of agriculture to the U.S. economy.

You asked

me to discuss the impact on agriculture of developments in the general economy
and financial markets.

Although conditions in the agricultural sector depend

very importantly on circumstances unique to that sector, over recent years its
performance has in some respects become increasingly tied to events in the rest
of the economy.

During the past decade, in the absence of large surplus stocks

of farm commodities, crop production problems and changes in demand for farm
output, whether in the U.S. or abroad, have been transmitted more rapidly to
changes in the price and availability of farm products.

In similar fashion,

cyclical changes in the general level of interest rates have recently been
reflected more quickly and completely in the cost of funds borrowed by farmers.
Agriculture, like many other sectors of the U.S. economy, has been
affected by the related ailments of high inflation, high interest rates and
sluggish economic activity that have plagued us for the last few years.

The

failure of consumer incomes to grow, after taking account of inflation, has
limited demand for many farm products, particularly meat.

With favorable

weather in many areas of the country spurring production at the same tine,
retail food prices this year seem certain to register their smallest increase
since 1976.

Prices for meats and livestock have actually fallen this year,

reflecting a shift in consumers' preferences that may have been accentuated
by the uncertain economic environment. The softness in agricultural prices
has helped to slow the overall rate of inflation this year— which, of course,
is what we are all trying to achieve.
For the farmer, however, relatively stable prices have meant little
growth in gross farm income.

Other prices, unfortunately, have not stopped

rising— including those paid by farmers for the goods necessary to produce




-2
their output.

Prices of reduction goods and services purchased from the

nonfarm sector rose by 11 percent in 1981, following a 16 percent increase
in 1980.

The result has been a marked decline in net farm income^

Moreover,

not only has inflation reduced farm earnings, it has also eroded the purchas­
ing power of this net income.

In response, farmers have pared their purchases

of new equipment sharply, placing great stress on the manufacturers in this
sector.

Thus inflation has played a major and direct role in causing diffi­

culties for farmers and in related industries.
Inflation also has affected the agricultural sector through its influ­
ence on interest rates.

When prices are expected to rise lenders seek to be

compensated for being repaid in funds of reduced purchasing power by receiving
a higher return on their loans,

ilany borrowers often are willing to pay these

higher rates, because they expect the goods they are purchasing on credit will
be more -expensive if they wait.

As a result, the rapid inflation we have

experienced in recent years has been associated with historically high inter­
est rates.
Prior to 1979, farmers borrowing from rural banks were largely insu­
lated from fluctuations in interest rates in national markets, because these
changes had little effect on the cost of funds at such banks.

The introduc­

tion of smaller time deposits with ceiling rates tied to money market rates
has changed that situation, however.

By September 30 of this year, 6-month

money-market certificates of deposit represented 30 percent of total resources
at agricultural banks and large-denomination certificates accounted for another
7 oercent; thus, well over a third of the footings of these banks were in the
form of short-term deposits carrying market-related rates.

In addition, most

rural banks have been offering longer-term "small saver" certificates, which,




-

3

-

bet?inning this summer, have been issued at market-related rates.

Consequently,

when market interest rates increased sharply during the past spring and
summer, the rising cost of funds at rural banks led to higher rates on farm
loans.

Even so, at their peaks, these rates remained below the prime rate

at large banks.

The average effective rate on farm loans at the smaller

banks had reached 19.1 percent at the time of our quarterly survey conducted
during the first week of August, when the prime rate at large banks was 20-1/2
percent.
Although the shift to market-related yields on the liabilities of
smaller and rural banks has caused loan rates at these institutions to fluc­
tuate with changes in market rates, there have been offsetting benefits to
rural communities.

Rural residents, including farmers, have been able to

obtain market-related yields on their deposits in local institutions.

The

capacity of rural banks to compete more successfully for savings has allowed
them to maintain or increase their lending ability during a period in which
it would probably otherwise have been impaired.

The ample liquidity and

lending capacity of rural banks is illustrated by the relatively low level
of their average loan-to-deposit ratios recently.

Currently this measure

is around 61 percent, down from 68 percent two years ago, despite growth in
loans over this period.

Credit has remained available to farmers, albeit at

very high rates.
The rise in interest rates has greatly aggravated cash flow difficul­
ties for those farmers who are both highly leveraged— operating at high debtto-asset ratios— and relying on short-term financing.

When one looks at the

agricultural sector as a whole, however, it appears that farmers in this par­
ticularly vulnerable credit position are a small proportion of all farmers.




-

4

-

The average debt-to-asset ratio in agriculture is only 18 percent— less than
half the average ratio found in nonfinancial corporate business.

Furthermore,

the average interest rate being paid on all outstanding farm debt has risen
relatively slowly, and for 1981 is estimated at about 10-1/4 percent, up less
than 2 percentage points from 1979.

Much outstanding debt was incurred in

earlier years at lower fixed rates and for long periods from sellers of
farms, life insurance companies, and other mortgage lenders, or from Federal
Land Ranks whose variable rates have risen relatively slowly; also, a signif­
icant proportion of recent new debt consisted of drought-related Farmers Horae
Administration loans made at below-raarket rates.

The increase in interest

costs that has resulted from the rise in rates accounts for a relatively small
part— less than one-fifth— of the drop in real net earnings of the farm sector
since 1979.
By the same token, the reduction in interest rates that has occurred in
the last few months is unlikely to produce dramatic improvement in the financial
situation of the farming sector as a whole.

The increase in total interest

costs will be slowed, but average rates on new loans would have to fall below
11 percent in order to reverse the upward climb in the average rate on all
debt.

However, the ongoing drop in market and farm loan rates will greatly

aid those highly-leveraged users of short-term loans who were hardest hit as
rates rose.
The recent declines in interest rates appear to stem primarily from
reductions in private demands for money and credit associated with a weaken­
ing economy— a combination that implies costs as well as benefits to farmers.
Longer-term relief will not come until we see a pronounced and continuing
moderation in the inflation that has gripped this country for more than a




-

decade.

5-

Reduced inflation will bring with it permanently lower interest rates

and will set the stage for a resumption of sustained economic growth.
The Federal Reserve is following a strategy designed to bring this
about.

We have announced our intention to reduce gradually growth in money

and credit to rates consistent with stable noninflationary economic growth.
The course will not be smooth.

In a world of volatile expectations and rapid

changes in financial practices we cannot guarantee the achievement of our
objectives for monetary expansion over short periods, nor perhaps should we
attempt to do so.

Moreover, even a stable growth path for money and credit

may be associated with considerable volatility in the level and pattern of
spending as the economy adapts to slowing inflation rates.
The current downturn in economic activity is an unfortunate example of
this.

I believe that the decline will be limited, partly because the recent

downward movement in interest rates will buoy demands in credit-sensitive
sectors.

It would be a grave mistake, in my view, for the Federal Reserve

to attempt to turn the economy around by greatly accelerating money growth.
Such a policy might result initially in lower interest rates and a faster
rebound in activity, but it would also signal once again a lack of resolve
in combatting inflation.

The ultimate outcome would be higher inflation and

interest rates and additional strains on our economy and financial system.
This outcome can be prevented if the Federal Reserve sticks to its longer
run policy, and we are determined to do so.
The transition to an economy of noninflationary growth will not be easy.
The problems we are facing have been building up for many years, and we cannot
expect quick or painless solutions to them.

Moreover, heavy reliance on mone­

tary policy to accomplish this goal puts particular stress on those sectors of



-

6-

the economy that are sensitive to changes in the cost and availability of
credit— and agriculture falls increasingly into this category.

The adjust­

ment would be swifter and more equitable, were the federal government's bud­
get policy working to reinforce the thrust of monetary policy.

This does

not appear to be in prospect, given the very large gaps now expected between
receipts and expenditures in coming years.

High-budget deficits put addi­

tional strain on private borrowers, because in effect the government has
first call on- the nation's pool of savings.

Reducing government competition

for these funds would lower Interest rates and encourage private spending
initiatives.

As important as the direct effect of lower deficits on finan­

cial markets, in my view, would be the perception fostered by a better outlook
for budget balance that policy throughout the government was being formulated
to accomplish the same goal.

One reason that inflation has persisted at such

a high level in the face of* generally weak economic activity is that the pub­
lic is not yet convinced that government will follow a sustained and consistent
policy to end it.

We must convince businessmen, farmers, consumers, and wage

earners that they can no longer plan on continuing price increases— that all
elements of government policy are dedicated to stopping inflation and will
persist until they succeed.