View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
Tuesday, June 23, 1981
Expected at 10:30 a.m.

Statement by
Frederick H. Schultz
Vice-Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Agriculture
Subcommittee on Conservation, Credit, and Rural Development
U. S. House of Representatives

June 23, 1981

I appreciate this opportunity to appear before your committee to dis­
cuss Federal Reserve policy and the implications for the agricultural sector.
The Board recognizes the critical role of agriculture in meeting fundamental
human needs here and abroad; we also are conscious of the importance of a
vital farm sector for -the strength and stability of the American economy.

We

know, too, that many segments of the agricultural community are experiencing
difficult times, in part because of financial conditions*
I would note that the Federal Reserve has greatly enhanced its
collection of data on farm credit conditions and has become a significant
source of timely information in this area.

In the mid-1970s, when it became

evident that the volatility of agricultural commodity prices and of credit
conditions had increased, several regional Reserve Banks joined in conducting
quarterly surveys of trends at agricultural banks.

Then, in 1977, the Federal

Reserve began a quarterly national survey of interest rates and other terms of
bank loans to farmers.

Most recently, an Agricultural Finance Patabook

was established as a regular quarterly publication of the Board of Governors.
An examination of the available data indicates quite clearly that,
while the farm sector— like others— is confronted today with a problem of high
credit costs, it is not facing a significant problem with respect to credit
availability.

You will recall that there were serious concerns about shortages

of agricultural credit supply at rural banks in late 1979 and early 1980.

For

agricultural banks nationwide, the average loan-deposit ratio— one indicator
of banks' capacity to make additional loans— had reached 68 percent by the
fall of 1979, having climbed in the late 1970s from the 55 percent area that
had prevailed throughout the 1968 to 1975 period (chart 1).




Many agricultural

bankers believed that they might be unable to accommodate the in.-.rease'l loan
demands they expected from farmers in the spring of 1980.
However, even during this period of concern, there were in train
changes in deposit and loan trends that subsequently alleviated the liquidity
squeeze.

On the deposit side, favorable 1979 farm income and the availability

of the attractive new 6-month money market certificate helped to maintain a sub­
stantial inflow of lendable funds.

Meanwhile, with interest rates on loans at

banks rising faster than those posted by production credit associations and
the Fanners Home Administration early last year, demands for production credit
were diverted from the banks.
loan demands.

The business recession also cut into nonfarm

As a result of all these developments, agricultural banks saw

their loan-deposit ratio fall sharply last year, to 60 percent.

Thus far in

1981 loan growth at these banks has picked up a bit, but deposit growth has
kept pace4, so that liquidity positions in the aggregate have not deteriorated.
However, as I noted, the more comfortable credit availability situa­
tion has not isolated farmers from the stresses of high interest rates.

Indeed,

the direction of change in recent years has been toward a greater integration
of the credit markets, lowering the old sectoral and geographic barriers.
developments across the economy tend now to follow a similar course.

Credit

In the

case of agricultural banks, the 6-month MMC has been a raalor factor in linking
the local farm loan market to the national credit market.

The

mmc

has enabled

agricultural banks to remain competitive in the market for savings, and in the
process It has transformed their liability structure.

The MMC was introduced

in mid-1978, and by March of this year it accounted por ?7 percent of the
total resources of agricultural Sanks; with lar*e 'denomination CDs ($100,000




olus) accounting for another 7 percent, roughly a third of the banks’footings
were in the form of short-term deposits carrying market-related rates.
The shift into MMCs from passbook savings and other low-rate instru­
ments resulted in a marked upward adjustment of the average cost of funds for
agricultural banks, and that cost is much more responsive than it was in the
past to swings in money market rates.

Traditionally, loan rates at rural banks

have been based on the average cost of funds, rather than on what the banks
could earn in the money market at any given time.

This sluggishness of average

costs in the pre-MMC era was mirrored in a comparative stability of farm loan
rates, but the transformation of bank liability structure that has occurred over
the past three years has changed this picture drastically (chart 2).

For

example, in our quarterly survey of bank lending to farmers, the effective
average rate charged by smaller banks reached 17.1 percent in Hay 1980— in a
week when the national business prime rate was 18 percent.
13.7 percent in August, when the prime rate was 11 percent.

It then fell to
In the latest sur­

vey, made this May, the effective loan rate at the smaller banks was 17.5 per­
cent, at a time when the prime was 19 percent.

Thus,, farm loan rates at these

banks, which account for about five-sixths of farm lending, have been fluctua­
ting much more than in the past, though not as much as the business prime rate.
At very large banks that are active in national money markets,
and which account for the remaining one-sixth of farm lending, the average
farm loan rate follows the prime quite closely, and is usually slightly above
it (chart 3).

In the May survey, effective ¿arm loan rates at these banks

averaged 19.5 percent, lust above the national business prime.
Of course there is a substantial dispersion of rates on individual
loans.

In May, for example, 13 percent of the farm loan volume was reported




-

4

-

at effective rates of less than 16 percent, and 16 percent had rates above 20
percent.

Thus, the interest rate experience of individual farmers has varied

considerably.

I might also note that, on average, operators of small farms

may have been able to borrow at somewhat lower rates than large farmers.

At

least-, for example, the May survey data show that the effective rates on loans
under $100,000 averaged 17.5 percent while those on larger loans averaged 18.2
percent.

At small banks this difference has narrowed in recent quarters, but

it remains in evidence at large banks.
On the whole, our figures indicate that farm borrowers at banks have,
on average, paid somewhat lower rates than most business borrowers when market
rates of interest have risen to high levels.

This does not, however, alter

the fact that interest charges have risen significantly for most farmers,
especially for those who are heavy users of short-term production credit.
These higher interest costs inhibit agricultural investment and production
just as they do investment and production in other sectors of the economy.
Under the circumstances it is natural to ask whether economic policies are
being directed toward easing the pressures on interest rates.
In answering this question, it is necessary to recognize that the major
source of the high interest rates we have today is inflation.

We are faced

with a deeply entrenched inflation and Inflationary psychology that has created
major imbalances and inefficiencies in our economy.

Indeed, by now it is widely

accepted that ending the inflation is absolutely essential if we are to put
the nation securely on a path of balanced economic growth and high employment.
Inflation leaves its imprint on financial markets as surely as it
does on the markets for commodities and labor.

In an inflationary environment,

nominal sales and incomes must rise in order to maintain the same real levels




-

5

-

of activity, and so too must the nominal volnmos of money and credit*

The in­

flated credit demands will he met by lenders only if nominal interest rates
rise enough to compensate for the expected lower purchasing power of the dollars
with which debts are repaid— and borrowers are willing to pay that price
when they share those expectations.
Once an inflation has gathered momentum, the monetary authority has,
at least in principle, several options available to it, none of which are espe­
cially appealing.

It can seek to accommodate the enlarged demands for money

and thus attempt to sustain the real growth of the economy.
at least two major pitfalls.

This approach has

First, the history of Inflation suggests that it

is difficult to achieve a "steady state"— inflation tends to escalate.

Second,

even a steady inflation tends, over time, in an economy like ours to result in
significant distortions and dislocations that impose real economic costs.
Another option— one that some people have advocated— is to apply a
shock treatment by completely shutting off the supply of money for a period.
Unfortunately, when Inflationary expectations are deeply embedded in contractual
and other arrangements, such a drastic approach may rend the financial fabric
and exact an unacceptable toll in terms of lost economic production.
A third option, and the one we are pursuing, is in effect a middle
course: we are putting the economy on a strict monetary diet— a regimen that
will over time squeeze out the inflationary fat from our financial flows and
force adjustments on the part of business and labor consistent with a return
to price stability.

Such a gradual approach is not without its risks.

If

the commitment to the strategy is questioned, the adjustments of wage and
price behavior will he slower and the economic costs correspondingly greater.
There also is the risk of misestimating the effects of the selected policy




-

6

-

targets, with the consequence that more or less pressure may he placed on the
economy than is desirable. While the scope for fine-tuning clearly is very
limited, it must be recognized that in a world of rapidly changing financial
institutions, technology, and practices, there is a need to stay alert to the
possibility that a given monetary growth rate may vary in its impact on finan­
cial markets and the economy.
On balance, however, the risks of this gradual approach are outweighed
by its advantages.

Consequently, the Federal Reserve intends to continue seeking

a slowing in monetary expansion.

We have set objectives for the growth of money

this year that imply a significant deceleration from the pace of recent years,
and we anticipate further progress toward noninflationary rates of monetary
growth in the years ahead.
The consequences of this policy for interest rates cannot be predicted
with any precision.

Moveover, it must be emphasized that our policies are not

aimed at attaining any particular level or structure of interest rates.

However,

knowing the concern of the committee about the outlook for interest rates, let
me make a few general remarks.

The first would be that the initial direct

impact of monetary restraint is to place upward pressure on market interest
rates— especially shorter-term rates.

As the availability of money falls short

of what is demanded, interest rates tend to rise as businesses, households,
and others compete for the available supply.

In time, the higher rates also

tend to damp spending, and thereby to ease inflationary pressures— a process
that may involve some economic slack.
seem to find ourselves today.




This is the circumstance in which we

The degree and duration of that slack can be

-

7

-

greatly reduced if, upon observing the commitment o-f government to anti-infla­
tionary policy, people adapt their wage and price decisions -quickly to the
underlying economic realities.
As inflation and inflationary expectations begin to wind down, the
groundwork will be laid for a moderation of interest rates.

Over the long

haul, the size of the so-called inflation premium is a major determinant of
nominal interest rate levels.

In this respect, it is fair to say that the

Federal Reserve is pursuing a policy that offers the best hope for a sustained
reduction of interest rates.
It is to be emphasized, however, that the path to lower interest
rates will be shorter and less bumpy if other governmental policies move in
directions that are complementary to the thrust of monetary policy.
critical area in this regard is the federal budget.

The most

An expansive federal budget

stimulates aggregate demand and, at least initially, results in an enlarged
deficit and a greater federal call on the credit markets.

Higher interest rates

are the result* so long as the Federal Reserve does not deviate from its targets
in order to accommodate the government's financial demands.

Thus, because our

economy is already being taxed by high interest rates— and I speak not only of
agriculture, hut of a good many other major sectors— I urge you to place a top
priority on maintaining the current momentum toward curtailment of the growth
of federal spending.

I would urge you as well to exercise caution with respect

to tax cuts, to take care that any cuts are not so great as to offset the
d.eficit-reducing effect of the expenditure restraint and that they are focused
as much as possible on fostering greater productivity.

In this latter regard,

I believe that the greatest productivity gains per dollar of reduced taxes are




-

8

-

available if tax cuts are directed at the business sector, including the busi­
ness of agriculture; I recognize, however, that the high personal tax burdens
that have developed also call for some remedy, and that well designed action
on this front could well have a significant payoff in terms of enhanced produc­
tivity.

Hut I would underscore again that it is crucial that the Congress

keep its eye on the overall balance of the spending-revenue package to ensure
that financial markets are not further strained in this critical period of
transition to a less inflationary economy.




Chart 1
Average Loan/Deposit Ratios at Commercial Banks
Semiannual

Percent

Note:

"Agricultural banks" are banks at-which farm loans comprise 25 percent
more of total loans.




Chart 2
Average Farm Loan interest Rates at Agricultural Banks
Compared with National Business Prime Rate
Quarterly
First Day of Quarter
Percent
25

20

15

10

25

20

15

10

I1968 I I1970I I1972 I 11974 I I1976 I I1978I.. 1980
. m




Chart 3
Average Farm Loan Interest Rates at Commercial Banks
Compared with National Business Prime Rate
Quarterly
First week of second month of quarter

20

15

10

1977




1978

1979

J__ I__ L
1980

J----1— L
1981