View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by
Frederick H. Schultz
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
National Credit Conference
Chicago, Illinois
March 24, 1981

Many years ago, in the early 60's, I was a member of the Florida
House of Representatives.

I got to the House at a time when there was a

speaker who was pretty tyrannical.

He ran the place with an iron hand.

The

ellow who sat next to me on the floor of the House was part of the speaker's
inner circle, and he and the speaker used to get together every morning and
decide what was going to be done in the House that day.

Unfortunately, my

friend failed to attend the meeting one day when there was a bill coming up
on the floor in which the speaker was very interested.

So when the bill hit

the floor, my friend took a look at it, decided he didn't like it, grabbed
the microphone, and moved that the bill be laid upon the table, which is a
very unfriendly motion in that it kills the bill.

The speaker, as he usually

did when he was interested in a bill, had put someone else in his chair and
was in the back of the room patrolling to see that everything was going to
come out all right.

He heard this motion and jammed that big green cigar he

used to smoke in his mouth and came down the middle aisle like a destroyer
under full steam.

He wheeled around the front row, and he wheeled around in

front of this friend of mine and jammed his finger up under his nose and said,
"No, no!"

The place reverberated, and my friend stood there for just a minute

and then he lifted the microphone and he said, "Mr. Speaker, now that it's

-2-

been explained to me, I withdraw my motion."
I'm going to try to explain monetary policy this morning, and I
will try to be simple -- but perhaps not quite that simple -- in what I'm
going to talk about.
I would like to call this speech "Common Sense and Monetary Policy"
because there are a lot of very interesting, attractive ideas running around
Washington and elsewhere these days that have some validity, that certainly
are worth considerable thought, but that I'm afraid have led to some rather
simplistic statements that are worrisome.

Let me just talk about a few of

those.
First of all, there is the idea that the Federal Reserve controls
the money supply.

I'm sure you've all heard that.

some validity, but not much.

The fact is, in the first place, it's very dif-

ficult to know what money really is.
country?

Unfortunately, it has

What is the money supply in this

We publish a series of "M's" with different components, but what is

the money supply?

Is it transactions balances or time deposits?

In which M

do you put money market funds, overnight RP's, Eurodollars, and so on?
thermore, what is the dividing line between money and credit?
put credit cards?

Fur-

Where do you

Do they deserve to be wholly in credit or are they, in

fact, a money substitute in a good many ways?

These are serious questions

about exactly what money is, and that's one of the reasons we publish so many
different "M's" and don't target on a single number.
mistake last year, they targeted on M-3.

The British made that

Unfortunately, they did worse with

M-3 than they did with all the other monetary aggregates and now everybody
points to what a terrible job they did, which isn't really the fact; they
simply forgot that different developments will effect different monetary
aggregates.

-3-

We're having that sort of situation right now.

With the advent

of NOW accounts, which are in M-1B, M-1A is going down like a stone and M-2
is rising.

M-1A is obviously going down because demand deposits are being

changed into NOW accounts.

But why is M-2 going up very rapidly?

Some

people are pulling money out of savings accounts and putting them into NOW
accounts, which decreases M-2, but at the same time the money market funds,
also in M-2, are growing very rapidly.

All of which indicates and illus-

trates why we look at a lot of different aggregates.

Although our operating

techniques are based, as you know, on nonborrowed reserves, we think it's
important to look at a number of different aggregates to get a better idea
of what's happening in the real world.
Even if we knew what the money supply was, could we really control
it very accurately?

As a practical matter, the answer is no.

If you want to

be entirely theoretical about it and ask whether we could devise a system for
holding the money supply very, very close to a target on a monthly basis, the
answer is that we could come fairly close, if we went to contemporaneous
reserve accounting and if we closed the discount window; that is, if we forced
you to come up with reserves the day after we announced them rather than with
a two week lag and if we forced you to go to the market to get the money.

I,

for one, don't happen to think that that's a very good way to run monetary
policy.

It doesn't take a genius to figure out that if you think you've seen

volatility in interest rates up to now you ain't seen nothin' like what you'd
see under that kind of a situation; clearly the interest rates would vary
enormously.
Aside from going to such an extreme, how closely can we control the
money supply?

The fact is not very closely.

We did some studies last year

-4-

indicating that two-thirds of the time there will be a variance of plus or
minus $3.3 billion in the reported M-1B figures on a weekly basis.

That's

an enormous amount of variation and is a totally unexplained kind of variation.

That's what we call "noise."

That sort of thing evens out over a

monthly basis and gets much better over a quarterly basis.
Again, it's very difficult to know what money is; it's very hard
to control it; and, the fact of the matter is, in my opinion, that it is
not very good public policy to attempt to control it too closely.

I think

it is clear to almost everyone that money is like any other commodity:

if

you attempt to control the price, the supply is going to fluctuate; if you
attempt to control the supply, the price is going to fluctuate.

We've

changed to a different kind of operating technique, and so, in trying to
hold the supply much closer to a targeted range, clearly the price is going
to fluctuate more.
I think you would certainly agree with me that the volatility of
interest rates creates a great many problems.

We were talking earlier about

why we've had such very high real interest rates in this country.
have we had 2 0 percent interest rates in the United States?
it is risk premium, and part of it is an inflation premium —
inflation at roughly 10 percent at an annual rate.

Why

I think part of
with underlying

So it seems to me that it

isn't the wisest thing in the world to try to stick to simple, mechanical ways
of carrying out monetary policy.
Another thing you hear is that monetary policy or supply side policy
can work immediately.

Let me say, first of all, that I think of myself as

something of a monetarist.

Henry Kaufman would probably call me a pure mone-

tarist and Milton Friedman would probably discount me.

However, I do think

-5-

that monetarism has been of considerable importance to us.

It has been clear,

I think, that we got carried much too far to one side with Keynesianism, which
in essence says that fiscal policy makes all the difference.

Milton Friedman

and others have done us a great service in pointing out that monetary policy
and the money supply are important.

I believe that and agree with it, and I

think that, given the kind of inflationary environment we've had, it was
crucial that we go to the new kinds of techniques that we're using which mean
that we're looking much more at the growth of the money supply than at interest rates or anything else.

I believe that we're practicing flexible mone-

tarism.
I think I'm a supply sider, too.

I think it is vital in this country

that we have a situation in which we are adding to our productive capacity and
to our productivity and can thereby restimulate real growth.

I am amazed,

though, at how far some of these theories have been carried.

Some monetarists

will tell you, for instance, that the Fed caused the big drop in economic
-civity last year.

They said it was obvious how it happened: the Fed made the

money supply go down, and that made the economy fall off the cliff.
wasn't the case at all.

That just

What happened was that the credit controls came on

and changed everybody's way of thinking and of doing things.

People took money

out of their transactions balances and paid off their loans.

The economy went

down and the money supply went down.
tarists is all wrong.

The cause and effect imputed by the mone-

What amazes me is that monetarists have always admitted

in the past that there was a considerable lag between a policy action and its
effect on the real economy; they've always said that there was at least a two
quarter lag.

In today's world, I suspect that's shorter, because in a highly

inflationary environment these time lags do tend to shorten.

But now suddenly

-6-

you hear monetarists saying that monetary policy had an immediate effect.

I

think that not only flies in the face of all past theory, but it also flies
in the face of common sense; it doesn't work that way.
through interest rates.

Monetary policy works

If you restrain monetary policy, interest rates have

a tendency to go up, and that has an effect on how people do things.

You do

get a lag; common sense indicates that to you.
The supply siders also fascinate me with the idea that things are
going to happen immediately:

first, that you're going to have a tax cut which

is going to go immediately into savings rather than into spending; second,
that it is immediately going to create more productive capacity so supplies
will go up and prices won't.

It has always seemed to me that there is some

lag between the time that you give people an incentive to build manufacturing
plants and the time they can get them built.
have disappeared.

Somehow these time lags seem to

Frankly, I think some of supply side thinking is based on

the idea that you can change the way people do things with rhetoric, and I
have great doubts that that's the case.

It would seem to me that the American

people have gotten very cynical and that it's going to take more than mere
rhetoric to change the way they want to do things.
Another statement that you hear is that steady, stable growth in the
money supply will mean lower interest rates.

I am fascinated by that one.

Over time, I am certainly willing to admit that.

As a matter of fact that is

the predicate on which we have formed our policy; that is, that inflation is
heavily a monetary phenomenon and that to get inflation down you must reduce
the growth of the money supply to non-inflationary levels over time.
said that's what we're going to do; it is what we are going to do.

We have

But it

doesn't solve all the problems very quickly, and the idea that that kind of a

-7-

policy will automatically and immediately mean lower interest rates and less
volatility of interest rates is very interesting to me.
I suggest to you that that is not the case.

It will over time

have the effect of getting inflation down, and when you get inflation down
you're going to get interest rates down.

But I guess "where the monetarists

tend to go wrong is in the cause and effect relationship.

They seem to think

that changes in the money supply have the strongest effect upon the economy.
I think the opposite actually tends to be true: the money supply will tend
to react to changes in economic activity.
right now.

You're seeing that kind of thing

The economy is quite volatile; we've had very considerable ups

and downs; these have had a very considerable impact on the money supply.

We

have just gone through a period when the money supply hasn't grown very much
but the economy has been quite strong.

Why?

Because people change their

demand for money; high interest rates have a tendency to do that to them, and
we've had a period of very high interest rates.

People have accounts like

NOW accounts, which give them a transactions balance and pay them interest.
As a consequence, the money supply has been affected very sharply.

We have

had an enormous increase in velocity in this particular quarter; you are seeing
a high rate of economic activity supported by a rather low money supply growth.
At any rate, these relationships are quite different from those which
people would lead you to believe exist.

The fact is that if you try to hold

the money supply fairly stable, interest rates are going to be volatile, they
are going to fluctuate.

They're not going to do what they did last year.

I

think it's very clear that last year's volatility was primarily caused by the
credit controls.

When we put them on, economic activity dropped; when we took

them off, we hadn't done a thing about inflationary expectations, which were

-8-

still very high.

People went back to doing things the same way they had

before; the economy surged; the money supply surged; and interest rates went
up.

Interest rates are going to fluctuate more sharply under the kinds of

technique we are using now; that's part of the trade-off.

Interest rates

will not be as volatile as they were last year, but they will be more volatile than they would have been under the old techniques.
You also hear that monetary policy can control inflation.

A lot

of people say, "Look, all you've got to do is have a good, firm monetary
policy; that'll take care of inflation.
to on the fiscal side.

Then you can do anything you want

You can spend whatever you want to spend."

that as a very dangerous statement.

I regard

You can make a theoretical argument

that monetary policy can control inflation, but as a practical matter that
is a dangerous approach to the problem, because monetary policy is a very
rough tool.

It does not fall equally on all sectors of the economy.

It falls

much more heavily on small business and housing and autos and the thrift industry and farmers and public utilities -- on all of those sectors of the economy
that tend to be very interest rate sensitive.

It seems to me that we have

already gone through two bouts of very high interest rates which have had a
debilitating effect on a lot of those areas of our economy.

If you want to

depend on monetary policy alone to try to control inflation, you're going to
have more bouts of very high interest rates, probably higher than you've seen
up until now.

Frankly, I don't think that there are a lot of sectors of the

economy that can stand that.

It seems to me that what you will have is a

large number of bankruptcies; I thought that that was what we were trying to
avoid.

-9-

Inflation has frequently existed in industrialized countries.
had it in this country before.

We've

It's always been cured, in the past, by a

depression or a serious recession.
In every country that I know of inflation has been cured by going
through a very tough period.

I don't think we're going to get out of this

period without some pain, but I do think it's possible for us to get out if
we have the right balance of policies.

That does not, in my opinion, mean

putting the load on monetary policy; if you do that, you're going to cure
inflation, but you're going to cure it by having waves of bankruptcies that
create a liquidity crisis in the country.

That'll get inflation down all

right, but that's a hell of a way to do it.
One final comment.
don't count.

Some people I talk to say that budget deficits

They come up with some interesting arguments; for instance,

that 30 years ago in this country we had budget deficits and very low inflation.

They say, "look at Germany, look at Austria, look at Japan; they con-

tinue to run deficits every year and yet their inflation rates are low."

In

other words, they say there is no connection between budget deficits and
inflation.

Of course, you have to look at each particular situation.

years ago we didn't have any inflation problem in this country.

Thirty

We weren't

dealing with the same kind of environment; we weren't dealing with the kind of
"momentum inflation" we have in this country today.
not demand pull or cost push, but momentum inflation.
way people anticipate things.
today.

That's really our problem:
It's expectations, the

We're living in a different kind of a world

As far as Germany and Austria and Japan are concerned, in the first

place, they have an entirely different kind of pool of savings to draw from.
Japan has a savings rate of 20 percent; Germany has a savings rate of

-10-

14 percent; ours is less than half that.

In addition, if you analyze their

budget deficits, you'll see that they're heavily caused by subsidies to
savings and investments.

I could live with budget deficits in this country

if that were the cause, but that's not what's causing our budget deficits
today.

Putting that argument aside, the fact is that people in this country

believe that budget deficits cause inflation, and until you can change their
expectations things —

until you can change the way they think and the way they do

we're not going to get inflation under control.
It is, I believe, vital that we have broad, deep budget cuts.

Paul Volcker spent a morning with Margaret Thatcher and Geoffrey Howe a month
or so ago, and Mrs. Thatcher kept pressing the point that in her opinion the
great mistake made in Britain was not getting budget cuts broad enough, deep
enough, fast enough.

If you don't, you get into the kind of downward spiral

that they find themselves in today.

They've got a very weak economy, with

unemployment over 10 percent, and yet they have to raise taxes.

The way to

avoid that is to get your cuts early so that you begin to change the process.
I for one, think tax cuts are important.
though, because taxes in this country are too high.
needed for a stimulative effect.

I think they're important,
I don't believe they're

The feeling I get is that there is tremen-

dous latent demand out there and, if you could get interest rates down, you
could have a considerable stimulative effect.

I think that that's the way

•we ought to try to move.
I think that it's vital that we get the budget cuts because I think
the budget deficit is crucial -- crucial because we've got to get liquidity
into the private sector in this country.

Short term debt is much too high at

banks; the debt structure of our corporations is much too high; they need to

-11-

be able to get to the capital markets.

They can't get to the capital markets

as long as the government is taking at least 25 percent of all the credit in
this country, and that's the fact today.

If we are going to get "reliquified,"

it is absolutely crucial that we get the budget deficit down and that the
government stop crowding out the private sector so that the private sector
can get to the capital markets and the big corporations can get some money
and so that that can filter down through the system to the smaller corporations.
It is, I think, clear that if you're going to change expectations, you've got
to get the budget deficit down.
People are all from Missouri now: they want to be shown.

They've

heard administration after administration tell them that they're going to get
inflation under control and no such thing has happened.

The only overt act

that's going to change expectations is for the Congress to pass substantial
budget cuts.

I've asked people all over the country: "On the basis of what

you have heard are you going to change the way you're doing things?
answer was "no."

Their

I said, "If you see the Congress pass the budget cuts, will

chat change the way you think?"

The answer was "yes."

One final reason for getting the deficit down is that interest on
the public debt in this country is now running above $80 billion.

If people

in this country see the budget deficit begin to come down, if they see a
credible program of reducing those deficits over time, I believe that interest
rates will be much lower and then interest on the government debt would be
much lower.

If we don't get the kind of cuts that I'm talking about, or if

the tax cuts are bigger than the budget cuts and the deficit continues to
rise, I think interest rates are going to be higher and that will add tremendously to the interest paid on the public debt; the swing, either way, could

-12-

easily amount to as much as $20 billion.

I believe very sincerely that if

we can begin to get the budget deficit down in this country, we can take the
load off the Federal Reserve, interest rates will begin to come down, and
the problem will begin to unwind.

If the budget deficits remain high and

go higher, I think we're in for some very tough times.
On that happy note, let me end with another story.
fellow who won the Nobel prize in astro physics.

There was a

He was in great demand as

a speaker and the university that he worked for provided him with a car and
driver.

They were traveling around to about the 30th speech and the chauf-

feur said, "You know, doctor, I've heard you make that speech so many times
that I can make it word for word.

The physicist said, "You're kidding."

The chauffeur said, "Nope, I can do it absolutely word for word."
prize winner said, "That's remarkable.

The Nobel

You know I would really rather spend

the time in the back of the room with a drink in my hand than get up and make
that speech again so why don't you try it?"

The chauffeur got up and sure

enough delivered the speech word for word, and when he finished the master of
ceremonies got up and said, "Doctor, that was a marvelous speech.

I know you

don't ordinarily answer questions but that was such a marvelous speech and
some of the people here are so interested that I know you won't mind answering
at least a few questions.

There happens to be an astro physicist on our

faculty and he's just dying to ask you a question."

This man then stood up

and delivered himself of a question complete with differential equations
lasting for about five minutes.

The chauffeur stood there and when the

fellow was finished, he looked at him and said, "You know, that's a stupid
question.

And just to show you what a stupid question that is, I'm going to

let my chauffeur in the back of the room answer it."

-13-

I have some of my chauffeurs up here in the front of the room.

At

any rate, if you have any questions, I'll be glad to try to answer them.

.QUESTION:

You mentioned the necessity of private industry to raise capital

and that, of course, includes the banking system.

We have spent a good deal

of time thinking about capital adequacy as well we should.
banks.

We want to improve

At the same time that this is very much on your mind and on ours, we

have visitors from abroad who do a good deal of business on our shores but
they seem to have different rules and perhaps for some no rules.

In any event,

while perhaps initially this was a problem for the money-center banks, it
seems to be all over the country today.

I wonder if you might address the

question or should I withdraw it.
GOV. SCHULTZ:
QUESTION:

When you hear the answer, you may wish you had.

I'll sit down.

I wonder if you would care to comment on your think-

ing or what thinking the Board may have done on it.
GOV. SCHULTZ:

We are concerned about capital adequacy.

We're concerned

because of the inequity that's involved in the money center banks having very
ow capital ratios and the smaller banks having very high ones.

Clearly the

smaller banks under those circumstances have to work a whole lot harder to
get the kind of return on equity that the big banks can get.
More importantly, we are very concerned about the question of capital
adequacy in the country today, rather than about the competition from abroad.
I think we've heard the argument that there are only three American banks in
the top twenty or so these days and, "Isn't that awful."
we necessarily think that so absolutely terrible.
see our banks be the best rather than the biggest.

I don't think that

I think we would much rather
Furthermore, when we look

at the foreign banks, we don't find that they have as low capital ratios as

-14-

many people 'would think because they have so many hidden assets.

You have

to leave the French banks out; the French banks have very low capital ratios
because they are primarily owned by the government and there's not much you
can do about that.
some studies —

As best we can judge at this point —

and we're doing

the indications are that the other foreign banks are not

really out of line with the kind of capital ratios in this country.
We're very concerned about capital adequacy.

We are very concerned

about the very low capital ratios of the large money center banks.

I under-

stand the argument that they're much better diversified and can operate on
lower capital ratios.

We think the trend has gone too far.

We are very con-

cerned about it and are looking at it.
QUESTION:

Sir, with respect to inflation and expectations, budget deficits,

how can control over any of these things bring down inflation as long as we
have union wage contracts and the big industries with 10 and 12 percent wage
increases for three years out?
GOV. SCHULTZ:
be hearing.

I think that this is, again, one of the fallacies that you may
Let me say I think the President is a great communicator, and he

tends to be a very up-beat kind of a guy, and maybe that is what the country
needs; it needs to have the enthusiasm and the American spirit and approach.
But I'm afraid that he has given a lot of people in this country the idea that
we can get through this without a tough period ahead of us, and I don't think
that's possible.
ebullient economy.

I don't see how you can get prices and wages down in an
It seems to me fairly clear that we are going to have to

endure a period of at least slow growth, because as long as it is easier for
businessmen to raise prices than it is to try to hold down the wages they pay,
we are going to continue to have an inflationary period.

As long as businessmen

-15-

th ink that the line of least resistance is to raise prices, and as long as
labor thinks the line of least resistance is to get more in the way of wages,
we're not going to change things.
I'm very much afraid that part of the process is that there's going
to have to be a period when there is restraint on the economy so that there is
pressure on wages and prices.

I think that that has to be combined with the

sort of thing I've talked about: a monetary policy that is clear, that says
that we are going to bring down that growth of money supply over time; a
fiscal policy that says we're going to get those budget deficits down over
time; and a regulatory policy that gets rid of some of the many impediments
that we have to the way the free market ought to work in this country.
not promising you a rose garden, because I don't think it's possible.
'81 is going to be a difficult year.

I am
I think

I happen to think that we have a real

chance of getting through most of that difficulty in 1981 and that it is
entirely possible that you will begin to see inflation starting to come down
towards the end of this year.
A number of studies have been done to try to tell how restraint on
the economy works.

How much does it work to bring inflation down and how much

does it work to increase unemployment?

Art Okun did some studies that indi-

cated that he thought that 90 percent of economic restraint worked to increase
unemployment and only 10 percent to lower inflation.

I think some recent

studies -- some economists that I've talked to recently —

feel that those per-

centages are not that bad, that it's probably more like 75/25.

But even more

important, I'm a rational expectationist, and I believe that those percentages
change over time, and I think 1981 is the crucial year.

If we do the kinds of

things that we're talking about, I think when we get into 1982 inflation will

-16-

begin to come down more rapidly at much less cost in restraint on the economy.
As a matter of fact, in my opinion, the only way that you can get back to good,
real growth in this economy is to get inflation down.

It all has to work

together, but I certainly would not say that it's going to be easy.
QUESTION:

There are a lot of unregulated people that are in the banking indus-

try and do I see any change?
GOV. SCHULTZ:

I certainly hope so.

Obviously, the best case in point is money

market funds.

What we have is a situation in which unregulated, non-depository

institutions are taking deposits; to me, that ain't fair.

I don't want to use

the term, "level playing field," because I created what we call the Thrift
Advisory Council at the Fed, and when they were in the other day and one of
them said he really didn't want to hear any more about the level playing field
because he was reminded that the Christians and the lions were on a level playing field, too.

At any rate, there clearly is an inequity.

What do you do about it?

Philosophically I think we would very much

like to deregulate the depository institutions, but the fact of the matter is
the thrift industry can't stand it at this point in time.

They are under tre-

mendous pressure, and it is just not possible to deregulate further because of
the impact on them.
institutions.

On the other side, you can regulate the non-depository

Then you have to ask how?

That gets you into a morass.

It's

difficult at this point to figure out what it is that we can do that's going
to have any real impact.

If you put reserve requirements on money market

funds, is that going to solve your problem?

Our analysis says probably not.

It may be one approach, but I don't know how much impact it's going to have
because all they have to do is say that instead of having check writing capabilities, they'll just allow three transfers a month out of the money market

-17-

fund into the checking account at the bank; that gets them out of the definition of transactions balance and out of the reserve requirement.

Is the check

writing capability a crucial marketing tool to the money market fund?
don't really know.

We

There are a lot of other proposals, like forcing them to

put a certain amount of their funds into Treasury bills, for instance.

At the

present time about a quarter of their money goes into commercial paper, about
a quarter of it into CD's, around 20 percent into Treasuries, and the rest of
it into RP's and Eurodollars and various instruments like that.

One idea has

been to pass a law which says you've got to put 50 percent of your investments
into Treasuries, the argument being that that will bring the rate on Treasuries
down.

I don't really think so.

Honey is too fungible.

You may get the money

market funds to put more money into T-bills, but that will merely mean that
some people who presently have their money in T-bills will turn around and put
their money in commercial paper and CD's because the interest rates will change.
So I don't think that's going to help very much.

It would have some impact on

:: ie amount that they're able to pay; it would bring down the yield on the money
market fund.

Of course, that gets you into some rather serious problems, too.

You know I've made some comments about the inequity, and the fact that
something needs to be done to erase that inequity regarding the money market
funds.

I sure do get a lot of mail on that subject, none of which is very sup-

portive.

Almost all of it is from every association of retired people that you

can think.

They are saying, quite logically, "We didn't do anything to cause

inflation.

Now you're going to prevent us from protecting ourselves against

it by limiting the amount of yield that we can get."
It's going to be a very difficult problem.

My judgment is that the

balance of the equities at this point points to doing something about the

-18-

money market funds until such time as we can deregulate the depository
institutions further.

I will have no problem at that point; banks will

compete in that market when we just let them.
QUESTION:

Could you speculate on what DIDC's reaction might be to the FHLBB

proposal of yesterday to allow interstate mergers of problem S&L's?

Do you

think that FHLBB is pushing the interstate idea a little too fast?
GOV. SCHULTZ:

No, I think that what is coming about is the realization that

we have a difficult situation out there and that we need to have laws on the
books that allow us to take care of mergers and consolidations in institutions that are in some difficulty.

There are those who would say to you that

that's letting the camel's nose under the tent, that that's the first move
toward interstate banking.

I doubt it.

great pressure is coming from.
coming from competition.

I don't think that that's where the

The great pressure for interstate banking is

The fact of the matter is that banks can do every-

thing but take deposits nationwide and are doing so, so there are a lot of
competitive pressures that are forcing us towards interstate banking.

I, for

one, hope it comes very slowly, and I, for one, hope it comes with the kind
of safeguards that I believe we need to end up with a financial system in this
country that doesn't differ too much from what we have now.

I do not want us

to have a financial structure like most other industrialized nations with a
small number of very large banks.
geared for that.

I don't think our economy or our policy is

Furthermore, some of the studies we've done indicate that

small banks can be very, very competitive and very innovative, particularly
in the area of marketing.

It seems to me that what we want to try to do is

to create a system which gives small banks the opportunity to be viable and
to be good competitors down the road.

-19-

I don't think you can do that rapidly.
time to do.

I think that takes some

But I think there will be legislation in the Congress this year

that will allow this problem of failing or troubled institutions to be
addressed interstate, so that I think that the action of the Bank Board yesterday is not going to be unusual.

I think that you will see that kind of

an approach throughout the industry, whether it's banks or thrifts.

I don't

see that as the camel's nose under the tent for interstate banking, but I
suppose there are those who might.
QUESTION:

Mr. Schultz, many of your remarks addressed the questions of supply

of and demand for credit.

It seems to me that a tremendous influence on the

supply of credit today is the relative attractiveness of world investment in
dollar denominated securities.

Would you agree with this and what effects on

the relative attractiveness do you foresee from monetary policy, tax relief
and spending cuts?
GOV. SCHULTZ:

There isn't any question that the world's getting a lot smaller

from a financial point of view.

We've tried to impede the flow of funds across

national boundaries and the fact is that it just doesn't work very well.

Money

is too fungible and, unfortunately, some of you people out there are too creative, so I think that that trend will continue.
That leads to a number of conclusions.

One of them is that you can

no longer carry out domestic monetary policy just by looking at what is happening inside your own country.
degree.

You are seeing that to a greater and greater

Look at what is happening to the Germans right now.

The German eco-

nomy is very weak, but their current account went into deficit last year;
they are having more of a problem with inflation than they've had for some
years; they have got to protect their currency; and, as a consequence, they

-20-

have had to raise interest rates by about 400 basis points in the last few
weeks.

They've had to go to a totally different kind of lombard facility

which raised their short-term rates literally overnight by 400 basis points.
That was exactly the opposite of what they would have liked to do for their
domestic monetary policy, but it is very clear that the inter-relationship
of countries has become so important and that they, more than anybody else,
understand how important it is to have a strong currency if you're going to
try to hold down inflati on.

That s true of every country, but particularly

of a country like Germany or Japan whose energy comes almost entirely from
outside the country.

You must remember that all international oil transac-

tions in the world are denominated in dollars, and when you have a period in
which the dollar has been very strong vis-a-vis the mark -- in a period of
less than a year it went from 174 up to about 220 -- the Germans can't stand
that kind of depreciation in the mark because it increases their cost so much
and adds tremendously to their inflation rate.

They've had to step in with a

monetary policy just the opposite of what they would have liked to have done
from a domestic point of view.
I see nothing that's going to stop the trend towards international
banking.

The fact is the United States hasn't done too badly.

We talk about

this terrible invasion of the foreign banks in the United States; they presently hold something over $200 billion in assets.

But American banks hold

something over $300 billion in assets of other countries, so we're still
considerably ahead of the game.

The impact is felt in so many ways.

of international lending that you have seen is not going to stop.
has some dangers to it.

The kind

I think it

We are concerned about Brazil and Korea and the

Philippines and Mexico in terms of their ability to repay their loans.

-21-

Fortunately, our banks don't have very much in Poland, less than $2 billion.
Most of that credit is held in Germany and it is likely, I think, that the
Poles will have a moratorium.

But one of the more interesting aspects of

that is that no Eastern European or communist country in that bloc has
declared a moratorium up until now on their credit, and I think that there
is considerable evidence that the Russians are constrained in what they can
do and will do in Poland by the amount of Polish credits that are outstanding.
After all, the Russians have got to finance an enormous pipeline, which is
going to cost many billions of dollars, so that at this time they're concerned
about their credits.

The whole question of money flows, in my opinion, has

become not only much more important from the point of view of the flows back
und forth between countries, but because I think it will have a very lasting
effect on the politics of the world.