View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Frederic S. Mishkin

At Bridgewater College, Bridgewater, Virginia
April 10, 2007

Monetary Policy and the Dual Mandate
Thank you for inviting me to talk with you today.1 I would like to direct my remarks to the
macroeconomic mission of the Federal Reserve System. I wish to note that these remarks reflect
only my own views and not those of the Federal Reserve Board or of anyone else associated with
the Federal Reserve System.
In a democratic society like our own, the ultimate purpose of the central bank is to promote the
public good by pursuing a course of monetary policy that fosters economic prosperity and social
welfare. In the United States, as in virtually every other country, the central bank has a more specific
set of objectives that have been established by the government. This mandate was originally
specified by the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 and was most recently clarified by an amendment to
the Federal Reserve Act in 1977.
According to this legislation, the Federal Reserve's mandate is "to promote effectively the goals of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates." Because long-term
interest rates can remain low only in a stable macroeconomic environment, these goals are often
referred to as the dual mandate; that is, the Federal Reserve seeks to promote the two coequal
objectives of maximum employment and price stability. In the remainder of my remarks today, I
will describe how these two objectives are consistent with our ultimate purpose of fostering
economic prosperity and social welfare. I will then talk about some important practical challenges in
implementing these goals.
(By the way, I wish that I could also discuss the Federal Reserve's role in promoting the stability of
the financial system, another key objective of central banks, but unfortunately that would violate my
own personal mandate of finishing this speech in the allotted time.)
Now with respect to the first objective, the rationale for maximizing employment is fairly obvious.
The alternative situation--high unemployment--is associated with human misery, including lower
living standards and increases in poverty as well as social pathologies such as loss of self-esteem, a
higher incidence of divorce, increased rates of violent crime, and even suicide. Furthermore, when
unemployment is high, the economy has idle workers along with a reduced level of production and
household income. And when factories are idle, firms generally choose not to invest in additional
plant and equipment, which in turn has adverse consequences for subsequent labor productivity and
economic growth. All these symptoms of high unemployment were observed during the economic
devastation of the Great Depression during the 1930s, which is now just a fading memory. But even
less severe recessions are associated with painful consequences for many individual workers and
their families.
With respect to the second objective--that of price stability--there is now a broad consensus among
policymakers, academic economists, and the general public in support of the principle that
maintaining a low and stable inflation rate provides lasting benefits to the economy. In particular,
low and predictable inflation promotes social welfare by simplifying the savings and retirement
planning of individual households and by facilitating firms' production and investment decisions.

Furthermore, an environment of overall price stability contributes to economic efficiency by
reducing the variability of relative prices and by minimizing the distortions that arise because the tax
system is not completely indexed to inflation.
Price stability also has important benefits in terms of equity. For example, an elevated inflation rate
typically increases poverty because the poorest members of society do not have access to the sorts
of financial instruments that would help protect them against inflation. By the way, these are not just
theoretical arguments: The experience of the United States in the 1970s, and that of many other
economies across a wide range of times and circumstances, demonstrates that high and unstable
inflation generally detracts from the standard of living, hinders the process of capital formation and
economic growth, and in some countries has even led to political and social instability. Such
episodes also show that a full recovery from the adverse effects of severe inflation can take many
years.
Although I could spend all morning extolling the virtues of the dual mandate, let me now turn to
describing some of the challenges that the Federal Reserve faces in implementing this mandate.
The first challenge is determining how to interpret the dual mandate. Of course, the Federal Reserve
doesn't take a literal approach to the goal of maximum employment. In that case, our policies would
need to be directed at getting everyone to work at least one hundred hours a week, and we would
have to discourage senior citizens from retiring and young people from attending college instead of
entering the labor force. Furthermore, every modern economy has a certain level of "frictional"
unemployment, which reflects the transitory periods over which individuals remain voluntarily
unemployed while searching for a new job. Partly for these reasons, Federal Reserve officials and
other policymakers often refer to this aspect of the dual mandate as the goal of maximum
sustainable employment, and they place particular emphasis on the word sustainable.
Similarly, in promoting the goal of price stability, policymakers have generally not taken this goal
literally--by aiming at complete constancy of the price level--but instead have pursued policies
aimed at maintaining a low and predictable inflation rate. In particular, at a congressional hearing in
mid-1988, then-Chairman Greenspan defined price stability as an environment in which households
and businesses "can safely ignore the possibility of sustained, generalized price increases or
decreases" in making their saving and investment decisions.2
Now let's turn to the practical challenges in conducting monetary policy to achieve the dual
mandate.
A central element in successful monetary policy is a strong commitment to a nominal anchor, that
is, the use of monetary policy actions and statements to maintain low and stable inflation. During
the 1980s and 1990s, the Federal Reserve succeeded in bringing inflation down from double-digit
levels to the average rate of about 2 percent that has prevailed over the past decade. Moreover, when
some measures of inflation were close to 1 percent in 2003, the Federal Open Market Committee's
official statements specifically noted that any further substantial decline in inflation would be
unwelcome, mainly because of the risk that a falling price level (which has not occurred since the
Great Depression) could cause a significant disruption to economic activity and employment.
In recent years, the Federal Reserve has been quite successful in maintaining a nominal anchor. Not
only has the inflation rate remained within a reasonably narrow range, but inflation expectations, as
measured by spreads between inflation-indexed and non-inflation-indexed Treasury securities and
by surveys of professional forecasters and the general public, have also been well anchored.
Maintaining price stability is also essential for achieving the other element of the dual mandate,
namely, maximum sustainable employment. First, as I have already emphasized, a low and
predictable inflation rate plays a crucial role in facilitating long-term growth in employment and
labor productivity. Second, although the economy will inevitably be buffeted by various shocks, in
the majority of circumstances the appropriate monetary policy response to stabilize inflation also
helps to stabilize employment and output fluctuations around their maximum sustainable levels. In

other words, the two elements of the dual mandate are usually complementary.
To see how a commitment to price stability leads to appropriate policy actions to stabilize
employment and output fluctuations, we need to understand that there are two key determinants of
inflation: inflation expectations and the amount of slack in the economy.3 Maintaining a nominal
anchor helps stabilize inflation expectations, which in turn means that rises or falls in inflation tend
to be highly correlated with economic slack. Thus, stabilizing inflation also helps to stabilize
economic activity around sustainable levels.
To see further how this process would work, consider a negative shock to aggregate demand (such
as a decline in consumer confidence) that causes households to cut spending. The drop in demand
leads, in turn, to a decline in actual output relative to its potential, that is, the level of output that the
economy can produce at the maximum sustainable level of employment. As a result, future inflation
will fall below levels consistent with price stability, and the central bank will pursue an
expansionary policy to keep inflation from falling. The expansionary policy will then result in an
increase in demand that raises output back up to potential output in order to return inflation to a
level consistent with price stability.
For example, during the last recession the Federal Reserve reduced its target for the federal funds
rate a total of 5-1/2 percentage points, and this stimulus not only contributed to economic recovery
but also helped avoid an unwelcome further decline in inflation. In other cases, a tightening of the
stance of monetary policy is needed to prevent an "overheating" of economic activity, thereby
avoiding a boom-bust cycle in the level of employment as well as an undesirable upward spurt of
inflation.
A strong commitment to price stability helps reduce fluctuations in employment and output in other
ways. First, when inflation expectations are well anchored, a central bank will not have to worry that
expansionary policy to counter a negative demand shock will lead to a sharp rise in expected
inflation--a so-called inflation scare--that will then push up actual inflation in the future. Thus, a
strong commitment to a nominal anchor enables a central bank to be more aggressive in the face of
negative shocks and therefore to prevent rapid declines in employment or output.
Moreover, with a strong commitment to a nominal anchor, supply shocks to inflation, such as a rise
in relative energy prices, are likely to have only a temporary effect on inflation. This result is
exactly what we have seen in the United States. Because people are confident that the Fed will not
allow inflation to remain high, the recent sharp run-up in oil prices did not lead to a sustained rise in
longer-run inflation expectations. As a result, inflation rose temporarily but has now been falling
back again. When inflation expectations are well-anchored, the occurrence of an adverse aggregate
supply shock does not necessarily mean that the central bank must raise interest rates aggressively in
order to keep inflation under control, and hence the commitment to price stability can help avoid
imposing unnecessary harm on the economy and on the workers who are most vulnerable to a
weakening of economic activity.
Now that we see the benefits of maintaining a commitment to a nominal anchor, one might naturally
think that there would also be benefits to establishing a similar sort of anchor for the maximum level
of employment. But that thought would be incorrect.
In particular, although the Federal Reserve can determine and achieve the long-run average rate of
inflation in keeping with its mandate of price stability, the level of maximum sustainable
employment is not something that can be chosen by the Federal Reserve because no central bank
can control the level of real economic activity or employment over the longer run. As I've already
emphasized, monetary policy can certainly help improve the maximum sustainable employment of
the economy by maintaining low and predictable inflation. But any attempt to use stimulative
monetary policy to maintain employment above its long-run sustainable level will inevitably lead to
an upward spiral of inflation and therefore will actually undermine the productive capacity of the
economy, with severe adverse consequences for household income and employment.

Indeed, the level of maximum sustainable employment is primarily driven by the fundamental
structure of the economy, including factors such as demographics, people's preferences, the
efficiency of labor markets, the characteristics of the tax code, and so forth. And many policies
outside the control of the Fed can have a significant effect on the efficiency of the economy and
hence on the maximum sustainable level of employment.
Another crucial challenge in implementing the dual mandate is that the level of maximum
sustainable employment cannot be directly observed and is subject to considerable uncertainty.
Indeed, economists do not even agree on the economic theory or econometric methods that should
be used to measure the level of maximum sustainable employment. This challenge would be less
formidable if the structure of the U.S. economy remained fairly constant over a sufficiently long
period of time. In that case, a reasonably good estimate of the natural unemployment rate--the
unemployment rate consistent with maximum sustainable employment--could be obtained from the
actual long-term average rate of unemployment, and one could similarly estimate the path of
potential output by fitting a trend to actual gross domestic product (GDP) data. In fact, however,
such estimates can be highly misleading because the structure of the U.S. economy is highly
dynamic and evolves almost continuously over time.
In particular, over the past few decades the natural unemployment rate and the path of potential
output have apparently moved around quite substantially. If we do not recognize the potential for
such shifts, they can pose serious pitfalls for the conduct of monetary policy. It is difficult to gauge
these structural changes even with the benefit of hindsight, and it is even more difficult to recognize
such developments when they occur. For example, most economists now agree that the natural
unemployment rate shifted upward in the late 1960s and that potential output growth shifted
downward after 1970. However, perhaps because these shifts were not generally recognized until
much later, monetary policy in the 1970s seems to have been aimed at unsustainable levels of
output and employment, and hence policymakers may have unwittingly contributed to a series of
boom-bust cycles as well as accelerating inflation that reached double digits by the end of the
decade. And although subsequent monetary policy tightening was successful in bringing inflation
back under control, the toll was a severe recession in 1981-82, which pushed up the unemployment
rate to around 10 percent.
The opposite problem occurred in the second half of the 1990s, when the common view among
economists was that the natural rate of unemployment was near 6 percent. When the actual
unemployment rate dropped close to 4 percent, and the economy was growing at a rate that many
economists viewed as unsustainable, there were widespread calls for the Fed to raise interest rates to
prevent an acceleration in inflation. Under Chairman Greenspan's leadership, however, the Federal
Reserve resisted these views because it did not see inflation pressures developing and questioned
whether the common estimate of the natural rate of unemployment was correct. The result was that
the Fed did not tighten monetary policy, and the economy reaped the benefits of the new economy:
very low levels of unemployment and a modest decline in the inflation rate.
Attempting to anchor a particular rate of growth of output and employment in the longer term could
therefore lead to seriously flawed policies. As I have already noted, an attempt by the Fed to achieve
growth that is higher than the underlying growth rate of productive capacity would lead to
unnecessary fluctuations of employment and inflation. And trying to achieve growth that is lower
than the economy's true potential growth rate would create unnecessary unemployment and generate
deflationary pressures that would subsequently have to be reversed.
Given the possible pitfalls of trying to anchor the level of output or employment, what is the best
way for a central bank to minimize deviations of employment from its maximum sustainable level?
To be sure, central banks need to form some views about the economy's potential to produce on a
sustained basis. After all, as I have already noted, the amount of slack in the economy is a key
determinant of inflation. But, rather than focusing on fixed estimates of potential output or the
natural rate of unemployment, central banks should take an eclectic approach in assessing the
overall balance of economic activity relative to productive capacity. In other words, in pursuing the

dual mandate, the central bank should recognize that a wide variety of indicators drawn from labor,
product, and financial markets provide information about the overall balance of supply and demand
in the economy. In addition, central banks should use information from various price indicators to
tell them whether the economy is overheating or running well below productive capacity.
In some circumstances, a temporary tradeoff between the two elements of the dual mandate may
exist. Unforeseen shocks to the economy--an adverse supply shock, for example--might lead to
inflation that is temporarily above levels consistent with price stability at the same time that
employment is growing more slowly than its maximum sustainable pace. In such a situation,
returning inflation too quickly to levels consistent with price stability might unnecessarily
exacerbate the economic weakness. Instead, while restoring price stability remains critical, the
central bank should do so at a pace that does not do undue harm to the economy.
Finally, central banks should respond aggressively to output and employment fluctuations on those
(hopefully rare) occasions when the economy is very far below any reasonable measure of its
potential. In this case, errors in measuring potential output or the natural rate of unemployment are
likely to be swamped by the large magnitude of resource gaps, so it is far clearer that expansionary
policy is appropriate. Furthermore, taking such actions need not threaten the central bank's
credibility in its pursuit of price stability.
It should be clear from my remarks today that although as a Federal Reserve official I am legally
obligated to fulfill the dual mandate, I am actually an enthusiastic supporter. The best way to
achieve the mandate is for the Federal Reserve to have a strong commitment to a nominal anchor to
promote price stability, but with a focus on keeping employment as close as possible to its
maximum sustainable level.

Footnotes
1. I want to thank Andrew Levin, Brian Madigan, and Spencer Dale for their extremely helpful
comments on and assistance with this speech. Return to text
2. Alan Greenspan (1988), statement before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs
(746 KB PDF), U.S. Senate, July 13. Return to text
3. Two other important factors are import prices, which are determined by world market prices and
exchange rates, and relative energy prices, such as the price of oil. However, a central bank has no
control over world market or relative oil prices, and so adding these factors into the analysis does
not change the basic conclusion here. Return to text
Return to top